IN SEMIINFINITE FRACTIONAL PROGRAMMING. PART II: FIRST-ORDER DUALITY MODELS

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "IN SEMIINFINITE FRACTIONAL PROGRAMMING. PART II: FIRST-ORDER DUALITY MODELS"

Transcription

1 GENERALIZED α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex FUNCTIONS IN SEMIINFINITE FRACTIONAL PROGRAMMING. PART II: FIRST-ORDER DUALITY MODELS G.J. ZALMAI Communicated by the former editorial board In this paper, we discuss a fairly large number of first-order duality results under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity assumptions for a semiinfinite fractional programming problem. AMS 200 Subject Classification: 49N5, 90C30, 90C32, 90C34, 90C46. Key words: Semiinfinite programming, fractional programming, generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions, infinitely many equality and inequality constraints, first-order dual problems, duality theorems.. INTRODUCTION In this paper, we state and prove a fairly large number of parametric and parameter-free duality results under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ- invexity assumptions for the following semiinfinite fractional programming problem: P Minimize ϕx = fx gx subject to G j x, t 0 for all t T j, j q, H k x, s = 0 for all s S k, k r, x X, where q and r are positive integers, X is a nonempty open convex subset of R n n-dimensional Euclidean space, for each j q {, 2,..., q} and k r, T j and S k are compact subsets of complete metric spaces, f and g are real-valued functions defined on X, for each j q, z G j z, t is a real-valued function defined on X for all t T j, for each k r, z H k z, s is a real-valued function defined on X for all s S k, for each j q and k r, t G j x, t and s H k x, s are continuous real-valued functions defined, respectively, on T j and S k for all x X, and gx > 0 for all x satisfying the constraints of P. REV. ROUMAINE MATH. PURES APPL., ,, 35 62

2 36 G.J. Zalmai 2 The present study is essentially a continuation of the investigation initiated in the companion paper [2 where some information about fractional programming is presented, the current status of semiinfinite programming is briefly discussed and numerous key references are cited, an overview of the concept of α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity and some of its extensions is given, and a fairly large number of sets of global sufficient optimality results under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity assumptions are established. For the necessary background material and preliminaries, the reader is referred to [2. Here we shall make use of the sufficient optimality results developed in [2 and a set of necessary optimality conditions, which will be recalled in the next section, and construct several first-order duality models for P and prove appropriate duality theorems. Second- and higher-order counterparts of these results are discussed in [3, 4. Although presently various duality results exist in the related literature for several classes of static and dynamic fractional optimization problems with a finite number of constraints, so far no such results are available for any kind of semiinfinite fractional programming problems involving generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. To the best of our knowledge, all the duality results established in this paper are new in the area of semiinfinite programming. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we recall an auxiliary result which will be needed in the sequel. We begin our discussion of duality for P in Section 3 where we formulate two parametric duality models with somewhat restricted constraint structures, and prove weak, strong, and strict converse duality theorems under appropriate generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ- invexity assumptions. In Section 4, we present another pair of parametric duality models with relatively more general constraint structures that allow for a greater variety of generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity hypotheses under which duality can be established. We continue our investigation of parametric duality for P in Section 5 where we consider two generalized duality models and prove several sets of duality results. These duality models are, in fact, two families of dual problems for P whose members can easily be identified by appropriate choices of certain sets and functions. The nonparametric counterparts of these generalized duality models are taken up in Section 6, and a number of duality results are established. Finally, in Section 7, we summarize our main results and also point out some additional research opportunities arising from certain modifications of the principal problem model P. 2. PRELIMINARIES For proving our duality theorems, we shall need a few basic definitions and auxiliary results. For the definitions of the new classes of generalized

3 3 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 37 α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions that will be utilized in the statements and proofs of our duality theorems, the reader is referred to [2, and the two auxiliary results that will be needed in the sequel for proving strong and strict converse duality theorems are stated below. Theorem 2.. [5. Let x F and λ = fx /gx, let f and g be continuously differentiable at x, for each j q, let the function z G j z, t be continuously differentiable at x for all t T j, and for each k r, let the function z H k z, s be continuously differentiable at x for all s S k. If x is an optimal solution of P, if the generalized Guignard constraint qualification holds at x, and if the set cone{ G j x, t : t ˆT j x, j q} + span{ H k x, s : s S k, k r} is closed, then there exist integers ν0 and ν, with 0 ν0 ν n +, such that there exist ν0 indices j m, with j m q, together with ν0 points tm ˆT jm x, m ν0, ν ν0 indices k m, with k m r, together with ν ν0 points sm S km for m ν \ν0, and ν real numbers vm, with vm > 0 for m ν0, with the property that fx λ gx + ν0 vm G jm x, t m + m= ν m=ν 0 + v m H km x, s m = 0, where ˆT j x = {t T j : G j x, t = 0} and ν \ν0 is the complement of the set ν0 relative to ν. Eliminating λ and redefining the Lagrange multipliers v m, m ν, we obtain the following parameter-free version of Theorem 2.. Theorem 2.2. Let x F, let f and g be continuously differentiable at x, for each j q, let the function z G j z, t be continuously differentiable at x for all t T j, and for each k r, let the function z H k z, s be continuously differentiable at x for all s S k. If x is an optimal solution of P, if the generalized Guignard constraint qualification holds at x, and if the set cone{ G j x, t : t ˆT j x, j q} + span{ H k x, s : s S k, k r} is closed, then there exist integers ν0 and ν, with 0 ν0 ν n +, such that there exist ν0 indices j m, with j m q, together with ν0 points t m ˆT jm x, m ν0, ν ν0 indices k m, with k m r, together with ν ν0 points sm S km for m ν \ν0, and ν real numbers vm, with vm > 0 for m ν0, with the property that ν0 ν gx fx fx gx + vm G jm x, t m + vm H km x, s m = 0. m= m=ν0 + We shall call x a normal feasible solution of P if x satisfies all the constraints of P, if the generalized Guignard constraint qualification holds

4 38 G.J. Zalmai 4 at x, and if the set cone{ G j x, t : t ˆT j x, j q} + span{ H k x, s : s S k, k r} is closed. The forms and features of these results will serve as our guide in this paper for constructing several parametric and nonparametric duality models for P and proving appropriate duality theorems. In the remainder of this paper, we assume that the functions f, g, G j, t, t T j, j q, and H k, s, s S k, k r, are continuously differentiable on the open set X. With regard to the choice of the type of generalized invex functions, specified in Definitions in [2, to be used in the statements and proofs of our duality theorems, we shall consistently use the cases in which the functions α and β are nonzero for all x, y X X. All the duality results established in this paper can be modified, restated, and proved for the other cases in a straightforward manner. 3. DUALITY MODEL I In this section, we consider two dual problems with relatively simple constraint structures and prove weak, strong, and strict converse duality theorems under appropriate α, β, γ, η, 0, θ-invexity conditions. More general duality models and results for P will be discussed in the subsequent sections. Let { H = y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s : y X; λ R; 0 ν 0 ν n + ; v R ν, v i > 0, i ν 0 ; J ν0 = j, j 2,..., j ν0, j i q; K ν\ν0 = k ν0 +,..., k ν, k i r; t = t, t 2,..., t ν 0, t i T ji ; s = s ν 0+,..., s ν, s i S ki }. Consider the following two problems: DI λ subject to sup y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H 3. fy λ gy + ν 0 m= ν 0 v m G jm y, t m fy λgy + v m G jm y, t m + m= DI sup y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H λ subject to 3.2 and ν m=ν 0 + ν m=ν 0 + v m H km y, s m = 0, v m H km y, s m 0;

5 5 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II fy λ gy + + ν m=ν 0 + ν 0 m= v m G jm y, t m v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y 0 for all x F, where β is a function from X X to R and η is a function from X X to R n. The structures of the two problems designated above as DI and DI are based directly on the form and contents of the necessary optimality conditions of Theorem 2.. This is, of course, the standard method for constructing Wolfe-type dual problems. Comparing DI and DI, we see that DI is relatively more general than DI in the sense that any feasible solution of DI is also feasible for DI, but the converse is not necessarily true. Furthermore, we observe that 3. is a system of n equations, whereas 3.3 is a single inequality. Clearly, from a computational point of view, DI is preferable to DI because of the dependence of 3.3 on the feasible set of P. Despite these apparent differences, it turns out that the statements and proofs of all the duality theorems for P DI and P DI are almost identical and, therefore, we shall consider only the pair P DI. The next two theorems show that DI is a dual problem for P. Theorem 3. Weak Duality. Let x and y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DI, respectively, and assume that the Lagrangian-type function z Lz, v, λ, t, s = fz λgz + ν 0 m= v m G jm z, t m + ν m=ν 0 + v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, 0, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0, where t t, t 2,..., t ν 0 and s s ν 0+, s ν 0+2,..., s ν. Then ϕx λ. Proof. From 3. we observe that fy λ gy + + ν 0 m= v m G jm y, t m ν m=ν 0 + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y = 0, which in view of our α, β, γ, η, 0, θ-pseudoinvexity assumption implies that αx, y γx, y e αx,y[lx,v,λ, t, s Ly,v,λ, t, s 0.

6 40 G.J. Zalmai 6 We need to consider two cases: αx, y > 0 and αx, y < 0. If we assume that αx, y > 0 and recall that γx, y > 0, then the above inequality becomes which implies that e αx,y[lx,v,λ, t, s Ly,v,λ, t, s, Lx, v, λ, t, s Ly, v, λ, t, s. In view of the dual feasibility of y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s and 3.2, the right-hand side of the above inequality is greater than or equal to zero, and hence we have Lx, v, λ, t, s 0. Inasmuch as x F, and v m > 0, m ν 0, this inequality simplifies to fx λgx 0. Hence, ϕx = fx/gx λ. If we assume that αx, y < 0, we arrive at the same conclusion. Theorem 3.2 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that for each feasible solution y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s of DI, the conditions specified in Theorem 3. are satisfied. Then there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is an optimal solution of DI and ϕx = λ. Proof. Since x is a normal optimal solution of P, by Theorem 2., there exist v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, and s such that w x, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, s is a feasible solution of DI and ϕx = λ. If w were not optimal, then there would exist a feasible solution x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s of DI such that ϕx = λ < λ, which contradicts Theorem 3.. Therefore, we conclude that w is an optimal solution of DI. We also have the following converse duality result for P and DI. Theorem 3.3 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DI, and assume that the function z Lz, ṽ, λ, t, s is strictly α, β, γ, η, 0, θ- pseudoinvex at x and γx, x > 0. Then x = x, that is, x is an optimal solution of P and ϕx = λ. Proof. a: Suppose to the contrary that x x. By Theorem 2., there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is a feasible solution of DI and ϕx = λ. Now proceeding as in the proof of Theorem 3. with x replaced by x and y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s by x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s and using the condition set forth above, we arrive at the strict inequality fx λgx > 0, and so ϕx > λ, which contradicts the fact that ϕx = λ λ. Therefore, we conclude that x = x and ϕx = λ.

7 7 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 4 4. DUALITY MODEL II In this section, we consider two duality models with special constraint structures that allow for a greater variety of generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity conditions under which duality can be established. Consider the following two problems: DII subject to sup y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H 4. fy λ gy + ν 0 m= λ v m G jm y, t m fy λgy 0, ν m=ν G jm y, t m 0, m ν 0, 4.4 v m H km y, s m 0, m ν\ν 0 ; DII sup λ y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H v m H km y, s m = 0, subject to 3.3 and The remarks and observations made earlier about the relationships between DI and DI are, of course, also valid for DII and DII. The next two theorems show that DII is a dual problem for P. Theorem 4. Weak Duality. Let x and w y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DII, respectively, and assume that any one of the following five sets of hypotheses is satisfied: a i z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y 0; b i z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y 0; c i z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y;

8 42 G.J. Zalmai 8 iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ρx, y 0; d i z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ρx, y 0; e i z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m + ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + ˆρx, y 0. Then ϕx λ. Proof. a: From the primal feasibility of x and 4.3 we see that G jm x, t m 0 G jm y, t m for each m ν 0, and hence αx, y ˆγ mx, y e αx,y[g jm x,tm G jm y,t m 0, which in view of ii implies that Gjm y, t m, e βx,yηx,y ˆρ m x, y θx, y 2. As v m > 0 for each m ν 0, the above inequalities yield 4.5 ν 0 ν 0 v m G jm y, t m, e βx,yηx,y v m ˆρ m x, y θx, y 2. m= m= Similarly, from the primal feasibility of x, 4.4, and iii we deduce that 4.6 ν ν v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y ρ m x, y θx, y 2. m=ν 0 + m=ν 0 + Combining 4. with 4.5 and 4.6, and using iv, we obtain fy λ gy, e βx,yηx,y [ ν 0 ν v m ˆρ m x, y + ρ m x, y θx, y 2 ρx, y θx, y 2, m= m=ν 0 + which in view of i implies that αx, y γx, y e αx,y{fx λgx [fy λgy} 0.

9 9 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 43 Since γx, y > 0, this inequality implies that fx λgx fy λgy, and therefore using 4.2 we have the desired inequality ϕx λ. b e: The proofs are similar to that of part a. Theorem 4.2 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that any one of the five sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 4. is satisfied for all feasible solutions of DII. Then there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is an optimal solution of DII and ϕx = λ. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 3.2. Theorem 4.3 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let w x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DII, and assume that any one of the five sets of conditions specified in Theorem 4. is satisfied and that the function z fz λgz is strictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at x. Then x = x, that is, x is an optimal solution of P, and ϕx = λ. Proof. a: Suppose to the contrary that x x. By Theorem 2., there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is a feasible solution of DII and ϕx = λ. Now proceeding as in the proof of Theorem 4. with x replaced by x and w by w and using our strict α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvexity assumption, we arrive at the strict inequality fx λgx > 0 and so ϕx > λ, which contradicts the fact that ϕx = λ λ. Therefore, we conclude that x = x and ϕx = λ. b e: The proofs are similar to that of part a. Theorem 4.4 Weak Duality. Let x and y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DII, respectively, and assume that any one of the following five sets of hypotheses is satisfied: a b i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y > 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y;

10 44 G.J. Zalmai 0 c d e iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y > 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ρx, y > 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ρx, y > 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m + ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + ˆρx, y > 0; Then ϕx λ. Proof. a : Because of our assumptions specified in ii and iii, 4.5 and 4.6 remain valid for the present case. From 4., 4.5, 4.6, and iv we deduce that fy λ gy, e βx,yηx,y [ ν 0 v m ˆρ m x, y + m= ν m=ν 0 + ρ m x, y θx, y 2 > ρx, y θx, y 2, which in view of i implies that αx, y γx, y e αx,y{fx λgx [fy λgy} 0. Since γx, y > 0, it follows from this inequality that fx λgx fy λgy 0, where the second inequality follows from 4.2. Therefore, we have the desired inequality ϕx λ. b e: The proofs are similar to that of part a. Theorem 4.5 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that any one of the five sets of conditions set forth in

11 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 45 Theorem 4.4 is satisfied for all feasible solutions of DII. Then there exist v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, s is an optimal solution of DII and ϕx = λ. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 3.2. Theorem 4.6 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let w x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DII, and assume that any one of the five sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 4.4 is satisfied for the feasible solution w of DII and that the function z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at x. Then x = x and ϕx = λ. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 4.3. Theorem 4.7 Weak Duality. Let x and y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DII, respectively, and assume that any one of the following seven sets of hypotheses is satisfied: a b c d i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is strictly α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ- pseudoinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is strictly α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii for each m ν\ν 0, z v m H km z, s m is strictly α, β, γ m, η, ρ m, θ- pseudoinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ν m=ν 0 + ρ mx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0;

12 46 G.J. Zalmai 2 e f g ii for each m ν 0, z G jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ m, η, ˆρ m, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is strictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ν 0 m= v m ˆρ m x, y + ρx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is strictly α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ρx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m is α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii z ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is strictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y; iv ρx, y + ˆρx, y + ρx, y 0; i z fz λgz is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii z ν 0 m= v mg jm z, t m + ν m=ν 0 + v mh km z, s m is strictly α, β, ˆγ, η, ˆρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y; iii ρx, y + ˆρx, y 0. Then ϕx λ. Proof. a: Suppose to the contrary that ϕx < λ. This means that fx λgx < 0, and hence αx, y γx, y e αx,y{fx λgx [fy λgy} < 0, which in view of i implies 4.7 fy λ gy, e βx,yηx,y ρx, y θx, y 2. From the primal feasibility of x and 4.3 we see that G jm x, t m 0 G jm y, t m for each m ν 0, and hence αx, y ˆγ mx, y e αx,y[g jm x,tm G jm y,t m 0, which in view of ii implies that Gjm y, t m, e βx,yηx,y < ˆρ m x, y θx, y 2.

13 3 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 47 As v m > 0 for each m ν 0, the above inequalities yield 4.8 ν 0 ν 0 v m G jm y, t m, e βx,yηx,y < v m ˆρ m x, y θx, y 2. m= m= Now combining 4., 4.6 which is valid for the present case because of our assumptions set forth in iii, 4.8, and iv, we get fy λ gy, e βx,yηx,y > ρx, y θx, y 2, which contradicts 4.7. Therefore, we conclude that ϕx λ. b g: The proofs are similar to that of part a. Theorem 4.8 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that any one of the seven sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 4.7 is satisfied for all feasible solutions of DII. Then there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is an optimal solution of DII and ϕx = λ. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 3.2. Theorem 4.9 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let w x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DII, and assume that any one of the seven sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 4.7 is satisfied for the feasible solution w of DII, and the function z fz λgz is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at x. Then x = x and ϕx = λ. Proof. a: By Theorem 2., there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is a feasible solution of DII and ϕx = λ. Suppose to the contrary that x x. From the primal feasibility of x and 4.3 we see that G jm x, t m 0 G jm x, t m for each m ν 0, and hence αx, x ˆγ mx, x e αx, x[g jm x,t m G jm x, t m 0, which in view of ii implies that βx Gjm x, t m, e βx, xηx, x < ˆρ m x, x θx, x 2., x As ṽ m > 0 for each m ν 0, the above inequalities yield 4.9 ν 0 ν 0 βx ṽ m G jm x, t m, e βx, xηx, x < ṽ m ˆρ m x, x θx, x 2., x m= m=

14 48 G.J. Zalmai 4 Now, combining 4., 4.6 which is valid for the present case because of our assumptions set forth in iii, 4.9, and iv, we get f x λ g x, e βx, xηx, x βx > ρx, x θx, x 2,, x which by virtue of the α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvexity of the function z fz λgz at x implies that αx, x γx, x e αx, x{fx λgx [f x λg x} > 0. Since γx, x > 0 and f x λg x 0, this inequality implies that fx λgx > 0, and so ϕx > λ, which contradicts the fact that ϕx = λ λ. Therefore, we conclude that x = x and ϕx = λ. b g: The proofs are similar to that of part a. 5. DUALITY MODEL III In this section, we discuss several families of duality results under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity hypotheses imposed on certain combinations of the problem functions. This is accomplished by employing a certain partitioning scheme which was originally proposed in [ for the purpose of constructing generalized dual problems for nonlinear programming problems. For this we need some additional notation. Let ν 0 and ν be integers, with ν 0 ν n+, and let {J 0, J,..., J M } and {K 0, K,..., K M } be partitions of the sets ν 0 and ν\ν 0, respectively; thus, J i ν 0 for each i M {0}, J i J j = for each i, j M {0} with i j, and M i=0 J i = ν 0. Obviously, similar properties hold for {K 0, K,..., K M }. Moreover, if m and m 2 are the numbers of the partitioning sets of ν 0 and ν\ν 0, respectively, then M = max{m, m 2 } and J i = or K i = for i > min{m, m 2 }. In addition, we use the real-valued functions z Φz, v, λ, t, s, and z Λ τ z, v, t, s defined, for fixed v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, and s, on X as follows: Φz, v, λ, t, s = fz λgz + v m G jm z, t m + v m H km z, s m, m J 0 Λ τ z, v, t, s = m J τ v m G jm z, t m + m K τ v m H km z, s m, τ M {0}. Making use of the sets and functions defined above, we can state our general duality models as follows:

15 5 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 49 DIII sup y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H λ subject to 5. fy λ gy + ν 0 m= v m G jm y, t m + ν m=ν fy λgy + m J 0 v m G jm y, t m m J τ v m G jm y, t m + DIII sup λ y,v,λ,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s H v m H km y, s m = 0, v m H km y, s m 0, m K τ v m H km y, s m 0, τ M; subject to 3.3, 5.2, and 5.3. The remarks and observations made earlier about the relationships between DI and DI are, of course, also valid for DIII and DIII. The next two theorems show that DIII is a dual problem for P. Theorem 5. Weak Duality. Let x and w y, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DIII, respectively, and assume that any one of the following four sets of hypotheses is satisfied: a b c i z Φz, v, λ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y>0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + M τ= ρ τ x, y 0; i z Φz, v, λ, t, s is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + M τ= ρ τ x, y > 0; i z Φz, v, λ, t, s is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is strictly α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ- pseudoinvex at y; iii ρx, y + M τ= ρ τ x, y 0; d i z Φz, v, λ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y, and for each τ M 2, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is strictly α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-pseudoinvex at y, where {M, M 2 } is a partition of M;

16 50 G.J. Zalmai 6 iii ρx, y + M τ= ρ τ x, y 0. Then ϕx λ. Proof. a: It is clear that 5. can be expressed as follows: 5.4 fy λ gy + v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m m J 0 M [ + v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m = 0. τ= m J τ m K τ Since for each τ M, Λ τ x, v, t, s = v m G jm x, t m + v m H km x, s m m J τ m K τ 0 by the primal feasibility of x and positivity of v m, m ν 0 m J τ v m G jm y, t m + m K τ v m H km y, s m by 5.3 = Λ τ y, v, t, s, it follows that αx, y γ τ x, y e αx,y[λτ x,v, t, s Λ τ y,v, t, s 0, which in view of ii implies that v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y m J τ m K τ Summing over τ, we obtain ρ τ x, y θx, y M [ v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y τ= m J τ m K τ M ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. Combining 5.4 and 5.5, and using iii we get fy λ gy + v m G jm y, t m m J 0 + M v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y ρ τ x, y θx, y 2 τ= τ= ρx, y θx, y 2,

17 7 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 5 which by virtue of i implies that αx, y γx, y e αx,y[φx,v,λ, t, s Φy,v,λ, t, s 0, Since γx, y > 0, we can deduce from this inequality that Φx, v, λ, t, s Φy, v, λ, t, s 0, where the second inequality follows from 5.2. Therefore, we have 0 Φx, v, λ, t, s = fx λgx + m J 0 v m G jm x, t m + fx λgx by the primal feasibility of x. v m H km x, s m Hence, ϕx λ. b: The proof is similar to that of part a. c : Suppose to the contrary that ϕx < λ. This gives fx λgx < 0. Using this inequality and keeping in mind that v m > 0 for each m ν 0, we have Φx, v, λ, t, s fx λgx by the primal feasibility of x < 0 Φy, v, λ, t, s by 5.2, and hence αx, y γx, y e αx,y[φx,v,λ, t, s Φy,v,λ, t, s < 0, which in view of i implies that 5.6 fy λ gy + v m G jm y, t m m J 0 + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y ρx, y θx, y 2. As shown in the proof of part a, for each τ M, we have Λ τ x, v, t, s Λ τ y, v, t, s, and hence αx, y γ τ x, y e αx,y[λτ x,v, t, s Λ τ y,v, t, s 0, which in view of ii implies that v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y m J τ m K τ < ρ τ x, y θx, y 2.

18 52 G.J. Zalmai 8 Summing over τ, we obtain M [ v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y τ= m J τ m K τ M < ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. Combining this inequality with 5.4 and using iii, we get fy λ gy + v m G jm y, t m m J 0 + M v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y > ρ τ x, y θx, y 2 τ= τ= which contradicts 5.6. Therefore, we conclude that ϕx λ. d: The proof is similar to that of part c. ρx, y θx, y 2, Theorem 5.2 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that any one of the four sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 5. is satisfied for all feasible solutions of DIII. Then there exist v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is an optimal solution of DIII and ϕx = λ. Proof. The proof is similar to that of Theorem 3.2. Theorem 5.3 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let w x, ṽ, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DIII, and assume that any one of the following four sets of conditions holds: a The assumptions specified in part a of Theorem 5. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIII, and the function z Φz, ṽ, λ, t, s is strictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at x. b The assumptions specified in part b of Theorem 5. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIII, and the function z Φz, ṽ, λ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at x. c The assumptions specified in part c of Theorem 5. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIII, and the function z Φz, ṽ, λ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at x. d The assumptions specified in part d of Theorem 5. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIII, and the function z Φz, ṽ, λ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at x. Then x = x and ϕx = λ.

19 9 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 53 Proof. a : Since x is a normal optimal solution of P, by Theorem 2., there exist v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, and s such that x, v, λ, ν, ν 0, J ν 0, K ν \ν 0, t, s is a feasible solution of DIII and ϕx = λ. Suppose to the contrary that x x. Now proceeding as in the proof of part a of Theorem 5. with x replaced by x and w by w, we arrive at the inequality βx f x, x λ g x + ṽ m G jm x, t m m J 0 + ṽ m H km x, s m, e βx, xηx, x ρx, x θx, x 2, which by virtue of our strict HAα, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvexity assumption implies that αx, x γx, x e αx, x[φx,ṽ, λ, t, s Φ x,ṽ, λ, t, s > 0. Since γx, x > 0, this inequality implies that Φx, ṽ, λ, t, s > Φ x, ṽ, λ, t, s 0, where the second inequality follows from the dual feasibility of w and 5.2. In view of the primal feasibility of x and dual feasibility of w, the above inequality reduces to fx λgx > 0, and so we get ϕx > λ, which contradicts the fact that ϕx = λ λ. Therefore, we conclude that x = x and ϕx = λ. b d: The proofs are similar to that of part a. As pointed out earlier, the duality models DIII and DIII can be viewed as two families of dual problems for P whose members can easily be identified by appropriate choices of the partitioning sets J µ and K µ, µ M {0}. The special cases and variants of DIII and DIII provide a multitude of dual problems for various classes of semiinfinite as well as conventional nonlinear programming problems. The remainder of this paper will be devoted to a brief discussion of some nonparametric duality models for P. It is of course possible to formulate the nonparametric analogues of the duality models DI, DI, DII and DII, and state and prove the counterparts of Theorems and Theorems However, for the sake of avoiding excessive repetition, we shall not treat these nonparametric duality models separately. Instead, in the next section we shall consider two general nonparametric duality models which subsume the semiinfinite versions of several well-known nonparametric dual problems that have been studied previously in the literature of fractional programming.

20 54 G.J. Zalmai DUALITY MODEL IV In this section, we formulate two generalized nonparametric duality models for P and prove appropriate duality theorems under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity conditions. In addition to the notation used in Section 5, we also need the function z Πz, y, v, t, s defined, for fixed y, v, t, and s, on X by Πz, y, v, t, s = gy [fz + m J0 v m G jm z, t m + v m H km z, s m Let K = DIV [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, sgz. { y, v, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s : y X; 0 ν 0 ν n+; v R ν, v i > 0, for i ν 0 ; J ν0 = j, j 2,..., j ν0, j i q; K ν\ν0 = k ν0 +,..., k ν, k i r; t = t, t 2,..., t ν 0, t i T ji ; s = s ν 0+,..., s ν, s i S ki }. Consider the following two nonparametric duality models for P : sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy subject to 6. gy [ fy + m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m [fy+ Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy+ v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m = 0, m ν 0 \J 0 m ν\ν 0 \K v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m 0, τ M; m J τ m K τ DIV sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K subject to 6.2 and fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy gy [ fy+ m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m [fy+ Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy + v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, m ν 0 \J 0 m ν\ν 0 \K 0 e βx,yηx,y 0 for all x F, where β : X X R and η : X X R n are given functions.

21 2 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 55 The remarks and observations made earlier about the relationships between DI and DI are, of course, also valid for DIV and DIV. The next two theorems show that DIV is a dual problem for P. Theorem 6. Weak Duality. Let x and w y, v, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ν0, t, s be arbitrary feasible solutions of P and DIV, respectively, and assume that fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s 0, gy > 0, and any one of the following four sets of hypotheses is satisfied: a b c d i z Πz, y, v, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at y and γx, y>0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + m τ= ρ τ x, y 0; i z Πz, y, v, t, s is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, τ, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y; iii ρx, y + m τ= ρ τ x, y > 0; i z Πz, y, v, t, s is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, t, s is strictly α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ- pseudoinvex at y; iii ρx, y + m τ= ρ τ x, y 0; i z Πz, y, v, t, s is prestrictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-quasiinvex at y and γx, y > 0; ii for each τ M, z Λ τ z, v, τ, s is α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-quasiinvex at y, and for each τ M 2, z Λ τ z, v, τ, s is strictly α, β, γ τ, η, ρ τ, θ-pseudoinvex at y, where {M, M 2 } is a partition of M; iii ρx, y + m τ= ρ τ x, y 0. Then ϕx ψw, where ψ is the objective function of DIV. Proof. a: It is clear that 6. can be expressed as follows: 6.3 gy [ fy + m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy + Since for each τ M, M [ τ= v m G jm y, t m m J τ + v m H km y, s m = 0. m K τ

22 56 G.J. Zalmai 22 Λ τ x, v, t, s = m J τ v m G jm x, t m + m K τ v m H km x, s m 0 by the primal feasibility of x and positivity of v m, m ν 0 m J τ v m G jm y, t m + m K τ v m H km y, s m by 6.2 = Λ τ y, v, t, s, it follows that αx, y γ τ x, y e αx,y[λτ x,v, t, s Λ τ y,v, t, s 0, which in view of ii implies that v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y m J τ m K τ ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. Summing over τ, we obtain M [ 6.4 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y τ= m J τ m K τ M ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. Combining 6.3 and 6.4, and using iii we get gy [ fy + m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m M [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy, e βx,yηx,y ρ τ x, y θx, y 2 which by virtue of i implies that αx, y γx, y e αx,y[πx,y,v, t, s Πy,y,v, t, s 0. τ= τ= ρx, y θx, y 2, Since γx, y > 0, we can deduce from this inequality that Πx, y, v, t, s Πy, y, v, t, s = 0, where the equality follows from the definitions of Π and Λ 0. Therefore, we have 0 Πx, y, v, t, s = gy [fx+ m J0 v m G jm x, t m + v m H km x, s m [fy+λ 0 y, v, t, sgx gyfx [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, sgx by the primal feasibility of x.

23 23 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 57 Hence, we get the desired inequality ϕx = fx gx fy + Λ 0y, v, t, s = ψw. gy b: The proof is similar to that of part a. c: Suppose to the contrary that ϕx < ψw. This means that gyfx [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, sgx < 0. Using this inequality and keeping in mind that v m > 0 for each m ν 0, we have Πx, y,v, t, s = gy [fx + m J0 v m G jm x, t m + v m H km x, s m [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, sgx gyfx [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, sgx by the primal feasibility of x < 0 = Πy, y, u, v, t, s by the definitions of Π and Λ 0, and hence αx, y γx, y e αx,y[πx,y,v, t, s Πy,y,v, t, s < 0, which in view of i implies that 6.5 gy [ fy + m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy, e βx,yηx,y ρx, y θx, y 2. As shown in the proof of part a, for each τ M, we have Λ τ x, v, t, s Λ τ y, v, t, s, and hence αx, y γ τ x, y e αx,y[λτ x,v, t, s Λ τ y,v, t, s 0, which in view of ii implies that v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y m J τ m K τ Summing over τ, we obtain < ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. M [ v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y τ= m J τ m K τ M < ρ τ x, y θx, y 2. τ= Combining this inequality with 6.3 and using iii, we get

24 58 G.J. Zalmai 24 gy [ fy + m J0 v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m M [fy + Λ 0 y, v, t, s gy, e βx,yηx,y > ρ τ x, y θx, y 2 τ= ρx, y θx, y 2, which contradicts 6.5. Therefore, we conclude that ϕx ψw. d: The proof is similar to that of part c. Theorem 6.2 Strong Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P and assume that any one of the four sets of conditions set forth in Theorem 6. is satisfied for all feasible solutions of DIV. Then there exist v, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that w x, v, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is an optimal solution of DIV and ϕx = ψw. Proof. a: Since x is a normal optimal solution of P, by Theorem 2.2, there exist v, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that gx fx fx gx + ν0 ν v m G jm x, t m + + v m H km x, s m =0. m=ν0 m= From this equation and the fact that x F and t m ˆT jm x for each m ν 0, it is easily seen that 6.6 gx [ fx + m J0 vm G jm x, t m + vm H km x, s m [fx + Λ 0 x, v, t, s gx + vm G jm x, t m m ν 0 \J m J τ v mg jm x, t m + + m ν\ν 0 \K 0 v m H km x, s m = 0, m K τ v mh km x, s m = 0, τ M {0}, 6.8 ϕx = fx + Λ 0 x, v, t, s gx, where vm = v m /gx for each m J 0 K 0, and vm = v m for each m ν\j 0 K 0. From 6.6 and 6.7 it is clear that w is a feasible solution of DIV. From 6.8 we see that ϕx = ψw and hence the optimality of w for DIV follows from Theorem 6.. b d: The proofs are similar to that of part a.

25 25 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 59 Theorem 6.3 Strict Converse Duality. Let x be a normal optimal solution of P, let w = x, ṽ, ν, ν 0, J ν0, K ν\ ν0, t, s be an optimal solution of DIV, and assume that any one of the following four sets of conditions holds: a The assumptions specified in part a of Theorem 6. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIV, and z Πz, x, ṽ, t, s is strictly α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvex at x; b The assumptions specified in part b of Theorem 6. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIV, and z Πz, x, ṽ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ- quasiinvex at x; c The assumptions specified in part c of Theorem 6. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIV, and z Πz, x, ṽ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ- quasiinvex at x; d The assumptions specified in part d of Theorem 6. are satisfied for the feasible solution w of DIV, and z Πz, x, ṽ, t, s is α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ- quasiinvex at x. Then x = x and ϕx = ψ w. Proof. a: Suppose to the contrary that x x. Since x is a normal optimal solution of P, by Theorem 6.2, there exist v, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, and s such that w x, v, ν, ν0, J ν0, K ν \ν0, t, s is a feasible solution of DIV and ϕx = ψw. Now, proceeding as in the proof of part a of Theorem 6. with x replaced by x and w by w, we arrive at the inequality g x [ f i x + m J0 ṽ m G jm x, t m + ṽ m H km x, s m [f x + Λ 0 x, ṽ, t, s g x, e βx, xηx, x ρx, x θx, x 2, βx, x which by virtue of our strict α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-pseudoinvexity assumption implies that αx, x γx, x e Πx, x,ṽ, t, s Π x, x,ṽ, t, s > 0. Since γx, x > 0, this inequality implies that Πx, x, ṽ, t, s > Π x, x, ṽ, t, s = 0. In view of the primal feasibility of x, this inequality reduces to and so we get g xfx [f x + Λ 0 x, ṽ, t, sgx > 0, ϕx = fx gx > f x + Λ 0 x, ṽ, t, s = ψ w, g x

26 60 G.J. Zalmai 26 which contradicts the fact that ϕx = ψw ψ w. Hence x = x and ϕx = ψ w. b d: The proofs are similar to that of part a. As pointed out earlier, the duality models DIV and DIV can be viewed as two families of nonparametric dual problems for P whose members can easily be identified by appropriate choices of the partitioning sets J µ and K µ, µ M {0}. In particular, if we let J 0 = ν 0 and K 0 = ν\ν 0, then we see that DIV and DIV reduce to the following dual problems for P : DIV a subject to [ gy fy + where sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K ν 0 m= Λy, v, t, s = v m G jm y, t m + ν 0 m= DIV a sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K subject to [ gy fy + ν 0 m= fy + Λy, v, t, s gy ν m=ν 0 + v m G jm y, t m + v m H km y, s m [fy + Λy, v, t, s gy = 0, ν m=ν 0 + fy + Λy, v, t, s gy v m G jm y, t m + ν m=ν 0 + v m H km y, s m ; v m H km y, s m [fy + Λy, v, t, s gy, e βx,yηx,y 0 for all x F, where β is a function from X X to R and η is a function from X X to R n. Similarly, if we choose J 0 = and K 0 =, then we obtain the following dual problems for P : DIV b subject to sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K gy fy fy gy ν 0 m= m J τ v m G jm y, t m + fy gy v m G jm y, t m + ν m=ν 0 + m K τ v m H km y, s m 0, τ M; v m H km y, s m = 0;

27 27 Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions. Part II 6 DIV b sup y,v,ν,ν 0,J ν0,k ν\ν0, t, s K fy gy subject to 6.9 and gy fy fy gy + + ν m=ν 0 + ν 0 m= v m G jm y, t m v m H km y, s m, e βx,yηx,y 0 for all x F, where β is a function from X X to R and η is a function from X X to R n. In this manner, one can easily identify many other special cases of DIV and DIV. The dual problems DIV a, DIV a, DIV b, and DIV b are the semiinfinite versions of some popular dual problems that have been investigated previously in the area of fractional programming. Evidently, one can easily specialize and restate Theorems for these special cases of DIV and DIV. 7. CONCLUDING REMARKS In this study, we have constructed six first-order parametric and two firstorder nonparametric duality models and established a fairly large number of duality results under various generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invexity hypotheses for a semiinfinite fractional programming problem. It appears that all these results are new in the area of semiinfinite programming. Furthermore, the style and techniques employed in this paper can be utilized to establish similar duality results for some other classes of related optimization problems. For example, it seems reasonable to expect that a similar approach can be used to investigate the optimality and duality aspects of the following classes of semiinfinite continuous minmax and multiobjective fractional programming problems: Minimize x F Minimize x F max y Y fx, y gx, y, f x g x,..., f px g p x We shall investigate these classes of semiinfinite programming problems in subsequent papers..

28 62 G.J. Zalmai 28 REFERENCES [ B. Mond and T. Weir, Generalized concavity and duality. In: Generalized Concavity in Optimization and Economics, S. Schaible and W.T. Ziemba Eds.. Academic Press, New York, 98, pp [2 G.J. Zalmai, Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions in semiinfinite fractional programming. Part I: Optimality conditions. Submitted to Rev. Roumaine Math. Pures Appl. [3 G.J. Zalmai, Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions in semiinfinite fractional programming. Part III: Second-order duality models. Submitted to Rev. Roumaine Math. Pures Appl. [4 G.J. Zalmai, Generalized α, β, γ, η, ρ, θ-invex functions in semiinfinite fractional programming. Part IV: Higher-order duality models. unpublished manuscript. [5 G.J. Zalmai and Qinghong Zhang, Generalized F, β, φ, ρ, θ-univex functions and optimality conditions in semiinfinite fractional programming, J. Interdiscip. Math , Received 4 May 202 Northern Michigan University Department of Mathematics and Computer Science Marquette, MI 49855, USA gzalmai@nmu.edu

Further Study on Strong Lagrangian Duality Property for Invex Programs via Penalty Functions 1

Further Study on Strong Lagrangian Duality Property for Invex Programs via Penalty Functions 1 Further Study on Strong Lagrangian Duality Property for Invex Programs via Penalty Functions 1 J. Zhang Institute of Applied Mathematics, Chongqing University of Posts and Telecommunications, Chongqing

More information

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1 Chapter 3 Continuity In this chapter we begin by defining the fundamental notion of continuity for real valued functions of a single real variable. When trying to decide whether a given function is or

More information

Duality of linear conic problems

Duality of linear conic problems Duality of linear conic problems Alexander Shapiro and Arkadi Nemirovski Abstract It is well known that the optimal values of a linear programming problem and its dual are equal to each other if at least

More information

2.3 Convex Constrained Optimization Problems

2.3 Convex Constrained Optimization Problems 42 CHAPTER 2. FUNDAMENTAL CONCEPTS IN CONVEX OPTIMIZATION Theorem 15 Let f : R n R and h : R R. Consider g(x) = h(f(x)) for all x R n. The function g is convex if either of the following two conditions

More information

No: 10 04. Bilkent University. Monotonic Extension. Farhad Husseinov. Discussion Papers. Department of Economics

No: 10 04. Bilkent University. Monotonic Extension. Farhad Husseinov. Discussion Papers. Department of Economics No: 10 04 Bilkent University Monotonic Extension Farhad Husseinov Discussion Papers Department of Economics The Discussion Papers of the Department of Economics are intended to make the initial results

More information

Convex Programming Tools for Disjunctive Programs

Convex Programming Tools for Disjunctive Programs Convex Programming Tools for Disjunctive Programs João Soares, Departamento de Matemática, Universidade de Coimbra, Portugal Abstract A Disjunctive Program (DP) is a mathematical program whose feasible

More information

Practice with Proofs

Practice with Proofs Practice with Proofs October 6, 2014 Recall the following Definition 0.1. A function f is increasing if for every x, y in the domain of f, x < y = f(x) < f(y) 1. Prove that h(x) = x 3 is increasing, using

More information

FACTORING POLYNOMIALS IN THE RING OF FORMAL POWER SERIES OVER Z

FACTORING POLYNOMIALS IN THE RING OF FORMAL POWER SERIES OVER Z FACTORING POLYNOMIALS IN THE RING OF FORMAL POWER SERIES OVER Z DANIEL BIRMAJER, JUAN B GIL, AND MICHAEL WEINER Abstract We consider polynomials with integer coefficients and discuss their factorization

More information

Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones

Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 9 (2002), No. 1, 301 307 Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones Walter Roth Department of Mathematics, Universiti Brunei Darussalam, Gadong BE1410, Brunei Darussalam

More information

Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions

Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions KC Border October 2004 Revised January 2009 Let A be a subset of R m

More information

FIRST YEAR CALCULUS. Chapter 7 CONTINUITY. It is a parabola, and we can draw this parabola without lifting our pencil from the paper.

FIRST YEAR CALCULUS. Chapter 7 CONTINUITY. It is a parabola, and we can draw this parabola without lifting our pencil from the paper. FIRST YEAR CALCULUS WWLCHENW L c WWWL W L Chen, 1982, 2008. 2006. This chapter originates from material used by the author at Imperial College, University of London, between 1981 and 1990. It It is is

More information

ALMOST COMMON PRIORS 1. INTRODUCTION

ALMOST COMMON PRIORS 1. INTRODUCTION ALMOST COMMON PRIORS ZIV HELLMAN ABSTRACT. What happens when priors are not common? We introduce a measure for how far a type space is from having a common prior, which we term prior distance. If a type

More information

I. GROUPS: BASIC DEFINITIONS AND EXAMPLES

I. GROUPS: BASIC DEFINITIONS AND EXAMPLES I GROUPS: BASIC DEFINITIONS AND EXAMPLES Definition 1: An operation on a set G is a function : G G G Definition 2: A group is a set G which is equipped with an operation and a special element e G, called

More information

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces D. R. Wilkins Academic Year 1996-7 9 Vector Spaces A vector space over some field K is an algebraic structure consisting of a set V on which are

More information

MA651 Topology. Lecture 6. Separation Axioms.

MA651 Topology. Lecture 6. Separation Axioms. MA651 Topology. Lecture 6. Separation Axioms. This text is based on the following books: Fundamental concepts of topology by Peter O Neil Elements of Mathematics: General Topology by Nicolas Bourbaki Counterexamples

More information

Adaptive Online Gradient Descent

Adaptive Online Gradient Descent Adaptive Online Gradient Descent Peter L Bartlett Division of Computer Science Department of Statistics UC Berkeley Berkeley, CA 94709 bartlett@csberkeleyedu Elad Hazan IBM Almaden Research Center 650

More information

10. Proximal point method

10. Proximal point method L. Vandenberghe EE236C Spring 2013-14) 10. Proximal point method proximal point method augmented Lagrangian method Moreau-Yosida smoothing 10-1 Proximal point method a conceptual algorithm for minimizing

More information

24. The Branch and Bound Method

24. The Branch and Bound Method 24. The Branch and Bound Method It has serious practical consequences if it is known that a combinatorial problem is NP-complete. Then one can conclude according to the present state of science that no

More information

3. Mathematical Induction

3. Mathematical Induction 3. MATHEMATICAL INDUCTION 83 3. Mathematical Induction 3.1. First Principle of Mathematical Induction. Let P (n) be a predicate with domain of discourse (over) the natural numbers N = {0, 1,,...}. If (1)

More information

HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS. n!f n (1) lim. ln x n! + xn x. 1 = G n 1 (x). (2) k + 1 n. (n 1)!

HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS. n!f n (1) lim. ln x n! + xn x. 1 = G n 1 (x). (2) k + 1 n. (n 1)! Math 7 Fall 205 HOMEWORK 5 SOLUTIONS Problem. 2008 B2 Let F 0 x = ln x. For n 0 and x > 0, let F n+ x = 0 F ntdt. Evaluate n!f n lim n ln n. By directly computing F n x for small n s, we obtain the following

More information

BANACH AND HILBERT SPACE REVIEW

BANACH AND HILBERT SPACE REVIEW BANACH AND HILBET SPACE EVIEW CHISTOPHE HEIL These notes will briefly review some basic concepts related to the theory of Banach and Hilbert spaces. We are not trying to give a complete development, but

More information

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES 1. The derivative of a function. Differentiation rules 1.1. The slope of a curve. The slope of a curve at a point P is a measure of the steepness of the curve. If Q is a point on the

More information

MATH 425, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS.

MATH 425, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS. MATH 45, PRACTICE FINAL EXAM SOLUTIONS. Exercise. a Is the operator L defined on smooth functions of x, y by L u := u xx + cosu linear? b Does the answer change if we replace the operator L by the operator

More information

How To Know If A Domain Is Unique In An Octempo (Euclidean) Or Not (Ecl)

How To Know If A Domain Is Unique In An Octempo (Euclidean) Or Not (Ecl) Subsets of Euclidean domains possessing a unique division algorithm Andrew D. Lewis 2009/03/16 Abstract Subsets of a Euclidean domain are characterised with the following objectives: (1) ensuring uniqueness

More information

LINEAR ALGEBRA W W L CHEN

LINEAR ALGEBRA W W L CHEN LINEAR ALGEBRA W W L CHEN c W W L Chen, 1997, 2008 This chapter is available free to all individuals, on understanding that it is not to be used for financial gain, and may be downloaded and/or photocopied,

More information

Duality in General Programs. Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725

Duality in General Programs. Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725 Duality in General Programs Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725 1 Last time: duality in linear programs Given c R n, A R m n, b R m, G R r n, h R r : min x R n c T x max u R m, v R r b T

More information

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Dan Collins The textbook defines a subspace of a vector space in Chapter 4, but it avoids ever discussing the notion of a quotient space. This is understandable

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

Duality in Linear Programming

Duality in Linear Programming Duality in Linear Programming 4 In the preceding chapter on sensitivity analysis, we saw that the shadow-price interpretation of the optimal simplex multipliers is a very useful concept. First, these shadow

More information

Research Article Stability Analysis for Higher-Order Adjacent Derivative in Parametrized Vector Optimization

Research Article Stability Analysis for Higher-Order Adjacent Derivative in Parametrized Vector Optimization Hindawi Publishing Corporation Journal of Inequalities and Applications Volume 2010, Article ID 510838, 15 pages doi:10.1155/2010/510838 Research Article Stability Analysis for Higher-Order Adjacent Derivative

More information

Inner Product Spaces

Inner Product Spaces Math 571 Inner Product Spaces 1. Preliminaries An inner product space is a vector space V along with a function, called an inner product which associates each pair of vectors u, v with a scalar u, v, and

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES Contents 1. Random variables and measurable functions 2. Cumulative distribution functions 3. Discrete

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

THE BANACH CONTRACTION PRINCIPLE. Contents

THE BANACH CONTRACTION PRINCIPLE. Contents THE BANACH CONTRACTION PRINCIPLE ALEX PONIECKI Abstract. This paper will study contractions of metric spaces. To do this, we will mainly use tools from topology. We will give some examples of contractions,

More information

WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT?

WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT? WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT? introduction Many students seem to have trouble with the notion of a mathematical proof. People that come to a course like Math 216, who certainly

More information

Mathematical Induction

Mathematical Induction Mathematical Induction (Handout March 8, 01) The Principle of Mathematical Induction provides a means to prove infinitely many statements all at once The principle is logical rather than strictly mathematical,

More information

1 Introduction. Linear Programming. Questions. A general optimization problem is of the form: choose x to. max f(x) subject to x S. where.

1 Introduction. Linear Programming. Questions. A general optimization problem is of the form: choose x to. max f(x) subject to x S. where. Introduction Linear Programming Neil Laws TT 00 A general optimization problem is of the form: choose x to maximise f(x) subject to x S where x = (x,..., x n ) T, f : R n R is the objective function, S

More information

15 Kuhn -Tucker conditions

15 Kuhn -Tucker conditions 5 Kuhn -Tucker conditions Consider a version of the consumer problem in which quasilinear utility x 2 + 4 x 2 is maximised subject to x +x 2 =. Mechanically applying the Lagrange multiplier/common slopes

More information

1 Norms and Vector Spaces

1 Norms and Vector Spaces 008.10.07.01 1 Norms and Vector Spaces Suppose we have a complex vector space V. A norm is a function f : V R which satisfies (i) f(x) 0 for all x V (ii) f(x + y) f(x) + f(y) for all x,y V (iii) f(λx)

More information

3. INNER PRODUCT SPACES

3. INNER PRODUCT SPACES . INNER PRODUCT SPACES.. Definition So far we have studied abstract vector spaces. These are a generalisation of the geometric spaces R and R. But these have more structure than just that of a vector space.

More information

How To Factorize Of Finite Abelian Groups By A Cyclic Subset Of A Finite Group

How To Factorize Of Finite Abelian Groups By A Cyclic Subset Of A Finite Group Comment.Math.Univ.Carolin. 51,1(2010) 1 8 1 A Hajós type result on factoring finite abelian groups by subsets II Keresztély Corrádi, Sándor Szabó Abstract. It is proved that if a finite abelian group is

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ALGEBRA VIA PROPER MAPS

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ALGEBRA VIA PROPER MAPS THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ALGEBRA VIA PROPER MAPS KEITH CONRAD 1. Introduction The Fundamental Theorem of Algebra says every nonconstant polynomial with complex coefficients can be factored into linear

More information

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88 The Heat Equation Lectures INF232 p. 1/88 Lectures INF232 p. 2/88 The Heat Equation We study the heat equation: u t = u xx for x (,1), t >, (1) u(,t) = u(1,t) = for t >, (2) u(x,) = f(x) for x (,1), (3)

More information

Section 4.2: The Division Algorithm and Greatest Common Divisors

Section 4.2: The Division Algorithm and Greatest Common Divisors Section 4.2: The Division Algorithm and Greatest Common Divisors The Division Algorithm The Division Algorithm is merely long division restated as an equation. For example, the division 29 r. 20 32 948

More information

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory In this lecture we go on considering a general equilibrium model of a private ownership economy. In contrast to the Notes IV, we focus on positive issues such

More information

Chapter 4, Arithmetic in F [x] Polynomial arithmetic and the division algorithm.

Chapter 4, Arithmetic in F [x] Polynomial arithmetic and the division algorithm. Chapter 4, Arithmetic in F [x] Polynomial arithmetic and the division algorithm. We begin by defining the ring of polynomials with coefficients in a ring R. After some preliminary results, we specialize

More information

8 Divisibility and prime numbers

8 Divisibility and prime numbers 8 Divisibility and prime numbers 8.1 Divisibility In this short section we extend the concept of a multiple from the natural numbers to the integers. We also summarize several other terms that express

More information

The Mean Value Theorem

The Mean Value Theorem The Mean Value Theorem THEOREM (The Extreme Value Theorem): If f is continuous on a closed interval [a, b], then f attains an absolute maximum value f(c) and an absolute minimum value f(d) at some numbers

More information

1. Prove that the empty set is a subset of every set.

1. Prove that the empty set is a subset of every set. 1. Prove that the empty set is a subset of every set. Basic Topology Written by Men-Gen Tsai email: b89902089@ntu.edu.tw Proof: For any element x of the empty set, x is also an element of every set since

More information

Date: April 12, 2001. Contents

Date: April 12, 2001. Contents 2 Lagrange Multipliers Date: April 12, 2001 Contents 2.1. Introduction to Lagrange Multipliers......... p. 2 2.2. Enhanced Fritz John Optimality Conditions...... p. 12 2.3. Informative Lagrange Multipliers...........

More information

MATH10040 Chapter 2: Prime and relatively prime numbers

MATH10040 Chapter 2: Prime and relatively prime numbers MATH10040 Chapter 2: Prime and relatively prime numbers Recall the basic definition: 1. Prime numbers Definition 1.1. Recall that a positive integer is said to be prime if it has precisely two positive

More information

F. ABTAHI and M. ZARRIN. (Communicated by J. Goldstein)

F. ABTAHI and M. ZARRIN. (Communicated by J. Goldstein) Journal of Algerian Mathematical Society Vol. 1, pp. 1 6 1 CONCERNING THE l p -CONJECTURE FOR DISCRETE SEMIGROUPS F. ABTAHI and M. ZARRIN (Communicated by J. Goldstein) Abstract. For 2 < p

More information

1 The Concept of a Mapping

1 The Concept of a Mapping Arkansas Tech University MATH 4033: Elementary Modern Algebra Dr. Marcel B. Finan 1 The Concept of a Mapping The concept of a mapping (aka function) is important throughout mathematics. We have been dealing

More information

Prime Numbers and Irreducible Polynomials

Prime Numbers and Irreducible Polynomials Prime Numbers and Irreducible Polynomials M. Ram Murty The similarity between prime numbers and irreducible polynomials has been a dominant theme in the development of number theory and algebraic geometry.

More information

ON SEQUENTIAL CONTINUITY OF COMPOSITION MAPPING. 0. Introduction

ON SEQUENTIAL CONTINUITY OF COMPOSITION MAPPING. 0. Introduction ON SEQUENTIAL CONTINUITY OF COMPOSITION MAPPING Abstract. In [1] there was proved a theorem concerning the continuity of the composition mapping, and there was announced a theorem on sequential continuity

More information

1 Formulating The Low Degree Testing Problem

1 Formulating The Low Degree Testing Problem 6.895 PCP and Hardness of Approximation MIT, Fall 2010 Lecture 5: Linearity Testing Lecturer: Dana Moshkovitz Scribe: Gregory Minton and Dana Moshkovitz In the last lecture, we proved a weak PCP Theorem,

More information

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics Chapter 7 Metric Spaces A metric space is a set X that has a notion of the distance d(x, y) between every pair of points x, y X. The purpose of this chapter is to introduce metric spaces and give some

More information

A NEW LOOK AT CONVEX ANALYSIS AND OPTIMIZATION

A NEW LOOK AT CONVEX ANALYSIS AND OPTIMIZATION 1 A NEW LOOK AT CONVEX ANALYSIS AND OPTIMIZATION Dimitri Bertsekas M.I.T. FEBRUARY 2003 2 OUTLINE Convexity issues in optimization Historical remarks Our treatment of the subject Three unifying lines of

More information

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm Lecture notes prepared for MATH 326, Spring 997 Department of Mathematics and Statistics University at Albany William F Hammond Table of Contents Introduction

More information

ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION. E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska

ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION. E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska Pliska Stud. Math. Bulgar. 22 (2015), STUDIA MATHEMATICA BULGARICA ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska Smirnov (1949) derived four

More information

Quotient Rings and Field Extensions

Quotient Rings and Field Extensions Chapter 5 Quotient Rings and Field Extensions In this chapter we describe a method for producing field extension of a given field. If F is a field, then a field extension is a field K that contains F.

More information

INTRODUCTORY SET THEORY

INTRODUCTORY SET THEORY M.Sc. program in mathematics INTRODUCTORY SET THEORY Katalin Károlyi Department of Applied Analysis, Eötvös Loránd University H-1088 Budapest, Múzeum krt. 6-8. CONTENTS 1. SETS Set, equal sets, subset,

More information

Factoring & Primality

Factoring & Primality Factoring & Primality Lecturer: Dimitris Papadopoulos In this lecture we will discuss the problem of integer factorization and primality testing, two problems that have been the focus of a great amount

More information

Integer roots of quadratic and cubic polynomials with integer coefficients

Integer roots of quadratic and cubic polynomials with integer coefficients Integer roots of quadratic and cubic polynomials with integer coefficients Konstantine Zelator Mathematics, Computer Science and Statistics 212 Ben Franklin Hall Bloomsburg University 400 East Second Street

More information

Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO

Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO R. L. Johnson and C. J. Neugebauer The main result says that a non-negative BMO-function w, whose reciprocal is also in BMO, belongs to p> A p,and

More information

Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming

Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming Marcel Oliver Revised: April, 0 The basic steps of the simplex algorithm Step : Write the linear programming problem in standard form Linear

More information

k, then n = p2α 1 1 pα k

k, then n = p2α 1 1 pα k Powers of Integers An integer n is a perfect square if n = m for some integer m. Taking into account the prime factorization, if m = p α 1 1 pα k k, then n = pα 1 1 p α k k. That is, n is a perfect square

More information

Quasi-static evolution and congested transport

Quasi-static evolution and congested transport Quasi-static evolution and congested transport Inwon Kim Joint with Damon Alexander, Katy Craig and Yao Yao UCLA, UW Madison Hard congestion in crowd motion The following crowd motion model is proposed

More information

SECTION 10-2 Mathematical Induction

SECTION 10-2 Mathematical Induction 73 0 Sequences and Series 6. Approximate e 0. using the first five terms of the series. Compare this approximation with your calculator evaluation of e 0.. 6. Approximate e 0.5 using the first five terms

More information

Critical points of once continuously differentiable functions are important because they are the only points that can be local maxima or minima.

Critical points of once continuously differentiable functions are important because they are the only points that can be local maxima or minima. Lecture 0: Convexity and Optimization We say that if f is a once continuously differentiable function on an interval I, and x is a point in the interior of I that x is a critical point of f if f (x) =

More information

CONTINUED FRACTIONS AND PELL S EQUATION. Contents 1. Continued Fractions 1 2. Solution to Pell s Equation 9 References 12

CONTINUED FRACTIONS AND PELL S EQUATION. Contents 1. Continued Fractions 1 2. Solution to Pell s Equation 9 References 12 CONTINUED FRACTIONS AND PELL S EQUATION SEUNG HYUN YANG Abstract. In this REU paper, I will use some important characteristics of continued fractions to give the complete set of solutions to Pell s equation.

More information

t := maxγ ν subject to ν {0,1,2,...} and f(x c +γ ν d) f(x c )+cγ ν f (x c ;d).

t := maxγ ν subject to ν {0,1,2,...} and f(x c +γ ν d) f(x c )+cγ ν f (x c ;d). 1. Line Search Methods Let f : R n R be given and suppose that x c is our current best estimate of a solution to P min x R nf(x). A standard method for improving the estimate x c is to choose a direction

More information

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4 Economics 00a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4 1.1. Quantity Discounts and the Budget Constraint (a) The only distinction between the budget line with

More information

Inner product. Definition of inner product

Inner product. Definition of inner product Math 20F Linear Algebra Lecture 25 1 Inner product Review: Definition of inner product. Slide 1 Norm and distance. Orthogonal vectors. Orthogonal complement. Orthogonal basis. Definition of inner product

More information

So let us begin our quest to find the holy grail of real analysis.

So let us begin our quest to find the holy grail of real analysis. 1 Section 5.2 The Complete Ordered Field: Purpose of Section We present an axiomatic description of the real numbers as a complete ordered field. The axioms which describe the arithmetic of the real numbers

More information

PYTHAGOREAN TRIPLES KEITH CONRAD

PYTHAGOREAN TRIPLES KEITH CONRAD PYTHAGOREAN TRIPLES KEITH CONRAD 1. Introduction A Pythagorean triple is a triple of positive integers (a, b, c) where a + b = c. Examples include (3, 4, 5), (5, 1, 13), and (8, 15, 17). Below is an ancient

More information

Math 319 Problem Set #3 Solution 21 February 2002

Math 319 Problem Set #3 Solution 21 February 2002 Math 319 Problem Set #3 Solution 21 February 2002 1. ( 2.1, problem 15) Find integers a 1, a 2, a 3, a 4, a 5 such that every integer x satisfies at least one of the congruences x a 1 (mod 2), x a 2 (mod

More information

NOTES ON LINEAR TRANSFORMATIONS

NOTES ON LINEAR TRANSFORMATIONS NOTES ON LINEAR TRANSFORMATIONS Definition 1. Let V and W be vector spaces. A function T : V W is a linear transformation from V to W if the following two properties hold. i T v + v = T v + T v for all

More information

Scheduling Real-time Tasks: Algorithms and Complexity

Scheduling Real-time Tasks: Algorithms and Complexity Scheduling Real-time Tasks: Algorithms and Complexity Sanjoy Baruah The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Email: baruah@cs.unc.edu Joël Goossens Université Libre de Bruxelles Email: joel.goossens@ulb.ac.be

More information

Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski.

Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski. Discussion on the paper Hypotheses testing by convex optimization by A. Goldenschluger, A. Juditsky and A. Nemirovski. Fabienne Comte, Celine Duval, Valentine Genon-Catalot To cite this version: Fabienne

More information

Numerical Verification of Optimality Conditions in Optimal Control Problems

Numerical Verification of Optimality Conditions in Optimal Control Problems Numerical Verification of Optimality Conditions in Optimal Control Problems Dissertation zur Erlangung des naturwissenschaftlichen Doktorgrades der Julius-Maximilians-Universität Würzburg vorgelegt von

More information

CHAPTER SIX IRREDUCIBILITY AND FACTORIZATION 1. BASIC DIVISIBILITY THEORY

CHAPTER SIX IRREDUCIBILITY AND FACTORIZATION 1. BASIC DIVISIBILITY THEORY January 10, 2010 CHAPTER SIX IRREDUCIBILITY AND FACTORIZATION 1. BASIC DIVISIBILITY THEORY The set of polynomials over a field F is a ring, whose structure shares with the ring of integers many characteristics.

More information

CHAPTER 9. Integer Programming

CHAPTER 9. Integer Programming CHAPTER 9 Integer Programming An integer linear program (ILP) is, by definition, a linear program with the additional constraint that all variables take integer values: (9.1) max c T x s t Ax b and x integral

More information

Introduction to Finite Fields (cont.)

Introduction to Finite Fields (cont.) Chapter 6 Introduction to Finite Fields (cont.) 6.1 Recall Theorem. Z m is a field m is a prime number. Theorem (Subfield Isomorphic to Z p ). Every finite field has the order of a power of a prime number

More information

Integrating Benders decomposition within Constraint Programming

Integrating Benders decomposition within Constraint Programming Integrating Benders decomposition within Constraint Programming Hadrien Cambazard, Narendra Jussien email: {hcambaza,jussien}@emn.fr École des Mines de Nantes, LINA CNRS FRE 2729 4 rue Alfred Kastler BP

More information

minimal polyonomial Example

minimal polyonomial Example Minimal Polynomials Definition Let α be an element in GF(p e ). We call the monic polynomial of smallest degree which has coefficients in GF(p) and α as a root, the minimal polyonomial of α. Example: We

More information

Recovery of primal solutions from dual subgradient methods for mixed binary linear programming; a branch-and-bound approach

Recovery of primal solutions from dual subgradient methods for mixed binary linear programming; a branch-and-bound approach MASTER S THESIS Recovery of primal solutions from dual subgradient methods for mixed binary linear programming; a branch-and-bound approach PAULINE ALDENVIK MIRJAM SCHIERSCHER Department of Mathematical

More information

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Phoebus J. Dhrymes 1 July 2012 1 c Phoebus J. Dhrymes, 2012. Preliminary material; not to be cited or disseminated without the author s permission. 2 Contents

More information

Homework until Test #2

Homework until Test #2 MATH31: Number Theory Homework until Test # Philipp BRAUN Section 3.1 page 43, 1. It has been conjectured that there are infinitely many primes of the form n. Exhibit five such primes. Solution. Five such

More information

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture II August 25, 2011 Definition and : Lecture A Brief Brush with Duality Cobb-Douglas Cost Minimization Lagrangian for the Cobb-Douglas Solution

More information

Mathematical finance and linear programming (optimization)

Mathematical finance and linear programming (optimization) Mathematical finance and linear programming (optimization) Geir Dahl September 15, 2009 1 Introduction The purpose of this short note is to explain how linear programming (LP) (=linear optimization) may

More information

14.451 Lecture Notes 10

14.451 Lecture Notes 10 14.451 Lecture Notes 1 Guido Lorenzoni Fall 29 1 Continuous time: nite horizon Time goes from to T. Instantaneous payo : f (t; x (t) ; y (t)) ; (the time dependence includes discounting), where x (t) 2

More information

CHAPTER 5. Number Theory. 1. Integers and Division. Discussion

CHAPTER 5. Number Theory. 1. Integers and Division. Discussion CHAPTER 5 Number Theory 1. Integers and Division 1.1. Divisibility. Definition 1.1.1. Given two integers a and b we say a divides b if there is an integer c such that b = ac. If a divides b, we write a

More information

Student Outcomes. Lesson Notes. Classwork. Discussion (10 minutes)

Student Outcomes. Lesson Notes. Classwork. Discussion (10 minutes) NYS COMMON CORE MATHEMATICS CURRICULUM Lesson 5 8 Student Outcomes Students know the definition of a number raised to a negative exponent. Students simplify and write equivalent expressions that contain

More information

Notes on metric spaces

Notes on metric spaces Notes on metric spaces 1 Introduction The purpose of these notes is to quickly review some of the basic concepts from Real Analysis, Metric Spaces and some related results that will be used in this course.

More information

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}. Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 5, September 16 Outline 1 Walrasian Demand 2 Properties of Walrasian Demand 3 An Optimization Recipe 4 First and Second Order Conditions Definition Walrasian

More information

Chapter 5. Banach Spaces

Chapter 5. Banach Spaces 9 Chapter 5 Banach Spaces Many linear equations may be formulated in terms of a suitable linear operator acting on a Banach space. In this chapter, we study Banach spaces and linear operators acting on

More information

All trees contain a large induced subgraph having all degrees 1 (mod k)

All trees contain a large induced subgraph having all degrees 1 (mod k) All trees contain a large induced subgraph having all degrees 1 (mod k) David M. Berman, A.J. Radcliffe, A.D. Scott, Hong Wang, and Larry Wargo *Department of Mathematics University of New Orleans New

More information

A Little Set Theory (Never Hurt Anybody)

A Little Set Theory (Never Hurt Anybody) A Little Set Theory (Never Hurt Anybody) Matthew Saltzman Department of Mathematical Sciences Clemson University Draft: August 21, 2013 1 Introduction The fundamental ideas of set theory and the algebra

More information

Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations

Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations 1 Introduction Any linear programming problem can be rewritten in either of two standard forms. In the first form, the objective is to maximize, the material

More information