International Macroeconomics

Similar documents
Introduction to Exchange Rates and the Foreign Exchange Market

Agenda. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy, Part 1. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates.

What Determines Exchange Rates? In the Short Run In the Long Run

How To Calculate The Price Of A Dollar

Purchasing-Power Parity: Definition, Measurement, and Interpretation

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

Imagine you are planning a trip to France

Measuring long-run equilibrium exchange rates using standardized products with different specifications

Relationships among Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates. J. Gaspar: Adapted from Jeff Madura, International Financial Management

Exchange Rates Revised: January 9, 2008

This chapter seeks to explain the factors that underlie currency movements. These factors include market fundamentals and market expectations.

Chapter Outline. Chapter 13. Exchange Rates. Exchange Rates

Nominal, Real and PPP GDP

Finance 581: Arbitrage and Purchasing Power Parity Conditions Module 5: Lecture 1 [Speaker: Sheen Liu] [On Screen]

Refer to Figure 17-1

Econ 202 H01 Final Exam Spring 2005

Comparing Levels of Development

Econ 202 Final Exam. Table 3-1 Labor Hours Needed to Make 1 Pound of: Meat Potatoes Farmer 8 2 Rancher 4 5

Quantitative significance of growth Inequality and poverty. Sources of growth Global imbalance Tensions and risks

A HOW-TO GUIDE: UNDERSTANDING AND MEASURING INFLATION

Exchange Rate Determination I: Prices and the Real Exchange Rate

Oxford University Business Economics Programme

D) surplus; negative. 9. The law of one price is enforced by: A) governments. B) producers. C) consumers. D) arbitrageurs.

Global wage projections to 2030 September 2013

Purchasing Power Parity: Even The Big Mac Can Predict FX Rates

Definitions and terminology

III. INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Ghana South Korea United States. Real GDP per capita (2005 dollars) Per centage of 1960 real GDP per capita real GDP per capita

Nontradables, real exchange rate and pricing-to-market

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP?

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam

EC201 Intermediate Macroeconomics. EC201 Intermediate Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Solution

Relative prices and Balassa Samuleson e ect

Chapter Review and Self-Test Problems

Chapter 12. National Income Accounting and the Balance of Payments. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

CHAPTER 15 EXCHANGE-RATE ADJUSTMENTS AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Burgernomics: An Instructional Case On The Law Of One Price Carolin E. Schmidt, Heilbronn University, Germany

The East Asian Miracle Main characteristics of the Asian Miracle

Econ 202 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

International Economic Relations

MGE#12 The Balance of Payments

Development aid in 2015 continues to grow despite costs for in-donor refugees

FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATES

Gross Domestic Product, the Business Cycle, and the Fed s goals for the Macroeconomy SMART Lesson

Chapter 24. What will you learn in this chapter? Valuing an economy. Measuring the Wealth of Nations

Cosumnes River College Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 3 Due September 17, 2015

11.1 Estimating Gross Domestic Product (GDP) Objectives

HAS BRAZIL REALLY TAKEN OFF? BRAZIL LONG-RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CONVERGENCE

2. Discuss the implications of the interest rate parity for the exchange rate determination.

1 Multiple Choice - 50 Points

Free-response/problem

EXTERNAL DEBT AND LIABILITIES OF INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES. Mark Rider. Research Discussion Paper November Economic Research Department

The labour market, I: real wages, productivity and unemployment 7.1 INTRODUCTION

Monetary Policy Bank of Canada

ASSIGNMENT 1 ST SEMESTER : MACROECONOMICS (MAC) ECONOMICS 1 (ECO101) STUDY UNITS COVERED : STUDY UNITS 1 AND 2. DUE DATE : 3:00 p.m.

Study Questions (with Answers) Lecture 14 Pegging the Exchange Rate

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

The Broad World Price Band

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

CHAPTER 16 EXCHANGE-RATE SYSTEMS

Argentina s Economy: A death foretold again, or a surprise rescue? Claudio M. Loser Centennial- Latin America March 2014

To appear as an entry in the Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Liberty Fund, Inc., edited by David Henderson.

Households Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750. Factor markets. Wages, profit, interest, rent = $750

Why Are Goods So Cheap in Some Countries?*

Australia s position in global and bilateral foreign direct investment

I. Measuring Output: GDP

Joint Workshop Affordability, Value for Money and Decision Making Tuesday 18 th November 2014 BAWA, Filton, Bristol

List of tables. I. World Trade Developments

International Labor Comparisons

A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar

IPA Global Publishing Statistics. Rüdiger Wischenbart

Chapter 5: GDP and Economic Growth

General Certificate of Education Advanced Level Examination January 2010

INFLATION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Economics 212 Principles of Macroeconomics Study Guide. David L. Kelly

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

BIS CEMLA Roundtable on Fiscal Policy, public debt management and government bond markets: issues for central banks

REER NEER India Forex Advisors IFA Classroom: Understanding NEER and REER Dated- 14 th August, 2014

Macroeconomia Capitolo 7. Seguire l andamento della macroeconomia. What you will learn in this chapter:

Factors affecting the inbound tourism sector. - the impact and implications of the Australian dollar

Cosumnes River College Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 11 Will Not Be Collected

The Canadian dollar as a commodity currency: Has the relationship changed?* Monica Mow Supervisor: Dr. Graham Voss

One of the foundations of international

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 17 MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND ISSUES March 17, 2016

Econ 202 Final Exam. Douglas, Spring 2006 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Chapter 1 Lecture Notes: Economics for MBAs and Masters of Finance

Reference: Gregory Mankiw s Principles of Macroeconomics, 2 nd edition, Chapters 10 and 11. Gross Domestic Product

Only by high growth rates sustained for long periods of time.

The Effect of Oil Prices on Exchange Rates: A Case Study of the Dominican Republic Jennifer C. Dawson

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

A new ranking of the world s most innovative countries: Notes on methodology. An Economist Intelligence Unit report Sponsored by Cisco

Comparative tables. CPSS Red Book statistical update 427

STATISTICS BRIEF. Purchasing power parities measurement and uses. In this issue. What are PPPs? March No. 3

Discussion of Global Liquidity and Procyclicality by Hyun Song Shin

Ch. 38 Practice MC 1. In international financial transactions, what are the only two things that individuals and firms can exchange? A.

Chapter 31 Open-Economy Macroeconomics: Basic Concepts

Economic Growth and Development EC 375. Chapter 1 #2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 (on pages 24-25) and Appendix problems A.1 and A.2 (on pages 28-29).

Transcription:

Slides for Chapter 9: Determinants of the Real Exchange Rate International Macroeconomics Schmitt-Grohé Uribe Woodford Columbia University May 1, 2016 1

The Law of One Price (LOOP) says that a good should cost the same abroad and at home. Formally, if the LOOP holds for good i, then where P i = P i S, P i = domestic currency price of good i P i = foreign currency price of good i S = nominal exchange rate, (domestic currency price for 1 unit of foreign currency) 2

Examples of goods for which the LOOP holds: Gold Oil Wheat Luxury Consumer Goods (Hermes neckties, MontBlanc pens, Rolex watches, Beats, etc. ) Examples of goods for which the LOOP fails: Big Mac [will discuss the Big Mac Index later] Housing Transportation Haircuts Restaurant Meals 3

Reasons Why the LOOP May Fail a good has non-traded inputs such as: labor rent electricity government policies/regulations (taxes) barriers to trade (tariffs, quotas) pricing to market (pharmaceuticals) 4

From the idea of the LOOP to PPP Theory PPP stands for Purchasing Power Parity Generalize the law of one price (LOOP) Let: P = domestic currency price of a domestic basket of goods P = foreign currency price of a foreign basket of goods S = nominal exchange rate, [domestic currency per unit of foreign currency] e = real exchange rate (RER) 5

Define e, the real exchange rate as follows: e = SP P (*) units? = domestic baskets foreign baskets If e = 1, we say PPP (Purchasing Power Parity) holds. e > 1, home basket is undervalued, or foreign basket overvalued. If e > 0, we say the RER depreciates e < 1, home basket is overvalued, or foreign basket undervalued. If e < 0, we say the RER appreciates. 6

Suppose the LOOP holds for all goods, does PPP (i.e., e = 1) have to hold? Not necessarily. Why? Because the foreign and domestic baskets could contain different items have different weights for the same items. 7

Absolute PPP We say that absolute PPP holds, when e = 1 Relative PPP We say that relative PPP holds, when e = 0 8

How to test relative PPP? Take logs of (*): ln e t = ln(s t P t ) ln(p t) If relative PPP holds, then ln e t = 0 and hence ln(s t Pt moving over time in tandem with ln(p t ) ) should be 9

Test 1 of Relative PPP in the long run: The next graph tests relative PPP by plotting ln(s t P t ) and ln(p t) for the dollar pound real exchange rate over the period 1820 to 2001. The broken line is ln(s t P UK t ) The solid line is ln(p US t ) The vertical difference between the broken and the solid line is e t, the dollar-pound real exchange rate. 10

Dollar-Sterling PPP Over Two Centuries Note: The figure shows U.S. and U.K. consumer price indices expressed in U.S. dollar terms over the period 1820-2001 using a log scale with a base of 1900=0. Source: Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor, The Purchasing Power Parity Debate, Journal of Economic Perspectives 18, Fall 2004, 135-158. 11

Observations on the figure 1. Overall the comovement between U.S. and U.K. prices over the past 180 years has been very high! This suggests that relative PPP holds in the long run. 2. Over the past 180 years the dollar has appreciated significantly vis-a-vis the Pound in real terms. 12

Test 2 of Relative PPP in the long run: P t U.S. Price level in dollars; P t foreign price level in foreign currency Take the k-period log difference of (*) ln e t ln e t k = ln ( Pt /P t k ) ( ) ( ) ln Pt /P t k + ln St /S t k 13

If relative PPP holds in the long run, then ln e t ln e t k = 0 This implies that ln ( P t /P t k ) ln ( Pt /P t k ) = ln ( St /S t k ) This equation says that the difference between foreign long run inflation and U.S. long run inflation should be equal to the rate of depreciation of the foreign currency against the dollar. This is intuitive, the currency of a country with a higher rate of inflation than the United States should depreciate against the dollar. 14

Taylor and Taylor test whether relative PPP holds in the long run by considering average inflation differentials and average depreciation rates against the U.S. dollar over the 29 year period 1970 to 1998 for 20 industrialized countries and 26 developing countries. Each country is one observation. If relative PPP holds in the long run, then a plot of long-run inflation differentials against long-run depreciation rates against the dollar should lie on the 45 degree line. The next graph shows that this is indeed the case providing more support to the claim that in the long-run relative PPP holds. 15

Consumer Price Inflation Relative to the U.S. Versus Dollar Exchange Rate Depreciation, 29-Year Average, 1970-1998 Note: The figure shows countries cumulative inflation rate differentials against the United States in percent (vertical axis) plotted against their cumulative depreciation rates against the U.S. dollar in percent (horizontal axis). The sample includes data from 20 industrialized countries and 26 developing countries. Source: Alan M. Taylor and Mark P. Taylor, The Purchasing Power Parity Debate, Journal of Economic Perspectives 18, Fall 2004, 135-158. 16

Q: Does Relative PPP hold in the short run? A: No. As we saw above in the time series plot, the real exchange rate, which in that plot is given by the difference between the two lines, changes from year to year, and hence relative PPP fails in the short run. Also recall from Chapter 8 that in monthly data we observed the following average changes in real exchange rates: over the short period September 1982 to January 1988 ln e t ln e t 1 (in percent) Germany -6.35 % Switzerland -8.35% France -6.25% Mexico -3.32% We conclude that in the short-run relative PPP does not hold. In fact e t is VERY volatile in the short run. 17

Summary: Relative PPP holds over the long run. Relative PPP fails to hold over the short run. 18

Absolute PPP Absolute PPP holds if e t = 1, that is if the purchasing power of $1 is the same in the United States and abroad To test relative PPP all we needed were observations on % S t,% P t,% P t... but to test absolute PPP we do need to observe the level of P t and not just an index. It is very hard to get data for the level of P t, because statistical agencies that produce the CPI typically publish an index and not the actual price level of a typical basket. 19

We will proceed in 2 steps. First we will analyze whether absolute PPP holds for a single good, MacDonald s Big Mac sandwich, and then we will look at data from the International Comparison Program. 20

Q: Does absolute PPP hold for the Big Mac Compute the real exchange rate for a Big Mac e BigMac = S P BigMac P BigMac If absolute PPP holds, then e BigMac = 1. e BigMac = 1 tells you how many U.S. Big Macs it takes to buy one foreign Big Mac. Here is some data on e BigMac = 1 for January 2015 21

The Big-Mac Real Exchange Rate January 2015 Country P BigMac S S P BigMac e BigMac Switzerland 6.50 1.16 7.56 1.58 Norway 48.00 0.13 6.30 1.32 Brazil 13.50 0.39 5.21 1.09 Sweden 40.70 0.12 4.97 1.04 United States 4.79 1.00 4.79 1.00 France 3.90 1.16 4.53 0.95 Italy 3.85 1.16 4.48 0.93 Britain 2.89 1.52 4.38 0.91 Australia 5.30 0.81 4.31 0.90 Germany 3.67 1.16 4.27 0.89 Turkey 9.25 0.43 3.97 0.83 South Korea 4100.00 0.00 3.78 0.79 Mexico 49.00 0.07 3.35 0.70 Argentina 28.00 0.12 3.25 0.68 Japan 370.00 0.01 3.14 0.66 China 17.20 0.16 2.77 0.58 India 116.25 0.02 1.89 0.39 Russia 89.00 0.02 1.36 0.28 Source: The Economist Magazine. 22

Observations on the table: Absolute PPP fails. Big Mac real exchange rates are not equal to unity. They are as high as 1.58 (for Switzerland) and as low as 0.28 (for Russia) In 2015 BigMac prices in Switzerland, Norway, Brazil (!), and Sweden were higher than in the United States. Big Mac real exchange rates are high for rich countries and low for poor countries. For example, look at India, the Big Mac real exchange rate is 39, which means that for 1 Big Mac in India one can only buy 39 percent of a Big Mac in the United States. Later in this chapter, we will explore in more detail whether absolute prices are lower in poor and emerging countries than in rich countries. 23

Over and Undervaluation of a Currency: Let St ppp denote the PPP exchange rate, that is, the nominal exchange rate that would make PPP hold,. That is, St ppp Pt i = P t US This is the nominal exchange rate that would make the real exchange rate equal to one. If then S PPP t > S t, P US t > S t P i t then we say that the dollar is overvalued (and the foreign currency undervalued) and iff St PPP < S t, then P US t < S t P i t 24

and we say the dollar is undervalued (and the foreign currency overvalued). If one believes that in the long run PPP should hold for Big Macs, then one would regard the currencies of Switzerland, Norway, Brazil, and Sweden as overvalued and would expect them to depreciate against the U.S. dollar over time. Similarly, one would expect all the countries with a Big Mac real exchange rate less than one to appreciate against the U.S. dollar over time. This is an argument sometimes suggested in The Economist Magazine. This week s homework asks you to evaluate this hypothesis empirically.

We have just seen that absolute PPP fails for Big Macs. But is there other data on price levels that can be used to test whether absolute PPP holds. Yes. There is one source on actual price levels: The International Comparison Program (ICP) It represents the most extensive and thorough effort to measure absolute PPP rates across countries. The ICP was established in the late 1960s on the recommendation of the United Nations Statistical Commission (UNSC). It began as a research project carried out jointly by the United Nations Statistical Office and the University of Pennsylvania. The first comparison, conducted in 1970, covered 10 economies. Now, 40 years later, the ICP is a worldwide statistical operation whose latest comparison ICP 2011 involved 199 economies. The program is led and coordinated by the ICP Global Office hosted by the World Bank. The 2011 ICP round collected over 7 million prices from 199 economies in eight regions, with the help of 15 regional and international partners. It is the most extensive effort to measure PPPs ever undertaken. 25

The ICP reports the real exchange rate, which is referred to as the Price Level Index e = PLI SP P where now P and P are actual price levels (and not indices!). Here is what they find for the year 2011 (most recent available): Foreign Country e 100 United States 100 Ethiopia 29 Bangladesh 31 India 32 Pakistan 28 China 54 Germany 108 Sweden 136 Switzerland 162 Japan 135 What do these numbers mean? Take India, a PLI of 32 means that you can buy a basket that costs $100 in the United States for $32 in India. Absolute PPP fails! Data Source: Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures of World Economies, Summary of Results and Findings of the 2011 International Comparison Program, Table 6.1, The World Bank, 2014. 26

Application: PPP Exchange Rates and World Shares in GDP What is the world share of GDP of high income, middle-income, and low-income economies? Comparisons of the size of economies (in $) tend to overstate the size of rich countries and understate the size of poor countries. Look at the next chart. It shows that in 2011, middle-income countries produced 32 percent of world GDP at market exchange rates but 48.2 of world GDP at PPP exchange rates. The flip-side of this is that GDP of high-income economies becomes significantly smaller when PPP-based GDPs are used, their share in world GDP falls from 67.3 percent to 50.3 percent. The largest relative difference obtains for low-income countries whose share in world GDP doubles from 0.7 percent when measured at market exchange rates to 1.5 percent when measured at PPP exchange rates. 27

Share of World GDP (exchange rate based) < 1% Share of World GDP (PPP based) 2% 32% 50% 48% 67% High income Middle Income Low Income The income categories are as follows: low income per capita gross national income (GNI) less than $1,025 (32 countries); middle income per capita GNI from $1,026 to $12,475 (84 countries); and high income per capita GNI greater than $12,475 (56 countries). 28

Is China the largest economy in the world? Not yet, in 2011, ICP reports that it is the second largest both at PPP exchange rates and at market exchange rates. U.S. GDP at market prices still twice as large as China s. And to assess economic power, it probably makes more sense to look at GDP at market exchange rates. GDP (PPP-based) GDP ($-based) Economy Rank World Share World Share 1 17.1 22.1 United States 2 14.9 10.4 China 3 6.4 2.7 India 4 4.8 8.4 Japan 5 3.7 5.2 Germany Data Source: Table 7.1 of Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures of World Economies, Summary of Results and Findings of the 2011 International Comparison Program. 29

Application: PPP Exchange Rates and Standard of Living Comparisons standard of living comparisons are tricky because of differences in relative prices. comparisons of per capita income (in $) tend to overstate the differences in real purchasing power between rich and poor countries because rich countries are systematically more expensive than poor countries. 30

220 200 Higher Prices in Rich Countries Norway 180 160 Japan Luxembourg PLI, (World=100), 2011 140 120 100 Germany United States 80 60 Comoros Congo, Dem. Rep. Liberia Niger China Qatar Kuwait Brunei Darussalam Macao SAR, China 40 Burundi India 20 500 2000 8000 32000 128000 Natural Log Scale, GDP per capita at PPP exchange rates, 2011 Data Source: ICP, 2011. 31

GDP per capita comparisons at such huge differences in relative prices cause important differences in the basic measurements of real incomes and real standards of living Country Per Capita GDP US$ PPP United States 49,782 49,782 India 1,533 4,735 US/India 32 11 At market exchange rates GDP per capita in the United States in 2011 was 32 times as large as that of India. However, at PPP exchange rate U.S. per capita GDP was only 11 times as large as that of India. $1,533 can buy 3 times as many goods in India (at Indian prices) than it can in the U.S. at U.S. prices. 32

Why does Absolute PPP fail? One reason is that many goods are not traded internationally, and hence price discrepancies will not be arbitraged away via trade. The price index is an average of all prices in the economy, traded goods prices, P T, and nontraded goods prices, P N P = φ(p T, P N ) Example: P = (P T ) α (P N ) 1 α Suppose the LOOP holds for traded goods: P T = SP T 33

but not for nontraded goods P N SP N Suppose the foreign price level, P, is constructed as P = φ(p T, P N ) The real exchange rate then is: e = SP P = Sφ(P T, P N ) φ(p T, P N ) = SP T φ(1, P N /P T ) P T φ(1, P N /P T ) = φ(1, P N /P T ) φ(1, P N /P T ). (1)

If the relative price of nontradables is higher in the foreign country, then the real exchange rate is greater than 1, if P N P T > P N PT, then e > 1.

Determinants of the Real Exchange Rate in the Medium Term: The Balassa-Samuelson Model 34

Recall that: e = φ ( 1, P N ) P T φ ( 1, P ) N PT From here clear that the real exchange rate depreciates if P N P T increases relative to P N PT Q: What could make P N P T go up relative to P N PT? A: Productivity growth in the traded sector relative to the nontraded sector in the foreign country being faster than in the domestic country. 35

The Balassa-Samuelson effect is the tendency for countries with higher productivity growth in tradables compared to nontradables to have higher prices (and hence appreciated real exchange rates. The Model 2 goods: Q T and Q N Q T = traded output Q N = nontraded output 36

Production Production of Tradables: Q T = a T L T Production of Nontradables: Q N = a N L N L T = labor input in the traded sector L N = labor input in the nontraded sector a T = exogenous labor productivity in the traded sector a N = exogenous labor productivity in the nontraded sector W = wage rate 37

Traded Goods Sector Firms choose Q T and L T to maximize profits subject to profits = P T Q T WL T. Q T = a T L T. Eliminate Q T Choose L T to maximize profits profits = PTaTLT WLT profits L T = 0 P T a T = W (*) 38

Nontraded Goods Sector Firms choose Q N and L N to maximize profits subject to profits = P N Q N WL N. Q N = a N L N. Eliminate Q N Choose L N to maximize profits profits = PNaNLN WLN profits L N = 0 P N a N = W (**) 39

Combining (*) with (**) yields P N P T = a T a N (2) That is, the Balassa-Samuelson model predicts that in equilibrium the relative price of nontradables in terms of tradables is inversely related to the ratio of labor productivity in the traded sector to that in the nontraded sector. Is this prediction of the Balassa-Samuelson model borne out in the data? 40

Take natural logarithms of (2) and consider changes over time % ( ) PN P T = % a T % a N This expression says that the percent change in the relative price of nontradables is equal to the growth rate differential between factor productivity in the traded sector and the nontraded sector. We wish to test whether this relationship holds over the long run in actual data. 41

De Gregorio, ( ) Giovannini, and Wolf (EER, 1994) collect data on % PN PT and on % a T % a N for 14 OECD countries over the period 1970-1985 That is they have 14 observations. The next slide shows what they find 42

Differential Factor Productivity Growth and Changes in the Relative Price of Nontradables Note: The figure plots the average annual percentage change in the relative price of nontradables in terms of tradables, % ( P N P T ), (vertical axis) against the average annual growth in total factor productivity differential between the traded sector and the nontraded sector, % a T % a N, (horizontal axis) over the period 1970-1985 for 14 OECD countries. Source: José De Gregorio, Alberto Giovannini, and Holger C. Wolf, International Evidence on Tradable and Nontradable Inflation, European Economic Review 38, June 1994, 1225-1244. 43

Comments on the figure: If Balassa-Samuelson model is true, then all 14 observations should line up on the 45 degree line. This is not quite the case. Still the figure demonstrates that 15-year averages for OECD countries display a positive relationship between % ( ) ( ) P N PT and % at a, N as predicted by the Balassa Samuelson model

What are the predictions of the Balassa-Samuelson Model for the Behavior of the Real Exchange Rate? A relationship like equation (2) must also hold in the foreign country P N PT = a T a N where PT = foreign currency price of traded goods abroad PN = foreign currency priced of nontraded goods abroad a T = exogenous labor productivity in the traded sector abroad = exogenous labor productivity in the nontraded sector abroad a N 44

Thus the Balassa Samuelson model predicts that, ( φ 1, P ) N P e = T φ ( 1, P ) N PT ( ) φ 1, a T a N = φ ( 1, a ) T a N Hence e, if a T a increases relative to a T N a, that is, the real exchange N rate of the domestic country depreciates if relative productivity growth in the traded sector relative to productivity growth in the nontraded sector is faster in the foreign country than in the domestic country. 45

Suppose the price index is given by φ(p T, P N ) = P 1 α T P α N, α (0,1) then the Balassa Samuelson model predicts that % e = α [ % ( a T a N ) % ( )] at a N This prediction can be confronted with data. What is needed? Observations of growth rates of technology in the traded and nontraded sector and observations on real exchange rate changes. 46

Can the Balassa Samuelson model explain the observed real depreciation of the German mark against the Japanese Yen and against the Italian Lira in the 1970s and 1980s? Canzoneri, Cumby, and Diba (JIE, 1999) collect data on productivity differential for the United States, Germany, Italy and Japan over the period 1970 to 1993. Consider the bilateral real exchange rate between the German Mark (DM) and the Italian Lira ( ): According to the Balassa Samuelson model we have % e DM/ = α [ % ( a I T a I N ) ( )] a G % T a G N 47

Over the long run, here 1970 to 1993, Balassa Samuelson explains well the observed real depreciation of the German mark against the Italian Lira. For it shows that the relative growth rate of labor productivity in the traded sector, relative to the nontraded sector, was higher in Italy than in Germany. These authors, however, also present evidence that the Balassa Samuelson model fails to explain the observed real appreciation of the Japanese yen against the U.S. dollar (not shown). What to make of this? In some episodes long-run changes in real exchange rates can be explained well by differences in relative productivity growth rates but not always. This is not necessarily evidence against Balassa Samuelson because clearly there can be other explanations for real exchange rate movements. We will turn to such alternative explanations next. 48

Add discussion on effects of trade barriers on real exchange rates 49

Add discussion on micro foundation of price indices. 50