Lecture 4: Properties of stock options



Similar documents
Lecture 5: Put - Call Parity

Lecture 7: Bounds on Options Prices Steven Skiena. skiena

9 Basics of options, including trading strategies

CHAPTER 7: PROPERTIES OF STOCK OPTION PRICES

Options. Moty Katzman. September 19, 2014

American Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan American Options

Factors Affecting Option Prices

Figure S9.1 Profit from long position in Problem 9.9

K 1 < K 2 = P (K 1 ) P (K 2 ) (6) This holds for both American and European Options.

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Option Properties. Liuren Wu. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Options Markets. (Hull chapter: 9)

Chapter 21: Options and Corporate Finance

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives

Finance 436 Futures and Options Review Notes for Final Exam. Chapter 9

Lecture 4: Derivatives

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi. Option Pricing

Lecture 12. Options Strategies

2. How is a fund manager motivated to behave with this type of renumeration package?

EC372 Bond and Derivatives Markets Topic #5: Options Markets I: fundamentals

Lecture 3: Forward Contracts Steven Skiena. skiena

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

1 Introduction to Option Pricing

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

How To Value Options In Black-Scholes Model

Lecture 3: Put Options and Distribution-Free Results

Notes for Lecture 2 (February 7)

Determination of Forward and Futures Prices. Chapter 5

Chapter 8 Financial Options and Applications in Corporate Finance ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Trading Strategies Involving Options. Chapter 11

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

Manual for SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2.

CHAPTER 22: FUTURES MARKETS

OPTIONS PRICING EXERCISE

a. What is the portfolio of the stock and the bond that replicates the option?

Underlying (S) The asset, which the option buyer has the right to buy or sell. Notation: S or S t = S(t)

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

American and European. Put Option

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems

2. Exercising the option - buying or selling asset by using option. 3. Strike (or exercise) price - price at which asset may be bought or sold

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 7 th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull

Chapter 17 Option Pricing with Applications to Real Options ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Name: 1 (5) a b c d e TRUE/FALSE 1 (2) TRUE FALSE. 2 (5) a b c d e. 3 (5) a b c d e 2 (2) TRUE FALSE. 4 (5) a b c d e.

Use the option quote information shown below to answer the following questions. The underlying stock is currently selling for $83.

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Lecture 21 Options Pricing

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 9. Binomial Trees : Hull, Ch. 12.

Financial Options: Pricing and Hedging

Chapter 2 An Introduction to Forwards and Options

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

Options Markets: Introduction

Option Premium = Intrinsic. Speculative Value. Value

Derivative: a financial instrument whose value depends (or derives from) the values of other, more basic, underlying values (Hull, p. 1).

SOLUTION1. exercise 1

Derivative Users Traders of derivatives can be categorized as hedgers, speculators, or arbitrageurs.

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

Lecture 11. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 7

A) 1.8% B) 1.9% C) 2.0% D) 2.1% E) 2.2%

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures

1 Further Pricing Relationships on Options

Other variables as arguments besides S. Want those other variables to be observables.

Chapter 6 Arbitrage Relationships for Call and Put Options

A short note on American option prices

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Mid-Term Spring 2003

Overview. Option Basics. Options and Derivatives. Professor Lasse H. Pedersen. Option basics and option strategies

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Bond Options, Caps and the Black Model

Assumptions: No transaction cost, same rate for borrowing/lending, no default/counterparty risk

DERIVATIVE SECURITIES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

ECMC49F Options Practice Questions Suggested Solution Date: Nov 14, 2005

Pricing Options: Pricing Options: The Binomial Way FINC 456. The important slide. Pricing options really boils down to three key concepts

CFA Level -2 Derivatives - I

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

Introduction to Options. Derivatives

Hedging Strategies Using Futures. Chapter 3

Arbitrage Restrictions on Option Prices. Class Objectives. Example of a mispriced call option

b. June expiration: = /32 % = % or X $100,000 = $95,

Hedging with Futures and Options: Supplementary Material. Global Financial Management

Option Payoffs. Problems 11 through 16: Describe (as I have in 1-10) the strategy depicted by each payoff diagram. #11 #12 #13 #14 #15 #16

Computational Finance Options

Solutions to Practice Questions (Bonds)

Chapter 20 Understanding Options

CHAPTER 22 Options and Corporate Finance

10 Binomial Trees One-step model. 1. Model structure. ECG590I Asset Pricing. Lecture 10: Binomial Trees 1

a. What is the sum of the prices of all the shares in the index before the stock split? The equation for computing the index is: N P i i 1

The Black-Scholes Formula

Chapter 2 Present Value

Understanding your account situation

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Lecture 15: Final Topics on CAPM

Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options

2 Stock Price. Figure S1.1 Profit from long position in Problem 1.13

Finance 350: Problem Set 6 Alternative Solutions

Transcription:

Lecture 4: Properties of stock options Reading: J.C.Hull, Chapter 9 An European call option is an agreement between two parties giving the holder the right to buy a certain asset (e.g. one stock unit) for a price K (strike price) at time T (maturity). An European put option is an agreement between two parties giving the holder the right to sell a certain asset (e.g. one stock unit) for a price K (strike price) at time T (maturity). An American option is an agreement where one can use the above right any time between 0 and time T. The word American or European does NOT refer to a geographic place. Most exchange-traded stock options have a life less than 1 year. 1 / 12

American versus European options Claim The price C of an American option is larger than the price c of an European option (with the same strike price K and maturity T ): c C. Proof Suppose that C < c. Instead of buying the European option we buy the American option. Then we can exercise the option at time T and there is no need to buy the more expensive European option. This shows that C should be larger than c. 2 / 12

The upper bound for prices of call options Claim The price C of an American call option (and therefore also the price c of an European call option) is smaller or equal than the spot price S 0 : c C S 0. Proof Suppose that C > S 0. We issue (i.e. sell) an American call option (for one stock with strike price K and maturity T ) to the market and obtain C(EUR). At the same time we buy one stock for the price S 0. So we have still C S 0 > 0 (EUR). 3 / 12

The other party of our contract has the right to buy from us one stock at any time up to the maturity date T. If he exercises his right we give him the stock which we have already bought, otherwise the stock remains our property. In any case we obtained C S 0 (EUR) from this deal and we are happy to have earned money without any risk (this is a typical arbitrage profit). Since arbitrage is not possible in our model we conclude that C S 0. 4 / 12

Basic assumptions in the theory of options Throughout our discussions in this course we will make the following assumptions: 1. There are no arbitrage opportunities, i.e. no party can get a riskless profit. 2. Borrowing and lending are possible at the risk-free interest rate r > 0 which is constant over time and is compounded continuously. 3. There are no transaction costs. For simplicity, we shall consider only stocks which do not pay dividends. 5 / 12

The lower bound for prices of European call options Claim Let c be the price of an European call option with strike price K and maturity T. Then the following inequality S 0 Ke rt c S 0 holds under the assumption that no dividend is payed on the stock. Proof The inequality c S 0 was already proved. Suppose that c + Ke rt < S 0. We will show that somebody can make an arbitrage profit in this case. 6 / 12

First Proof Suppose one trader has already the stock in his portfolio. Now he sees at the market the offer for a call option for the stock with strike price K and maturity T for a price c such that c + Ke rt < S 0. He immediately sells one stock, obtains S 0 EUR, buys the call option and puts the cash Ke rt on a deposit. After the maturity date T he then has K (EUR). At maturity date he exercises the call option and buys the stock with the cash K, and the stock is again in his portfolio. Thus he earned from this business S 0 (c + Ke rt ) EUR without any risk. 7 / 12

Second Proof We consider two portfolios. Portfolio A : 1 European call and cash = Ke rt. Portfolio B : 1 share. We shall compare the performance of these portfolios. After time T we have Portfolio A : The cash is worth K. If S T > K, the option is exercised and the portfolio is worth S T. If S T < K, option is not exercised and the portfolio is worth K. Thus the portfolio is worth max(s T, K). Portfolio B : the portfolio is worth S T. Here we use the assumption that no dividends are payed on the stock. 8 / 12

We see that portfolio A is worth at least as much as portfolio B at time T. Thus the worth of portfolio A at time 0 must be also bigger or equal than the worth of portfolio B, since otherwise we could make an arbitrage profit. Therefore c + Ke rt S 0. 9 / 12

Bounds for the price of a European put option Claim Let p be the price of an European put option with strike price K and maturity T. Then the following inequality Ke rt S 0 p Ke rt holds under the assumption that no dividend is payed on the stock. 10 / 12

Bounds for the price of a European put option Claim Let p be the price of an European put option with strike price K and maturity T. Then the following inequality Ke rt S 0 p Ke rt holds under the assumption that no dividend is payed on the stock. Proof (upper bound) Suppose that p > Ke rt is valid. One can sell (write) one put option for the stock obtaining p EUR. We take Ke rt EUR of this sum and make a deposit with interest rate r. After maturity time T the deposit has K EUR. The other party has the right to sell to us at maturity date T one stock for the price K. If this right is exercised we give the other party K EUR and we obtain the stock and still we have p Ke rt > 0 EUR in our pocket. A good deal! 10 / 12

Remark Similarly one proves that the price of an American put option is bounded by K. Here we can not deposit the money since the other party has the right to sell at any time between 0 and T. (lower bound) We consider two portfolios C and D and compare their performance. Portfolio C: 1 European put and 1 share. Portfolio D: cash = Ke rt. After time T we have Portfolio C: If S T < K, the put option is exercised, so we sell the share using our option and we obtain K EUR. If S T > K, the option is not exercised and the portfolio is worth S T. Thus the portfolio is worth max(s T, K). Portfolio D: The cash is worth K. 11 / 12

We see that portfolio C is worth at least as much as portfolio D at time T. Thus the worth of portfolio C at time 0 must be bigger or equal to the worth of portfolio D (since otherwise we could make an arbitrage profit): p + S 0 Ke rt p Ke rt S 0 12 / 12