General Equilibrium. Partial equilibrium: a single-market story. Determine the market price of the output

Similar documents
Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Chapter 6: Pure Exchange

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand

UCLA. Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Economics 200B Part 1 UCSD Winter 2015 Prof. R. Starr, Mr. John Rehbeck Final Exam 1

Problem Set II: budget set, convexity

Working Paper Series

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

Modeling Insurance Markets

Lecture Notes 10

MATHEMATICAL INDUCTION. Mathematical Induction. This is a powerful method to prove properties of positive integers.

4.6 Linear Programming duality

160 CHAPTER 4. VECTOR SPACES

A public good is often defined to be a good that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable in consumption.

CITY AND REGIONAL PLANNING Consumer Behavior. Philip A. Viton. March 4, Introduction 2

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 15: Repeated Games and Cooperation

The Real Business Cycle Model

IMPLEMENTING ARROW-DEBREU EQUILIBRIA BY TRADING INFINITELY-LIVED SECURITIES

Gains from Trade. Christopher P. Chambers and Takashi Hayashi. March 25, Abstract

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Game Theory: Supermodular Games 1

14.41 Midterm Solutions

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem

Manipulability of the Price Mechanism for Data Centers

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton

Topics in Consumer Theory

The Envelope Theorem 1

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

THE DIMENSION OF A VECTOR SPACE

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

The Real Business Cycle model

Midterm March (a) Consumer i s budget constraint is. c i b i c i H 12 (1 + r)b i c i L 12 (1 + r)b i ;

Fixed Point Theorems

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade?

On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference

Fairness in Routing and Load Balancing

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Numerical Analysis Lecture Notes

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Alok Gupta. Dmitry Zhdanov

Quality Ladders, Competition and Endogenous Growth Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine

Lecture Notes in Microeconomics

Metric Spaces. Chapter Metrics

Chapter 4. Duality. 4.1 A Graphical Example

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Security Pools and Efficiency

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

Online Appendix to. Stability and Competitive Equilibrium in Trading Networks

MATH 304 Linear Algebra Lecture 20: Inner product spaces. Orthogonal sets.

Investigación Operativa. The uniform rule in the division problem

Constrained optimization.

A.2 The Prevalence of Transfer Pricing in International Trade

n k=1 k=0 1/k! = e. Example 6.4. The series 1/k 2 converges in R. Indeed, if s n = n then k=1 1/k, then s 2n s n = 1 n

Economics of Insurance

On the Existence of Nash Equilibrium in General Imperfectly Competitive Insurance Markets with Asymmetric Information

THE NON-EQUIVALENCE OF EXPORT AND IMPORT QUOTAS

Cost Minimization and the Cost Function

Methods for Finding Bases

Product Differentiation In homogeneous goods markets, price competition leads to perfectly competitive outcome, even with two firms Price competition

Lecture Note 10: General Equilibrium in a Pure Exchange Economy

Tiers, Preference Similarity, and the Limits on Stable Partners

Pricing of Limit Orders in the Electronic Security Trading System Xetra

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

Math 55: Discrete Mathematics

88 CHAPTER 2. VECTOR FUNCTIONS. . First, we need to compute T (s). a By definition, r (s) T (s) = 1 a sin s a. sin s a, cos s a

Lecture 1: OLG Models

Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations

Conditions for Efficiency in Package Pricing

The Mean Value Theorem

m i: is the mass of each particle

Mathematical finance and linear programming (optimization)

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

General Equilibrium. Jonathan Levin. November 2006

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Chapter 7. Sealed-bid Auctions

mod 10 = mod 10 = 49 mod 10 = 9.

Optimal Security Design

International Trade Lecture 3: The Ricardian Model (Theory)

On the Interaction and Competition among Internet Service Providers

The Optimal Path of Government Debt

Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour. Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Migration with Local Public Goods and the Gains from Changing Places

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Envelope Theorem. Kevin Wainwright. Mar 22, 2004

Application of Game Theory in Inventory Management

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Practice with Proofs

Optimal Nonlinear Income Taxation with a Finite Population

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

Public Goods & Externalities

1.2. Successive Differences

Duality in Linear Programming

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Transcription:

General Equilibrium Partial equilibrium: a single-market story Determine the market price of the output How are the input prices determined? Not answered. General equilibrium: All prices are determined simultaneously. All markets clear (aggregate demand = aggregate supply in all markets).

GE theory takes account of the functioning of all individual markets the interactions between markets Our plan of study GE in pure exchange economy: consumers with endowments; no producers GE in production economy: consumers + producers

GE in Exchange Economy Model environment: n markets for n goods. I agents with utility u i ( x i), where i = 1,, I. Each receives endowments of n goods. e i = ( e i 1, ei 2,, ei n) : vector of endowments for agent i, where e i j 0, for all j = 1,, n. x i = ( x i 1, xi 2,, xi n) : consumption bundle of agent i, where x i j 0, for all j = 1,, n.

Feasibility: For each type of goods, the total amount consumed is no more than the total endowments: I i=1 x i k I i=1 e i k, k = 1,, n. We assume that the utility function u i ( ) is continuous and strictly increasing; there exists a unique solution to the utility-maximization problem.

Walrasian equilibrium An agent i takes prices p = (p 1, p 2,, p n ) as given and chooses the consumption bundle x i = ( x i 1, xi 2,, xi n) to maximize utility: max x i u i ( x i ) s.t. p x i p e i. Optimal solution: x i ( p, p e i), Marshallian demand function. p e i : consumer i s wealth, market value of the initial endowment

Definition The aggregate excess demand function for good k is z k (p) I i=1 x i k ( p, p e i ) I i=1 e i k. The aggregate excess demand is z (p) = (z 1 (p), z 2 (p),, z n (p)).

Theorem 16 (Properties of Aggregate Excess Demand) The aggregate excess demand z (p) is a continuous function, and satisfies 1. homogeneity: z (λp) = z (p), λ > 0. 2. Walras law: p z (p) = 0.

Proof of Part 1 of Theorem 16 (Homogeneity) Given prices λp, an agent s utility-maximization problem is: max x i u i ( x i ) s.t. λp x i λp e i max x i u i ( x i ) s.t. p x i p e i. Therefore, the agent s problem is the same under prices λp as under p. Thus, x i ( λp, λp e i) = x i ( p, p e i).

It follows that ( λp, λp e i ) z k (λp) = i x i k ( p, p e i ) i e i k = i x i k i e i k = z k (p), k. Thus, z (λp) = z (p), λ > 0. QED

Proof of Part 2 of Theorem 16 (Walras law) For each agent, non-satiation implies that p x i = p e i at the optimum. Thus, That is, p (x i e i) = 0, i n { pk [ x i k ( p, p e i ) e i k ]} = 0, i k=1 Sum up the above equation over all agents i = 1,, I: I i=1 ( n k=1 { pk [ x i k ( p, p e i ) e i k ]}) = 0.

Reversing the order of summations, we get n k=1 ( I i=1 ( n I p k=1 k i=1 { pk [ x i k ( p, p e i ) e i k [( x i k ( p, p e i ) e i k ]} ) = 0 )] ) = 0 n k=1 p k z k (p) = 0 p z (p) = 0. QED

Corollary If vector p = ( p 1, p 2,, p n 1, p n) is such that prices p 1, p 2,, p n 1 clear n 1 markets, then p n must clear the nth market. Definition A vector p is called a Walrasian equilibrium if z (p ) = 0. In light of the Corollary, it is convenient to use the price of a certain good as the numeraire when solving for a Walrasian equilibrium. That is, set one of the good prices as one, and then solve for the rest n 1 equilibrium prices.

Theorem 17 (First Welfare Theorem) If u i ( ) is strictly increasing, then every Walrasian equilibrium is Pareto optimal. That is, given p, u i ( x i ( p, p e i)) u i ( x i), for all feasible x i x i ( p, p e i), where ">" holds for at least one i.

Proof of Theorem 17 Suppose there exist some allocations { x i} I i=1 such that u i ( x i) u i ( x i ( p, p e i)), where ">" holds for at least one agent i. Since u i ( ) is strictly increasing, it must be true that p x i p x i ( p, p e i), > holds for at least one i. Summing over all i, p ( I i=1 xi ) > p ( I i=1 xi ( p, p e i)) = p ( I i=1 ei ),

which is equivalent to ( n I k=1 p k i=1 xi k ) I i=1 ei k > 0. This contradicts the feasibility constraint: I i=1 xi k I i=1 ei k, k, given positive prices. Therefore, the supposition cannot be true. QED

Theorem 18 (Second Welfare Theorem) Any effi cient allocation can be sustainable by a competitive equilibrium, under certain assumptions. [Proof of the Second Welfare Theorem is not required for this course.] Despite the apparent symmetry, the first welfare theorem is much more general than the second one, requiring far weaker assumptions.

Example 2 goods; 20 agents with the same indirect utility function: v (p 1, p 2, y) = y3 p 1 p 2. 2 Endowments: 10 agents with e = (3, 1) and 10 with e = (1, 3). Normalize p 1 = 1. Calculate the Walrasian equilibrium price p 2.

Solution Calculate the individual Marshallian demand of good 1 using Roy s identity: x 1 (p 1, p 2, y) = v p 1 v y = y 3 p 2 1 p2 2 3y 2 p 1 p 2 2 = y 3p 1. Calculate the aggregate demand of good 1, using p 1 = 1: 10 3p 1 + p 2 + 10 p 1 + 3p 2 = 40 + 40p 2. 3p 1 3p 1 3

In the equilibrium, market of good 1 clears so that the aggregate demand is equal to aggregate supply. This implies 40 + 40p 2 3 = 40 p 2 = 2. [Note: One can also calculate the above price from the market-clearing condition for good 2.] [End of solution.]

Example Consider the same environment as in the previous Example. Now endowments: 10 agents with e = (3, 1) and 10 with e = (1, 2). Calculate the Walrasian equilibrium prices. (Normalize p 1 = 1.)

Solution From the previous example, the Marshallian demands are given by x 1 (p 1, p 2, y) = y 3p 1, x 2 (p 1, p 2, y) = 2y 3p 2. Given p 1 = 1, the market-clearing condition for good 1 implies: 10 3p 1 + p 2 3p 1 + 10 p 1 + 2p 2 3p 1 = 40 p 2 = 8 3. [Again, one can also calculate the above price from the market-clearing condition for good 2.] [End of solution.]

Example Consider a two-consumer, two-good exchange economy. Consumers have the following utility function: u (x 1, x 2 ) = min [x 1, x 2 ]. Endowments are e 1 = (5, 0) and 10 with e 2 = (0, 20). Does the Walrasian equilibrium exist in this economy? (Normalize p 1 = 1.)

Solution Let (x 1, x 2 ) be consumer 1 s Marshallian demand and (y 1, y 2 ) consumer 2 s Marshallian demand. Then let m i be a consumer s income, where i = 1, 2. Consider consumer 1 s utility-maximization problem: max (x 1,x 2 ) {min [x 1, x 2 ]}, s.t. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 m 1. First suppose x 1 x 2 at the optimum. Then the problem is simplified to max (x 1,x 2 ) x 1, s.t. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = m 1,

where the budget constraint must hold with equality because the objective function is strictly increasing. Then it is obvious that it is optimal to have x 1 = x 2, which solves for Now suppose x 1 x 2 simplified to x 1 = x 2 = m 1 p 1 + p 2 = m 1 1 + p 2. (1) at the optimum. Then the consumer s problem is max (x 1,x 2 ) x 2, s.t. p 1 x 1 + p 2 x 2 = m 1. By similar argument as in the first case, the optimal solutions are still given by (1). Therefore, consumer 1 Marshallian demands are indeed given by x 1 = x 2 = 5p 1 p 1 + p 2 = 5 1 + p 2.

Similarly, consumer 2 s Marshallian demands are y 1 = y 2 = 20p 2 p 1 + p 2 = 20p 2 1 + p 2, where consumer 1 s income is m 2 = 20p 2. The market-clearing condition for good 1 implies: 5 1 + p 2 + 20p 2 1 + p 2 = 5, p 2 = 0. Therefore, there does not exist any strictly positive price of good 2 that supports a Walrasian equilibrium. Hence no Walrasian equilibrium for this economy. [End of solution.]