Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4"

Transcription

1 Economics 00a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to Quantity Discounts and the Budget Constraint (a) The only distinction between the budget line with a quantity discount and an ordinary budget line is the change in price for purchases of x beyond Q* units. This change in price induces a change in slope of the budget line. Therefore, the budget line is piecewise linear with (1) slope = -p / q = -1 if 0 < x < Q*. () slope = -p / q = -1/4 if 0 > Q*. We now need to identify the y-intercept and point of change of slope to fully describe the budget constraint. y-intercept If the consumer purchases only good y, she can purchase W / q = 3 / 4 = 8 units. So, one boundary point for the budget constraint is point A = (0, 8). Change of slope The slope of the budget constraint changes at x = Q*. At x = Q*, the consumer spends 4Q* on good x and has wealth W 4Q* to spend on good y corresponding to a total of (W 4Q*) / q = 8 Q* units of y given that W = 3 and q = 4. That is, the point on the budget line where the price of x (and thus the slope of the budget line) changes is B = (Q*, 8 Q*). Piecewise Linear Budget Constraint The equation for the first (of two) linear segment of the budget constraint is y = y-intercept + slope * x, which in this case yields the equation y = 8 x. We can solve for the second linear segment of the budget constraint by using the equation y = constant + slope * x. We know that the slope of this second segment of the budget constraint is -1/4 and the and that it starts at the point B = (Q*, 8-Q*). This gives the equation 8-Q* = constant ¼ * Q* OR constant = 8 (3/4) Q* Thus, the second component of the budget constraint is given by y = 8 (3/4) Q* - (1/4) x.

2 With this as background, we can now substitute the appropriate values of Q* to find the budget constraints in (a1), (a), (a3). (a1) Component 1: Straight line y = 8 x between A = (0, 8) and B = (5, 3). Component : Straight line y = (17 x) / 4 between B = (5, 3) and C = (17, 0). (a) Component 1: Straight line y = 8 x between A = (0, 8) and B = (16/3, 3). Component : Straight line y = 4 x/4 between B = (16/3, 8/3) and C = (16, 0). (a3) Component 1: Straight line y = 8 x between A = (0, 8) and B = (6, ). Component : Straight line y = (14 - x) / 4 between B = (6, ) and C = (14, 0). The graph below illustrates the budget set with Q* = 6. The boundary of the budget set is in bold. The dotted line indicates the convex combination of the intercepts of the budget set (0, 8) and (14, 0), showing that the budget set is not convex. Problem 1.1: Budget Set if Q* = Good (6, ) Good 1 (b) The quantity discount affects the budget constraint if the point (Q*, 0) lies within the budget constraint i.e. if the consumer can afford to purchase enough units of good x to reach the quantity discount: p Q* < W, or Q* < w / p. (c) The budget set is not convex for any positive value of Q* that influences the budget constraint i.e. Q* < W / p.

3 It is straightforward to see this in a graph. The line between any point on the budget constraint with x < Q* and any other point on the budget constraint with x > Q* is entirely outside the budget set. The quantity discount expands the budget constraint, and thereby expands the set of points included in convex combinations of the budget constraints including many points that remain outside the budget set. To make the same point algebraically, suppose that Q* = 6 and consider the straight line between the x-intercept (3 3Q*, 0) = (14, 0) and the y-intercept (0, W / q) = (0, 8) of the budget set. (It is also possible to make this same argument without assuming a specific value of Q*, but then the notation may make the exposition rather unwieldy.) A convex combination of these two points takes the form [14 α, 8(1- α)]. For α = ½, this convex combination produces the bundle [7, 4], which has associated value 41 (10 units at original prices 4 per unit and one unit of x purchased at quantity discount), and is not affordable with budget 3. Intuitively, each convex combination of points on the boundary of the budget set would be in the budget set based on the average prices of those goods. At (14, 0), the average price of x is 3 / 14, while at (0, 8) the average price of y is 4. Thus, the bundle (7, 4) would be affordable at average price 3/14 for x and average price 4 for y. But with the quantity discount, the average price of x declines with the number of units purchased exactly the opposite of what would be required for convex combinations to remain in the budget set.

4 1.. Discounts on Initial Units and the Budget Constraint (a) As in Problem 1.1, The only distinction between the budget line with a quantity discount and an ordinary budget line is the change in price for purchases of x beyond Q* units. This change in price induces a change in slope of the budget line. Therefore, the budget line is piecewise linear with slope = -p / q = -1/ if 0 < x < Q*. slope = -p / q = -1 if 0 > Q*. We now need to identify the y-intercept and point of change of slope to fully describe the budget constraint. y-intercept If the consumer purchases only good y, she can purchase W / q = 4 / 4 = 6 units. So, one boundary point for the budget constraint is point A = (0, 6). Change of slope The slope of the budget constraint changes at x = Q*. At x = Q*, the consumer spends Q* on good x and has wealth W Q* to spend on good y corresponding to a total of (W Q*) / q = 8 Q* / units of y given that W = 4 and q = 4. That is, the point on the budget line where the price of x (and thus the slope of the budget line) changes is B = (Q*, 6 Q* / ). Piecewise Linear Budget Constraint The equation for the first (of two) linear segment of the budget constraint is y = y-intercept + slope * x, which in this case yields the equation y = 6 x /. We can solve for the second linear segment of the budget constraint by using the equation y = constant + slope * x. Using slope = -1 and the values (Q*, 6- Q*/), we can solve for the constant and identify the constant on the second piece of the budget constraint: y = constant + slope * x: 6 - Q* / = constant Q* 6 + Q* / = constant, Thus, the second component of the budget constraint is given by y = 6 + Q* / x. With this as background, we can now substitute the appropriate values of Q* to find the budget constraints in (a1), (a), (a3).

5 (a1) Component 1: Straight line y = 6 x / between A = (0, 6) and B = (, 5). Component : Straight line y = 7 - x between B = (, 5) and C = (7, 0). (a) Component 1: Straight line y = 6 x / between A = (0, 6) and B = (4, 4). Component : Straight line y = 8 x between B = (4, 4) and C = (8, 0). (a3) Component 1: Straight line y = 6 x / between A = (0, 6) and B = (6, 3). Component : Straight line y = 9 - x between B = (6, 3) and C = (9, 0). Problem 1-: Budget Set with Q* = Good 4 (4, 4) Good 1 The graph below illustrates the budget set with Q* = 6. By contrast to the graph for Problem 1.1 above, it is apparent from inspection that this budget set is convex. (b) The budget set is convex for every positive value of Q*, It is straightforward to see this in a graph. The line between any point on the budget constraint with x < Q* and any other point on the budget constraint with x > Q* is always inside the budget set. By comparison to a pricing rule that maintains the same (lower initial) price for all units of good y, the price increase for later units of y causes the budget constraint to contract in a way that ensures that all convex combinations of points on the boundary of the budget set are still contained in the budget set.

6 1.3. Revealed Preference and Transitivity (Problem 1 on Problem Set 1) Solution will be included with Problem Set 1 Solutions 1.4. (Not) The Subsidy Principle (Problem on Problem Set 1) Solution will be included with Problem Set 1 Solutions 1.5 Revealed Preference and Compensated Demand (a) Suppose that the new bundle chosen by the consumer is (x*, y*). The Law of Compensated Demand says that (x* - 5)(8 10) + (y* - 5)(1 10) < 0 for the first case where prices change to p 1 = 8 and p = 1 and wealth stays at 100. This simplifies to the equation (y* - 5) (x* - 5) < 0, or x* > y*. The original bundle (5, 5) is still available under these conditions. So, the Law of Compensated Demand rules out all bundles with x* < 5. Similarly, The Law of Compensated Demand says that (x* - 5)(16 10) + (y* - 5)(4 10) < 0 for the second case where prices change to p 1 = 16 and p = 4 and wealth increases to 00. This simplifies to the equation 6x* + 14y* < 0. The budget constraint is given by 16 x* + 4 y* = 00 since the consumer spends all money on goods. Rearranging terms to isolate y*, we find y* = 5 / 3 x* / 3. Substituting back into the inequality, we find 6 x* - 14 (/3) x* + 14 * 5 / < 0, which simplifies to x* > 5. Once again, the Law of Compensated Demand rules out all bundles with x* < 5. In fact, these two cases correspond to the budget line, since prices and wealth simply double from the first case to the second. (b) Let (x*, y*, z*) be the bundle chosen under the new conditions. By the Law of Compensated Demand, (x* - 5)(8 10) + (y* - 10) (10 10) + (z* - 10) (1 10) < 0, which simplifies to x* > z*. But it is possible for demand for any individual good to increase or decrease. For example, the bundle (, 13.4, 0) satisfies this inequality with demand for good x falling despite its drop in price, while demand for good increases and demand for good z falls. Similarly, the bundle (11, 0, 31/6) satisfies this inequality with demand for goods x and z increasing while demand for good falls.

7 Note that (, 13.4, 0) and (11, 0, 31/6) were not available at the original prices, so WARP does not rule out the possibility of choosing either of them over (5, 5, 5), the bundle selected at the original prices. While we cannot conclude that demand for any one particular good must increase or fall, we can rule out some combinations of changes. If demand for good z rises, then demand for good x must rise even more, while if demand for good x falls, then demand for good 3 must fall even more. It seems natural that demand for good x would rise and demand for good z would fall, since the price of good x declined while the price of good z increased, but this need not be the case. OPTIONAL PROBLEM FROM MWG 4. MWG.D.4: You should be able to identify the non-convexity of this budget set immediately: if you were to draw a line connecting the points (4,0) and (a, M), the points on this line would lie outside the budget set. What this means in practical terms is that the individual can choose to have 4 hours of leisure (no work) and no consumption, or a hours of leisure and M consumption, but if the individual were to choose an amount of leisure exactly ½ of the way between a and 4, they would get less than ½ M in consumption. [The same is true if you pick any other fraction.] This makes it unlikely that individuals will choose (leisure, consumption) bundles that place them on the non-convex portion of a budget set. Try drawing some indifference curves and you will see that depending on how steep or flat these curves are, people will tend to locate either at (4,0) or (a,m). Moreover, two people with very similar indifference curves might end up choosing very different bundles because of this non-convexity. To demonstrate this non-convexity mathematically, the strategy is to find the slope of the line connecting (4,0) and (a,m), and then show that at the point on this line where leisure=16 (or alternatively, work=8 hours), you get a consumption level above the point on the budget set (16,b). Thus, the first helpful step is to find the values for a and b. The point (16,b) is attained with 8 hours of labor at a wage rate of s per hour, so b=8s. The value of a indicates how much leisure you will have left, if you work enough hours to consume M. You can consume M by working 8 hours at wage rate s and (16-a) hours at wage rate s : M = 8s + (16 a) s' M 8s = 16 a s' M 8s a = 16 s' If we work 8 hours (leisure=16), where would this put us on the line between (4,0) and (a,m)? If we calculate the slope of the line with respect to work hours instead of with

8 respect to leisure hours, we get rise/run = (M-0)/(4-a). Working 8 hours would thus give consumption of: 8M M 8s 8 + s' And then we need only show that this quantity is larger than 8s. There are many ways to do this; the most elegant is to notice that if we changed s to s in the above expression: 8M 8M = = 8s M 8s M 8 + s s Since we know from the problem that s >s, 8M 8M 8M > = = 8s M 8s M 8s M s' s s This demonstrates that the line is outside the budget set. NOTE: A full mathematical proof is ideal, but not necessary. Instead, a descriptive answer showing a clear understanding of the mathematical meaning of convexity as well as its practical interpretation in this problem, along with an appropriate graphical illustration, would be sufficient..1 Transformations of Utility Functions (a) When x = y, u(x, y) = xy = x. The desired transformation function f solves the equation f(u(x,y)) = x when x = y OR f(x ) = x, which can be solved by inspection: f(z) = SQRT(z). Then v(x, y) = f(u(x, y)) = SQRT(xy) = x 1/ y 1/ Next compute the Marginal Rate of Substitution for u and for v. u / x = y u / y = x, so ( u / y) / ( u / x) = x / y. v / x = 1/ x -1/ y 1/ v / y = 1/ x 1/ y -1/

9 so ( v / y) / ( v / x) = x / y. (b) When x = y, u(x, y) = x + y = x + x. The desired transformation function solves the equation f(u(x, y)) = x when x = y OR f(x + x ) = x. This indicates that f(x) is the inverse function to g(x) = x + x To invert this function, solve the equation z = x + x z + 1 = x + x + 1 z + 1 = (x+1) SQRT (z + 1) = x + 1 SQRT(z + 1) 1 = x So if g(x) = x + x, then g -1 (x) = SQRT(x+1) 1 i.e. f(x) = SQRT(x+1) 1. Then, v(x, y) = f(u(x,y)) = SQRT(x + y 1) 1. Next compute the Marginal Rate of Substitution for u and for v. u / x = u / y = y, so ( u / y) / ( u / x) = y.. v / x = (x + y 1) -1/ v / y = y (x + y 1) -1/ so ( v / y) / ( v / x) = y.. Convex Preferences and Quasiconcave Utility Functions Consider the utility functions u 1 (x, y) = xy, u (x, y) = x + y, u 3 (x, y) = x + SQRT(y). (a) As shown in the graph, these three utility functions produce indifference curves with qualitatively distinct properties. For indifference curves corresponding to u 1, convex combinations of bundles on an indifference curve lie above the indifference curve. For indifference curves corresponding to u, convex combinations of bundles on an indifference curve lie exactly on the indifference curve. For indifference curves corresponding to u 3, convex combinations of bundles on an indifference curve lie below the indifference curve. That is, u 1 appears to be strictly quasiconcave, u appears to be weakly quasiconcave and u 3 does not appear to be quasiconcave.

10 Problem.1 Graph

11 (b) Taking partial derivatives: u 1 / x = y u 1 / y = x; u / x = 1 u / y = 1; u 3 / x = 1 u 3 / y = y. MRS 1 MRS MRS 1 = ( u 1 / x) / ( u 1 / y) = y / x. = ( u 1 / x) / ( u 1 / y) = 1. = ( u 1 / x) / ( u 1 / y) = 1 / y. Along an indifference curve as x increases and y decreases, MRS 1 is decreasing, MRS is constant, and MRS 3 is increasing. This indicates that u 1 is strictly quasiconcave, u is weakly quasiconcave, and u 3 is not quasiconcave..3 Skiing & Violins (a) Graph for Problem A (0, 15) B (10, 10) 4 C (30, 0)

12 (b) As shown in the graph, a convex combination of two points on the same indifference curve lies below the indifference curve, indicating that with these indifference curves, the consumer strictly prefers the weighted average of utilities of two different bundles to the convex combination of those bundles. Thus, the preferences represented by these utility functions are not convex. (c) The lowest indifference curve is tangent to the budget line at B = (10, 10). The second indifference curve intersects with the budget line at A = (0, 15) and at (0, 5). The third indifference curve intersects with the budget line only at the boundary point C = (30, 0). Comparing these points and indifference curves, the optimal bundle on the budget line is at C = (30, 0). All other bundles on the budget line lie below the last indifference curve and therefore C = (30, 0) is strictly preferred to all other options on the given budget line. (d) The nonconvexity of preferences induces a choice of bundle that specializes in consumption of a single good. In essence, once we knew that the preferences were nonconvex as shown (with indifference curves that are mirror images of those for convex preferences) then it was almost certain that the optimal bundle would be at one of the ends of the budget line at A = (0, 15) or C = (30, 0).

13 .4 Piecewise Linear Indifference Curves and Optimal Bundles (a) First equate each bundle to a different bundle with x = y and then use transitivity to compare the bundles. The consumer is indifferent between bundle (x 1, y 1 ) and bundle (k 1, k 1 ) where k 1 = (x 1 + y 1 ) / 3. The consumer is indifferent between bundle (x, y ) and bundle (k, k ) where k = ( x + y ) / 3. The consumer s preference between the bundles can be identified from the comparison between k 1 and k. If k 1 > k, i.e. (x 1 + y 1 ) / 3 > ( x + y ) / 3, then the consumer strictly prefers (x 1, y 1 ) to (x, y ). Similarly, if k > k 1, i.e. (x + y ) / 3 > ( x 1 + y 1 ) / 3, then the consumer strictly prefers (x, y ) to (x 1, y 1 ). Finally, if k 1 = k, i.e. (x 1 + y 1 ) / 3 > ( x + y ) / 3, then the consumer is indifferent between (x 1, y 1 ) and (x, y ). (b) On a graph, show this consumer s indifference curves through (4, 4) and (8, 8). Graph for Problem.4(b) (c) As shown in the graph below, the bundle (4, 4) lies on the budget line and is the optimal choice.

14 Graph for Problem.4(c) (d) As shown in the graph below, the bundle (4, 4) lies on the budget line and is the optimal choice. Graph for Problem.4(d) (e) This utility function builds in a preference for equal consumption of both goods, as indicated by the change in slope of each indifference curve at the point where x = y.

15 With equal prices, as in (c), the consumer will naturally choose a bundle with equal amounts of each good. However, if the price of one good is much larger than the other (as in (d), when p > q) then the degree of the consumer s preference for equal consumption is outweighed by the difference in prices and the consumer will specialize consumption to just one good..5 Perfect Complements Solution will be included with Problem Set 1 Solutions

16 3.1 Cobb-Douglas Utility (a) Start by writing the Lagrangian: L(x, y) = x α y 1-α λ (px + qy - W) Taking partial derivatives gives the first-order conditions L / x = α x α-1 y 1-α λp = α (x / y) α-1 λp = 0; (1) L / y = (1-α) x α y α λq = (1-α) (x / y) α λq = 0; () L / λ = W px qy = 0. (3) Rearrange and solve for x and y however you like. For example, you could start by solving (1) and () for λ, then using those two equalities to solve for y as a function of x. λ = α (x / y) α-1 / p λ = (1-α) (x / y) α / q; Setting these equal, α (x / y) α-1 / p = (1-α) (x / y) α / q; OR α (y / x) / p = (1-α) / q; OR y = (1-α) px / αq. (4) Finally, we can solve for the optimal bundle by substituting (4) into (3) which is simply the budget constraint. First rewrite (3) as x = (W qy) / p (5) then substitute (5) into (4): y = (1- α) (W qy) / αq OR y = (1- α) W / αq - (1- α) y / α OR αy = (1- α) W / q - (1- α) y OR y = (1- α) W / q. (6) This is the formula for the choice of y in the optimal bundle. Substituting (6) into (5) yields the formula the choice of x in the optimal bundle. x = (W - (1- α) W) / p OR x = αw / p. (7)

17 (b) Use the same FOCs as above to solve for the Lagrange multiplier: λ = (1-α) (x / y) α / q; From (6) and (7), x / y = αq / (1-α) p, implying λ = (1-α) (αq / (1-α) p) α / q, which can be simplified slightly to λ = (α / p) α [(1-α) / q) 1-α. (c) Returning to the results from (a), the optimal choice of x is linear in W, α and 1 / p, and similarly the optimal choice of y is linear in W, 1-α and 1 / q. One property of these results is that total expenditure on x is equal to px*(p, W) = αw, while total expenditure on y is equal to qx*(p, W) = (1-α)W. That is, the parameter α determines the proportion of wealth spent on each good, then the prices p and q, translate that proportional expenditure into particular quantities of x and y. (d) Optimal Bundle With transformed utility function v(x, y) = α ln x + (1-α) ln y, L(x, y) = α ln x + (1-α) ln y λ (px + qy - W) Taking partial derivatives gives the first-order conditions L / x = α / x λp = 0; (1 ) L / y = (1-α) / y λq = 0; ( ) L / λ = W px qy = 0. (3 ) Solving (1) and () for λ, λ = α / px; λ = (1-α) / qy; Setting these equal, α / px = (1-α) / qy OR y = (1-α) px / αq, which is identical to (4). Thus, the optimal bundle is unchanged by the transformation of the utility function.

18 Lagrange Multiplier Now solving λ = (1-α) / qy for λ gives λ = (1-α) / q[(1- α) W / q] OR λ = 1 / W. Using the interpretation of λ as the shadow price of the budget constraint, the number of utility units achieved per additional unit of money varies with the form of the utility function. Therefore, since the transformation of the utility function changed the definition of one unit of utility, the Lagrange multiplier must also change as a result of this transformation. 3.. Skiing & Violins revisited (a) This is a separable utility function with associated first-order condition (MRS form) ( u / x) / p = ( u / y) / q OR 10 / p = y / q. With p = 10 and q = 0, the first-order condition is given by 10 / 10 = y / 0 OR y = 10. (b) From.3, we know that the utility function is not quasiconcave so that preferences are not convex and in fact, the first-order condition identifies a global minimum (i.e. minimum utility available on the budget constraint) rather than a maximum. (c) When the first-order conditions identify a minimum rather than a maximum, then the optimal bundle must be at one of the endpoints of the budget line, in this case (30, 0) and (0, 15). Computing u(30, 0) = 300 and u(0, 15) = 5, we conclude that the optimal bundle is (30, 0), since this gives higher utility in the comparison of the endpoints.

19 3.3 Comparative Statics with One Good (Problem 3 on Problem Set ) Solution will be included with Problem Set Solutions 3.4 Comparative Statics and the Marginal Rate of Substitution (Problem 1 on Problem Set ) Solution will be included with Problem Set Solutions 3.5 Utility Maximization with Quantity Discount (Problem on Problem Set ) Solution will be included with Problem Set Solutions 3.6. Utility Maximization with Discounts on Initial Units (a) The budget constraint is piecewise linear, with slope -1/ between the point A = (0, 6) and point B = (, 5) (the point where the quantity discount applies). The budget constraint is kinked at point B, with slope changing to -1 between B = (, 5) and C = (7, 0). The natural method for solving this problem is to find the optimal bundle on each separate linear portion of the budget line, and then compare these two bundles (a1) Between A = (0, 6) and B = (, 5) On this part of the budget line, p =, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x /. The equation for the line between A and B is y = 6 x /. Substituting the first-order condition into the budget line equation gives the solution x = 6, corresponding to a point beyond the end of the line between A and B. This indicates that the first-order conditions for a maximum cannot be satisfied on the line between A and B and instead that the optimal bundle on this line must be at either A or B. Since A yields utility 0, the optimal bundle on this line must be at B. TECHNICAL COMMENT: The first-order condition identifies the optimal bundle for a budget line from (0, 6) to (1, 0) the budget line that applies with no increase in the price of x for x > Q*. Under these conditions, the optimal bundle would be (6, 3), producing utility 18. When the first-order condition is not satisfied on the line between A and B, the utility function must be strictly increasing (or strictly decreasing) on that line. In this case, the utility function starts at 0 at point A and is strictly increasing in x until

20 reaching point B where x =. Therefore, the maximum value of the utility function on the line between A and B occurs at the boundary, point B. (a). Between B = (, 5) and C = (7, 0), On this part of the budget line, p = 4, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x. The equation for the line between B and C is y = 7 x. Substituting the first-order condition into the budget line equation gives the condition x = 7, which yields the solution x = 3.5, corresponding to the bundle ( ). This is the unique point on the line between B and C that satisfies the first-order condition. (a3) Comparing the candidate solutions. We have two candidate bundles for the consumer s optimum. Bundle (, 5) yields utility 10 and is the optimal choice on the budget line between A and B. By comparison, bundle (3.5, 3.5) yields utility 49/4 and is the optimal choice on the budget line between B and C. Since 49/4 > 10, bundle (7/, 7/) is the global optimum. (b) The solution follows the same method as in (a), but with slightly different budget equations throughout the analysis. As before, the budget constraint is piecewise linear, with slope -1/ between the point A = (0, 6) and point B = (4, 4) (the point where the quantity discount applies) and separate slope -1 between B = (4, 4) and C = (8, 0). (b1) Between A = (0, 6) and B = (4, 4), On this part of the budget line, p =, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x /. As in (a1), the first-order condition identifies a bundle beyond the end of the line between A and B. so the optimal bundle on this part of the budget line is at a boundary point, in this case at B = (4, 4). (b) Between B = (4, 4) and C = (8, 0), On this part of the budget line, p = 4, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x. The equation for the line between B and C is y = 8 x. Substituting the first-order condition into the budget line equation gives x = 8, which yields the solution x = 4, corresponding to the bundle (4. 4). This is the unique point on the line between B and C that satisfies the first-order condition.

21 (b3) Comparing the candidate solutions. We ve identified the same bundle (4, 4) as the optimal bundle on each separate component of the budget constraint. Therefore, the bundle, which lies exactly at the boundary between the two parts of the budget constraint, must be the global optimum. (c) The solution follows the same method as above, but with again slightly different budget equations throughout the analysis. As before, the budget constraint is piecewise linear, with slope -1/ between the point A = (0, 6) and point B = (6, 3) (the point where the quantity discount applies) and separate slope -1 between B = (6, 3) and C = (9, 0). (c1) Between A = (0, 6) and B = (6, 3) On this part of the budget line, p =, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x /. identifying a bundle (6, 3) that lies at the boundary of the line between A and B. (c) Between B = (6, 3) and C = (9, 0), On this part of the budget line, p = 4, q = 4 and the first-order condition is given by ( u / x) / ( u / y)) = p / q OR y = x. The equation for the line between B and C is y = 9 x. Substituting the first-order condition into the budget line equation gives x = 9, which corresponds to a bundle with x = 4.5 that does not lie on the line between B and C. The optimal bundle on this line must be at one of the boundaries and in this case is at point B = (6, 3). (c3) Comparing the candidate solutions. We ve identified the same bundle (6, 3) as the optimal bundle on each separate component of the budget constraint. Therefore, the bundle, which lies exactly at the boundary between the two parts of the budget constraint, must be the global optimum. (d) For purchases of good x beyond Q* units, the prices of the two goods are equal, so with the given utility function, the consumer would then want to set the quantities of these two goods equal. However, if Q* is relatively large by comparison to W, the consumer has reason to consume more of x than y (setting x = y if possible) in order to take advantage of the reduced price for x on initial purchases. In (a) and (b), when Q* is low, the consumer simply sets x = y and the value of Q* only affects the total number of units of each good that the consumer can choose.

22 In (c), where Q* is higher, the incentives change and the consumer sets x = y. (e) One immediate implication of the convexity of the budget set is that there is a unique optimum in every part of this problem (since the utility function is quasiconcave). In addition, since the utility function is continuous, any small change in Q* translates into a small change in utility value for each bundle implying that the optimal bundle for a given Q* must be close to the optimal bundle for Q* + ε. That is, the choice of optimal bundle is continuous in Q*. This property is reflected by the overlap of optimal bundles on each component of the budget constraint in (b) and (c).

23 4.1 Quasilinear Utility and Boundary Solutions (Problem 1 on Problem Set 3) Solution will be included with Problem Set 3 Solutions 4.. Quasilinear Utility and First-Order Conditions a) Suppose the consumer purchases positive quantities of all goods, then in the optimum, the following relation must hold: A 1 1 = = * * p1 p x px 3 3 p x = = p * 1 * 1, x 3 4Ap Ap3 * The consumer must enough wealth to purchase at least x and x * 3 quantities of good and 3, respectively. * * p1 p1 So, w> px + p3x3 = + 4Ap A 9 3 b) Substitute ( p1, p, p 3) = (3,4,5) into the last equation, we get w + 16A A c) A = 1, then the cutoff value for w is (i) Solve the problem without setting up a Lagrangian. 57 Suppose wealth w, then in the optimum, the consumer purchases 0 amount of good 16 1, and her consumption for good and good 3 satisfies 1 1, px p3x3 w p x = px + = 3 3 Solve the equations, we get x3 = p ( 1+ w 1), x = + w 1+ w p3 p p p Substitute ( p1, p, p 3) = (3,4,5), we get w 4 ( x1, x, x3) = (0,+ 4 + w, ( 4+ w )) If the wealth w >, the consumer spends 57 on good and 3 such that =, px + px 3 3 =, and spends all the remaining on good 1. p px x w w0 w ( x1, x, x3) = (,+ 4 + w0, ( 4+ w0 )), where w 0 =

24 (ii) Now set up a Lagrangian. 1/ L= x1+ x + ln x3 λ(3x1+ 4x + 5 x3 w) First order conditions give that 1 3λ 0, with equality if x 1 > x 3 x 4λ 0, with equality if x > 0. 5λ 0, with equality if x 3 > 0. p1x1+ px+ p3x3= w Solving this system will give the same result as above. 57 w 4 So, if w, ( x1, x, x3) = (0,+ 4 + w, ( 4+ w )) ; w w0 w if w >, ( x1, x, x3) = (,+ 4 + w0, ( 4+ w0 )), where w 0 = Homothetic Utility and Price Indices (Problem on Problem Set 3) Solution will be included with Problem Set 3 Solutions 4.4 Price Indices and Revealed Preference (a) Assume that wealth is the same in both periods and that Walras Law holds, so that the bundles consumed in each period have value W in that period: p 1 x* 1 + q 1 y* 1 = p x* + q y* = W Algebraically, the condition for the Laspeyres index to be less than 1 is CPI L = (p x* 1 + q y* 1 ) / (p 1 x* 1 + q 1 y* 1 ) < 1; OR (p x* 1 + q y* 1 ) / W < 1; OR p x* 1 + q y* 1 < W. Algebraically, the condition for the Paasche index to be less than 1 is CPI P = (p x* + q y* ) / (p 1 x* + q 1 y* ) < 1; OR W / (p 1 x* + q 1 y* ) < 1; OR p 1 x* + q 1 y* > W. Given equal levels of wealth in both periods, (1) the Laspeyres index is less than 1 if the bundle consumed in the first period is within the budget set in period ; () the Paasche

25 index is less than 1 if the bundle consumed in the second period is not in the budget set in period 1. To see this graphically, suppose that W = 150, p 1 = 5, q 1 = 5, p = 3, q = 6. This example reflects a case where the price of good y increases and the price of good x falls over time making it possible that a price index could be either greater than 1 (if it puts sufficient weight on y) or less than 1 (if it puts sufficient weight on x). With W = 150 and p 1 = 5, q 1 = 5, the budget line for period 1 is y 1 = 30 x 1. With W = 150 and p = 3, q = 6, the budget line for period is y = 5 x /. Figure 5.3(a) uses a solid line for the budget constraint in period 1 and a dashed line for the budget constraint in period. The budget lines intersect at point A = (10, 0). Let (x* 1, y* 1 ) represent the optimal bundle in period 1 and (x*, y* ) represent the optimal bundle in period. Since wealth is the same in both periods, we can identify the cost of bundles in period (relative to 150) by observing whether they are above or below the dashed budget line. Similarly, we can identify the cost of bundles in period 1 by observing whether or not they are above the solid budget line. From the discussion above, the Laspeyres index will be less than 1 if (x* 1, y* 1 ) is not in the budget set in period meaning that (x* 1, y* 1 ) is on the budget line in period 1 to the right of the intersection of the budget lines at point A = (10, 0). Similarly, the Paasche index will be less than 1 if (x*, y* ) is not in the budget set in period 1- meaning that (x*, y* ) is on the budget line in period 1 to the right of the intersection of the budget lines at point A = (10, 0).

26 Figure 5.3: Laspeyres and Paasche Indexes < A = (10, 0) C 5 B Figure 5.3 shows a possible combination of optimal bundles for this combination of first period and second period prices that produces both a Laspeyres index less than 1 and a Paasche index less than 1. Here, point B represents the choice in period 1 and point C represents the choice in period. Since point B is below the dotted budget line, it is within the budget set in period implying that the Laspeyres index is less than 1. Since point C is above the other budget line, it is not in the budget set in period 1, implying that the Paasche index is less than 1. Intuitively, bundles to the right of point A put greater weight on good x than y relative to this given change in prices so that computations based on these bundles emphasize good x (whose price declined in this example) and create price indexes less than 1. By similar reasoning, bundles to the left of point A create price indexes greater than 1. (b) If the Laspeyres index is less than 1, then (x* 1, y* 1 ) is inside the budget set in period. By local nonsatiation, the consumer can improve on the choice of (x* 1, y* 1 ) in period and therefore, the consumer must strictly prefer (x*, y* ) to (x* 1, y* 1 ). (c) If the Laspeyres index is exactly equal to 1 and wealth is equal in periods 1 and, then the optimal bundle for period 1 lies on the budget line for period (i.e. the bundle at point A must be chosen in period 1). If the optimal bundle in period is not the same as the optimal bundle in period 1, then by revealed preference, (x*, y* ) must be strictly preferred to point (x* 1, y* 1 ) and is not affordable in period 1. In Figure 5.3, this choice of

27 (x*, y* ) corresponds to a point like C a bundle to the right of the intersection of the budget lines since it is not affordable in period 1. (Note that this choice would also cause the Paasche index to be less than 1.) This result reflects an application of the Law of Compensated Demand, which says that consumption must move in the opposite direction of prices in response to a compensated price change. If the consumer chooses the bundle at point A in period 1, the price change is defined to be compensated (even though wealth is unchanged) because (x* 1, y* 1 ) is on the budget line in period. Further, the price change represents a decrease in the price of x and an increase in the price of y, so the Law of Compensated Demand indicates that the consumer will increase consumption of good x and reduce consumption of good y. (d) If the Laspeyres index is less than 1, then the optimal bundle in period 1 lies inside the budget set in period and must be to the right of point A on the solid budget line in Figure 5.4. Further, if the Paasche index is greater than 1, then the optimal bundle in period lies inside the budget set in period 1 and must be to the left of point A on the dashed budget line. This configuration is inconsistent with revealed preference because it indicates that (x* 1, y* 1 ) is inside the budget set in period and similarly (x*, y* ) lies inside the budget set in period 1. By revealed preference, (x*, y* ) must be strictly preferred to (x* 1, y* 1 ) and simultaneously (x* 1, y* 1 ) must be strictly preferred to (x*, y* ), producing a contradiction.

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 Fall 2011 Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 11

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 Fall 2011 Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 11 Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 Fall 2011 Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 11 LECTURE 1: BUDGETS AND REVEALED PREFERENCE 1.1. Quantity Discounts and the Budget Constraint Suppose that a consumer

More information

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}. Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 5, September 16 Outline 1 Walrasian Demand 2 Properties of Walrasian Demand 3 An Optimization Recipe 4 First and Second Order Conditions Definition Walrasian

More information

Envelope Theorem. Kevin Wainwright. Mar 22, 2004

Envelope Theorem. Kevin Wainwright. Mar 22, 2004 Envelope Theorem Kevin Wainwright Mar 22, 2004 1 Maximum Value Functions A maximum (or minimum) value function is an objective function where the choice variables have been assigned their optimal values.

More information

CONSUMER PREFERENCES THE THEORY OF THE CONSUMER

CONSUMER PREFERENCES THE THEORY OF THE CONSUMER CONSUMER PREFERENCES The underlying foundation of demand, therefore, is a model of how consumers behave. The individual consumer has a set of preferences and values whose determination are outside the

More information

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example A Detailed Price Discrimination Example Suppose that there are two different types of customers for a monopolist s product. Customers of type 1 have demand curves as follows. These demand curves include

More information

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS ECO 352 Spring 2010 Precepts Weeks 1, 2 Feb. 1, 8 REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS Concepts to be reviewed Budget constraint: graphical and algebraic representation Preferences, indifference curves. Utility function

More information

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1 Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1 What follows are some examples of different preference relations and their respective demand functions. In all the following examples, assume we have two goods x

More information

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition Ethan Kaplan September 19, 2011 Outline 1. Convexity and Declining MRS 2. Duality and Hicksian Demand 3. Slutsky Decomposition 4. Net and Gross Substitutes

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2010, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions We saw in the text that utility functions and indifference curves are different ways to represent a consumer s preferences. Calculus can

More information

EQUATIONS and INEQUALITIES

EQUATIONS and INEQUALITIES EQUATIONS and INEQUALITIES Linear Equations and Slope 1. Slope a. Calculate the slope of a line given two points b. Calculate the slope of a line parallel to a given line. c. Calculate the slope of a line

More information

3.1 Solving Systems Using Tables and Graphs

3.1 Solving Systems Using Tables and Graphs Algebra 2 Chapter 3 3.1 Solve Systems Using Tables & Graphs 3.1 Solving Systems Using Tables and Graphs A solution to a system of linear equations is an that makes all of the equations. To solve a system

More information

Economic Principles Solutions to Problem Set 1

Economic Principles Solutions to Problem Set 1 Economic Principles Solutions to Problem Set 1 Question 1. Let < be represented b u : R n +! R. Prove that u (x) is strictl quasiconcave if and onl if < is strictl convex. If part: ( strict convexit of

More information

In this section, we will consider techniques for solving problems of this type.

In this section, we will consider techniques for solving problems of this type. Constrained optimisation roblems in economics typically involve maximising some quantity, such as utility or profit, subject to a constraint for example income. We shall therefore need techniques for solving

More information

(a) We have x = 3 + 2t, y = 2 t, z = 6 so solving for t we get the symmetric equations. x 3 2. = 2 y, z = 6. t 2 2t + 1 = 0,

(a) We have x = 3 + 2t, y = 2 t, z = 6 so solving for t we get the symmetric equations. x 3 2. = 2 y, z = 6. t 2 2t + 1 = 0, Name: Solutions to Practice Final. Consider the line r(t) = 3 + t, t, 6. (a) Find symmetric equations for this line. (b) Find the point where the first line r(t) intersects the surface z = x + y. (a) We

More information

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

Problem Set #3 Answer Key Problem Set #3 Answer Key Economics 305: Macroeconomic Theory Spring 2007 1 Chapter 4, Problem #2 a) To specify an indifference curve, we hold utility constant at ū. Next, rearrange in the form: C = ū

More information

Algebraic expressions are a combination of numbers and variables. Here are examples of some basic algebraic expressions.

Algebraic expressions are a combination of numbers and variables. Here are examples of some basic algebraic expressions. Page 1 of 13 Review of Linear Expressions and Equations Skills involving linear equations can be divided into the following groups: Simplifying algebraic expressions. Linear expressions. Solving linear

More information

Deriving MRS from Utility Function, Budget Constraints, and Interior Solution of Optimization

Deriving MRS from Utility Function, Budget Constraints, and Interior Solution of Optimization Utilit Function, Deriving MRS. Principles of Microeconomics, Fall Chia-Hui Chen September, Lecture Deriving MRS from Utilit Function, Budget Constraints, and Interior Solution of Optimization Outline.

More information

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint. Lecture 2b: Utility c 2008 Je rey A. Miron Outline: 1. Introduction 2. Utility: A De nition 3. Monotonic Transformations 4. Cardinal Utility 5. Constructing a Utility Function 6. Examples of Utility Functions

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

Constrained Optimisation

Constrained Optimisation CHAPTER 9 Constrained Optimisation Rational economic agents are assumed to make choices that maximise their utility or profit But their choices are usually constrained for example the consumer s choice

More information

1. Graphing Linear Inequalities

1. Graphing Linear Inequalities Notation. CHAPTER 4 Linear Programming 1. Graphing Linear Inequalities x apple y means x is less than or equal to y. x y means x is greater than or equal to y. x < y means x is less than y. x > y means

More information

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory Lecture 2: Consumer Theory Preferences and Utility Utility Maximization (the primal problem) Expenditure Minimization (the dual) First we explore how consumers preferences give rise to a utility fct which

More information

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice CHAPTER OUTLINE 4.1 Preferences Properties of Consumer Preferences Preference Maps 4.2 Utility Utility Function Ordinal Preference Utility and Indifference Curves Utility and

More information

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation Jon Bakija This example shows how to use a budget constraint and indifference curve diagram

More information

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Problem Set 2 1/20/10

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Problem Set 2 1/20/10 Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University s by Olga Timoshenko Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Problem Set 2 1/20/10 This problem set is due on Wednesday, 1/27/10. Preliminary

More information

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem Consumer Theory The consumer s problem 1 The Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) We define the MRS(x,y) as the absolute value of the slope of the line tangent to the indifference curve at point point (x,y).

More information

U = x 1 2. 1 x 1 4. 2 x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

U = x 1 2. 1 x 1 4. 2 x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off? Chapter 7 General Equilibrium Exercise 7. Suppose there are 00 traders in a market all of whom behave as price takers. Suppose there are three goods and the traders own initially the following quantities:

More information

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost: Chapter 9 Lecture Notes 1 Economics 35: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes and Sample Questions Chapter 9: Profit Maximization Profit Maximization The basic assumption here is that firms are profit maximizing.

More information

constraint. Let us penalize ourselves for making the constraint too big. We end up with a

constraint. Let us penalize ourselves for making the constraint too big. We end up with a Chapter 4 Constrained Optimization 4.1 Equality Constraints (Lagrangians) Suppose we have a problem: Maximize 5, (x 1, 2) 2, 2(x 2, 1) 2 subject to x 1 +4x 2 =3 If we ignore the constraint, we get the

More information

Noah Williams Economics 312. University of Wisconsin Spring 2013. Midterm Examination Solutions

Noah Williams Economics 312. University of Wisconsin Spring 2013. Midterm Examination Solutions Noah Williams Economics 31 Department of Economics Macroeconomics University of Wisconsin Spring 013 Midterm Examination Solutions Instructions: This is a 75 minute examination worth 100 total points.

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) The economic agent (PR 3.1-3.4) Standard economics vs. behavioral economics Lectures 1-2 Aug. 15, 2009 Prologue

More information

SECOND DERIVATIVE TEST FOR CONSTRAINED EXTREMA

SECOND DERIVATIVE TEST FOR CONSTRAINED EXTREMA SECOND DERIVATIVE TEST FOR CONSTRAINED EXTREMA This handout presents the second derivative test for a local extrema of a Lagrange multiplier problem. The Section 1 presents a geometric motivation for the

More information

Indiana State Core Curriculum Standards updated 2009 Algebra I

Indiana State Core Curriculum Standards updated 2009 Algebra I Indiana State Core Curriculum Standards updated 2009 Algebra I Strand Description Boardworks High School Algebra presentations Operations With Real Numbers Linear Equations and A1.1 Students simplify and

More information

5 Systems of Equations

5 Systems of Equations Systems of Equations Concepts: Solutions to Systems of Equations-Graphically and Algebraically Solving Systems - Substitution Method Solving Systems - Elimination Method Using -Dimensional Graphs to Approximate

More information

1 Portfolio mean and variance

1 Portfolio mean and variance Copyright c 2005 by Karl Sigman Portfolio mean and variance Here we study the performance of a one-period investment X 0 > 0 (dollars) shared among several different assets. Our criterion for measuring

More information

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014) Intermediate Microeconomics (22014) I. Consumer Instructor: Marc Teignier-Baqué First Semester, 2011 Outline Part I. Consumer 1. umer 1.1 Budget Constraints 1.2 Preferences 1.3 Utility Function 1.4 1.5

More information

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Review of Fundamental Mathematics Review of Fundamental Mathematics As explained in the Preface and in Chapter 1 of your textbook, managerial economics applies microeconomic theory to business decision making. The decision-making tools

More information

Second degree price discrimination

Second degree price discrimination Bergals School of Economics Fall 1997/8 Tel Aviv University Second degree price discrimination Yossi Spiegel 1. Introduction Second degree price discrimination refers to cases where a firm does not have

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Ordinal preference theory Harald Wiese University of Leipzig Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 1 / 68 Part A. Basic decision and preference theory 1 Decisions

More information

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization 2.1. Introduction Suppose that an economic relationship can be described by a real-valued

More information

Math 0980 Chapter Objectives. Chapter 1: Introduction to Algebra: The Integers.

Math 0980 Chapter Objectives. Chapter 1: Introduction to Algebra: The Integers. Math 0980 Chapter Objectives Chapter 1: Introduction to Algebra: The Integers. 1. Identify the place value of a digit. 2. Write a number in words or digits. 3. Write positive and negative numbers used

More information

Problem Set II: budget set, convexity

Problem Set II: budget set, convexity Problem Set II: budget set, convexity Paolo Crosetto paolo.crosetto@unimi.it Exercises will be solved in class on January 25th, 2010 Recap: Walrasian Budget set, definition Definition (Walrasian budget

More information

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A Name: While every attempt was made to be complete in the types of problems given below, we make no guarantees about the completeness of the problems. Specifically,

More information

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences 1 Price Elasticity of Supply 1 14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen September 12, 2007 Lecture 4 Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences Outline 1. Chap 2: Elasticity -

More information

1.7 Graphs of Functions

1.7 Graphs of Functions 64 Relations and Functions 1.7 Graphs of Functions In Section 1.4 we defined a function as a special type of relation; one in which each x-coordinate was matched with only one y-coordinate. We spent most

More information

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture II August 25, 2011 Definition and : Lecture A Brief Brush with Duality Cobb-Douglas Cost Minimization Lagrangian for the Cobb-Douglas Solution

More information

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived. Chapter 2: Consumer Choice Short Answer Questions 1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived. Answer: An indifference curve shows the set of consumption bundles

More information

Critical points of once continuously differentiable functions are important because they are the only points that can be local maxima or minima.

Critical points of once continuously differentiable functions are important because they are the only points that can be local maxima or minima. Lecture 0: Convexity and Optimization We say that if f is a once continuously differentiable function on an interval I, and x is a point in the interior of I that x is a critical point of f if f (x) =

More information

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY Aggregate Supply represents the ability of an economy to produce goods and services. In the Long-run this ability to produce is based on the level of production

More information

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions. Name Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions. Question 1. A firm has a production function F (x 1, x 2 ) = ( x 1 + x 2 ) 2. It is a price

More information

Algebra I Vocabulary Cards

Algebra I Vocabulary Cards Algebra I Vocabulary Cards Table of Contents Expressions and Operations Natural Numbers Whole Numbers Integers Rational Numbers Irrational Numbers Real Numbers Absolute Value Order of Operations Expression

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Cost Minimization and the Cost Function

Cost Minimization and the Cost Function Cost Minimization and the Cost Function Juan Manuel Puerta October 5, 2009 So far we focused on profit maximization, we could look at a different problem, that is the cost minimization problem. This is

More information

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR EXERCISES 2. Draw the indifference curves for the following individuals preferences for two goods: hamburgers and beer. a. Al likes beer but hates hamburgers. He always prefers

More information

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88

The Heat Equation. Lectures INF2320 p. 1/88 The Heat Equation Lectures INF232 p. 1/88 Lectures INF232 p. 2/88 The Heat Equation We study the heat equation: u t = u xx for x (,1), t >, (1) u(,t) = u(1,t) = for t >, (2) u(x,) = f(x) for x (,1), (3)

More information

Economics of Insurance

Economics of Insurance Economics of Insurance In this last lecture, we cover most topics of Economics of Information within a single application. Through this, you will see how the differential informational assumptions allow

More information

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES 1. The derivative of a function. Differentiation rules 1.1. The slope of a curve. The slope of a curve at a point P is a measure of the steepness of the curve. If Q is a point on the

More information

15 Kuhn -Tucker conditions

15 Kuhn -Tucker conditions 5 Kuhn -Tucker conditions Consider a version of the consumer problem in which quasilinear utility x 2 + 4 x 2 is maximised subject to x +x 2 =. Mechanically applying the Lagrange multiplier/common slopes

More information

ALGEBRA 2: 4.1 Graph Quadratic Functions in Standard Form

ALGEBRA 2: 4.1 Graph Quadratic Functions in Standard Form ALGEBRA 2: 4.1 Graph Quadratic Functions in Standard Form Goal Graph quadratic functions. VOCABULARY Quadratic function A function that can be written in the standard form y = ax 2 + bx+ c where a 0 Parabola

More information

What are the place values to the left of the decimal point and their associated powers of ten?

What are the place values to the left of the decimal point and their associated powers of ten? The verbal answers to all of the following questions should be memorized before completion of algebra. Answers that are not memorized will hinder your ability to succeed in geometry and algebra. (Everything

More information

Economics 100A. Final Exam

Economics 100A. Final Exam Name form number 1 Economics 100A Final Exam Fill in the bubbles on your scantron with your id number (starting from the left side of the box), your name, and the form type. Students who do this successfully

More information

Constrained Optimization: The Method of Lagrange Multipliers:

Constrained Optimization: The Method of Lagrange Multipliers: Constrained Optimization: The Method of Lagrange Multipliers: Suppose the equation p(x,) x 60x 7 00 models profit when x represents the number of handmade chairs and is the number of handmade rockers produced

More information

4.3 Lagrange Approximation

4.3 Lagrange Approximation 206 CHAP. 4 INTERPOLATION AND POLYNOMIAL APPROXIMATION Lagrange Polynomial Approximation 4.3 Lagrange Approximation Interpolation means to estimate a missing function value by taking a weighted average

More information

Duality in General Programs. Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725

Duality in General Programs. Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725 Duality in General Programs Ryan Tibshirani Convex Optimization 10-725/36-725 1 Last time: duality in linear programs Given c R n, A R m n, b R m, G R r n, h R r : min x R n c T x max u R m, v R r b T

More information

Vocabulary Words and Definitions for Algebra

Vocabulary Words and Definitions for Algebra Name: Period: Vocabulary Words and s for Algebra Absolute Value Additive Inverse Algebraic Expression Ascending Order Associative Property Axis of Symmetry Base Binomial Coefficient Combine Like Terms

More information

A Utility Maximization Example

A Utility Maximization Example A Utilit Maximization Example Charlie Gibbons Universit of California, Berkele September 17, 2007 Since we couldn t finish the utilit maximization problem in section, here it is solved from the beginning.

More information

Algebra Unpacked Content For the new Common Core standards that will be effective in all North Carolina schools in the 2012-13 school year.

Algebra Unpacked Content For the new Common Core standards that will be effective in all North Carolina schools in the 2012-13 school year. This document is designed to help North Carolina educators teach the Common Core (Standard Course of Study). NCDPI staff are continually updating and improving these tools to better serve teachers. Algebra

More information

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Filipe R. Campante Davin Chor July 200 Abstract In this online appendix, we present the proofs for

More information

What does the number m in y = mx + b measure? To find out, suppose (x 1, y 1 ) and (x 2, y 2 ) are two points on the graph of y = mx + b.

What does the number m in y = mx + b measure? To find out, suppose (x 1, y 1 ) and (x 2, y 2 ) are two points on the graph of y = mx + b. PRIMARY CONTENT MODULE Algebra - Linear Equations & Inequalities T-37/H-37 What does the number m in y = mx + b measure? To find out, suppose (x 1, y 1 ) and (x 2, y 2 ) are two points on the graph of

More information

1 Determine whether an. 2 Solve systems of linear. 3 Solve systems of linear. 4 Solve systems of linear. 5 Select the most efficient

1 Determine whether an. 2 Solve systems of linear. 3 Solve systems of linear. 4 Solve systems of linear. 5 Select the most efficient Section 3.1 Systems of Linear Equations in Two Variables 163 SECTION 3.1 SYSTEMS OF LINEAR EQUATIONS IN TWO VARIABLES Objectives 1 Determine whether an ordered pair is a solution of a system of linear

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model 21.1: Introduction This is an important chapter in that it introduces, and explores the implications of, an empirically relevant utility function representing intertemporal

More information

the points are called control points approximating curve

the points are called control points approximating curve Chapter 4 Spline Curves A spline curve is a mathematical representation for which it is easy to build an interface that will allow a user to design and control the shape of complex curves and surfaces.

More information

Elements of a graph. Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section

Elements of a graph. Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section Click on the links below to jump directly to the relevant section Elements of a graph Linear equations and their graphs What is slope? Slope and y-intercept in the equation of a line Comparing lines on

More information

FINAL EXAM SECTIONS AND OBJECTIVES FOR COLLEGE ALGEBRA

FINAL EXAM SECTIONS AND OBJECTIVES FOR COLLEGE ALGEBRA FINAL EXAM SECTIONS AND OBJECTIVES FOR COLLEGE ALGEBRA 1.1 Solve linear equations and equations that lead to linear equations. a) Solve the equation: 1 (x + 5) 4 = 1 (2x 1) 2 3 b) Solve the equation: 3x

More information

Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Framework

Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Framework Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Framework The lifetime budget constraint (LBC) from the two-period consumption-savings model is a useful vehicle for introducing and analyzing

More information

Make sure you look at the reminders or examples before each set of problems to jog your memory! Solve

Make sure you look at the reminders or examples before each set of problems to jog your memory! Solve Name Date Make sure you look at the reminders or examples before each set of problems to jog your memory! I. Solving Linear Equations 1. Eliminate parentheses. Combine like terms 3. Eliminate terms by

More information

Utility. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory Utility 1 / 15

Utility. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory Utility 1 / 15 Utility M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory Utility 1 / 15 Utility Function The preferences are the fundamental description useful for analyzing choice and utility is simply a way of

More information

Tastes and Indifference Curves

Tastes and Indifference Curves C H A P T E R 4 Tastes and Indifference Curves This chapter begins a -chapter treatment of tastes or what we also call preferences. In the first of these chapters, we simply investigate the basic logic

More information

Chapter 5. Linear Inequalities and Linear Programming. Linear Programming in Two Dimensions: A Geometric Approach

Chapter 5. Linear Inequalities and Linear Programming. Linear Programming in Two Dimensions: A Geometric Approach Chapter 5 Linear Programming in Two Dimensions: A Geometric Approach Linear Inequalities and Linear Programming Section 3 Linear Programming gin Two Dimensions: A Geometric Approach In this section, we

More information

MATH 60 NOTEBOOK CERTIFICATIONS

MATH 60 NOTEBOOK CERTIFICATIONS MATH 60 NOTEBOOK CERTIFICATIONS Chapter #1: Integers and Real Numbers 1.1a 1.1b 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.8 Chapter #2: Algebraic Expressions, Linear Equations, and Applications 2.1a 2.1b 2.1c 2.2 2.3a 2.3b 2.4 2.5

More information

Practice with Proofs

Practice with Proofs Practice with Proofs October 6, 2014 Recall the following Definition 0.1. A function f is increasing if for every x, y in the domain of f, x < y = f(x) < f(y) 1. Prove that h(x) = x 3 is increasing, using

More information

2013 MBA Jump Start Program

2013 MBA Jump Start Program 2013 MBA Jump Start Program Module 2: Mathematics Thomas Gilbert Mathematics Module Algebra Review Calculus Permutations and Combinations [Online Appendix: Basic Mathematical Concepts] 2 1 Equation of

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

PPF's of Germany and France

PPF's of Germany and France Economics 165 Winter 2 Problem Set #1 Problem 1: Let Germany and France have respective labor forces of 8 and 6. Suppose both countries produce wine and cares according to the following unit labor requirements:

More information

Linear Equations. Find the domain and the range of the following set. {(4,5), (7,8), (-1,3), (3,3), (2,-3)}

Linear Equations. Find the domain and the range of the following set. {(4,5), (7,8), (-1,3), (3,3), (2,-3)} Linear Equations Domain and Range Domain refers to the set of possible values of the x-component of a point in the form (x,y). Range refers to the set of possible values of the y-component of a point in

More information

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Problem Set #5-Key Sonoma State University Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Dr Cuellar (1) Suppose that you are paying your for your own education and that your college tuition is $200 per

More information

Understanding Basic Calculus

Understanding Basic Calculus Understanding Basic Calculus S.K. Chung Dedicated to all the people who have helped me in my life. i Preface This book is a revised and expanded version of the lecture notes for Basic Calculus and other

More information

Thnkwell s Homeschool Precalculus Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks

Thnkwell s Homeschool Precalculus Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks Thnkwell s Homeschool Precalculus Course Lesson Plan: 36 weeks Welcome to Thinkwell s Homeschool Precalculus! We re thrilled that you ve decided to make us part of your homeschool curriculum. This lesson

More information

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES ECON 210 (1) Perfect Substitutes. Suppose that Jack s utility is entirely based on number of hours spent camping (c) and skiing (s).

More information

Demand. Lecture 3. August 2015. Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58

Demand. Lecture 3. August 2015. Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58 Demand Lecture 3 Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 August 2015 1 / 58 Introduction We saw the demand curve in chapter 2. We learned about consumer decision making in chapter 3. Now we bridge the gap between the

More information

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior Read Pindyck and Rubinfeld (2013), Chapter 3 Microeconomics, 8 h Edition by R.S. Pindyck and D.L. Rubinfeld Adapted by Chairat Aemkulwat for Econ I: 2900111 1/29/2015 CHAPTER

More information

Name: ID: Discussion Section:

Name: ID: Discussion Section: Math 28 Midterm 3 Spring 2009 Name: ID: Discussion Section: This exam consists of 6 questions: 4 multiple choice questions worth 5 points each 2 hand-graded questions worth a total of 30 points. INSTRUCTIONS:

More information

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically Slide 1 Slide 3 Econ 410: Micro Theory & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically Friday, November 9 th, 2007 Cost But, at some point, average costs for a firm will tend to increase. Why? Factory space and

More information

Section 3.1 Quadratic Functions and Models

Section 3.1 Quadratic Functions and Models Section 3.1 Quadratic Functions and Models DEFINITION: A quadratic function is a function f of the form fx) = ax 2 +bx+c where a,b, and c are real numbers and a 0. Graphing Quadratic Functions Using the

More information

Common Core Unit Summary Grades 6 to 8

Common Core Unit Summary Grades 6 to 8 Common Core Unit Summary Grades 6 to 8 Grade 8: Unit 1: Congruence and Similarity- 8G1-8G5 rotations reflections and translations,( RRT=congruence) understand congruence of 2 d figures after RRT Dilations

More information

In following this handout, sketch appropriate graphs in the space provided.

In following this handout, sketch appropriate graphs in the space provided. Dr. McGahagan Graphs and microeconomics You will see a remarkable number of graphs on the blackboard and in the text in this course. You will see a fair number on examinations as well, and many exam questions,

More information

Choice under Uncertainty

Choice under Uncertainty Choice under Uncertainty Part 1: Expected Utility Function, Attitudes towards Risk, Demand for Insurance Slide 1 Choice under Uncertainty We ll analyze the underlying assumptions of expected utility theory

More information

Math Review. for the Quantitative Reasoning Measure of the GRE revised General Test

Math Review. for the Quantitative Reasoning Measure of the GRE revised General Test Math Review for the Quantitative Reasoning Measure of the GRE revised General Test www.ets.org Overview This Math Review will familiarize you with the mathematical skills and concepts that are important

More information