1 U-shaped average variable costs

Similar documents
1 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

Economics II: Micro Fall 2009 Exercise session 5. Market with a sole supplier is Monopolistic.

chapter Behind the Supply Curve: >> Inputs and Costs Section 2: Two Key Concepts: Marginal Cost and Average Cost

Technology, Production, and Costs

x 2 + y 2 = 1 y 1 = x 2 + 2x y = x 2 + 2x + 1

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

Week 1: Functions and Equations

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen October 15, Lecture 13. Cost Function

Microeconomics Topic 6: Be able to explain and calculate average and marginal cost to make production decisions.

36 CHAPTER 1. LIMITS AND CONTINUITY. Figure 1.17: At which points is f not continuous?

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

MATH MODULE 5. Total, Average, and Marginal Functions. 1. Discussion M5-1

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Functions. MATH 160, Precalculus. J. Robert Buchanan. Fall Department of Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan Functions

Production and Cost Analysis

Zero: If P is a polynomial and if c is a number such that P (c) = 0 then c is a zero of P.

Microeconomics and mathematics (with answers) 5 Cost, revenue and profit

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

We will study the extreme case of perfect competition, where firms are price takers.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

Partial f (x; y) x f (x; x2 y2 and then we evaluate the derivative as if y is a constant.

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Costs of Production and Profit Maximizing Production: 3 examples.

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Demand. Lecture 3. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

Student Activity: To investigate an ESB bill

Profit maximization in different market structures

D) Marginal revenue is the rate at which total revenue changes with respect to changes in output.

SHORT-RUN PRODUCTION

GRAPHING IN POLAR COORDINATES SYMMETRY

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts

Practice Questions Week 8 Day 1

Chapter 04 Firm Production, Cost, and Revenue

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

Economics 10: Problem Set 3 (With Answers)

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Solving Quadratic Equations

Lecture Notes 10

Lab 12: Perfectly Competitive Market

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

The Graphical Method: An Example

Sample Problems. Practice Problems

Chapter 22 The Cost of Production Extra Multiple Choice Questions for Review

Microeconomics Sept. 16, 2010 NOTES ON CALCULUS AND UTILITY FUNCTIONS

Chapter 7: The Costs of Production QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

This unit will lay the groundwork for later units where the students will extend this knowledge to quadratic and exponential functions.

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Chapter 5 The Production Process and Costs

01 In any business, or, indeed, in life in general, hindsight is a beautiful thing. If only we could look into a

Algebra 1 Course Title

Cost of Production : An Example

QUADRATIC EQUATIONS AND FUNCTIONS

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Average rate of change of y = f(x) with respect to x as x changes from a to a + h:

MA107 Precalculus Algebra Exam 2 Review Solutions

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

Chapter 4. Polynomial and Rational Functions. 4.1 Polynomial Functions and Their Graphs

Introduction to Quadratic Functions

CORRELATED TO THE SOUTH CAROLINA COLLEGE AND CAREER-READY FOUNDATIONS IN ALGEBRA

Management Accounting 243 Pricing Decision Analysis

Chapter 6: Break-Even & CVP Analysis

Advanced Microeconomics

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

Lecture 9: Lines. m = y 2 y 1 x 2 x 1

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2

Plot the following two points on a graph and draw the line that passes through those two points. Find the rise, run and slope of that line.

1 Mathematical Models of Cost, Revenue and Profit

Section 3-7. Marginal Analysis in Business and Economics. Marginal Cost, Revenue, and Profit. 202 Chapter 3 The Derivative

QUADRATIC, EXPONENTIAL AND LOGARITHMIC FUNCTIONS

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Representation of functions as power series

Review of Production and Cost Concepts

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

Prot Maximization and Cost Minimization

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 13. THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models

Mathematics Online Instructional Materials Correlation to the 2009 Algebra I Standards of Learning and Curriculum Framework

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

2013 MBA Jump Start Program

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

Cosumnes River College Principles of Microeconomics Problem Set 6 Due Tuesday, March 24, 2015

MERSİN UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATIVE SCİENCES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MICROECONOMICS MIDTERM EXAM DATE

Transcription:

BEE1004 { Basic Mathematics for Economists BEE1005 { Introduction to Mathematical Economics Week 10, Lecture 2, part 2: Optimization III 04/12/2001 Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter 1 U-shaped average variable costs The third example of a total cost function discussed in the rst handout, week 6, was TC() =2 3 18 2 +60 +50 We want to know which quantity a pro t-maximizing rm with this cost function should produce when the market is perfectly competitive and the given market price is P. It turns out that the answer to this question depends on the average variable costs (AVC) and the marginal costs (MC). Hence, we must rst discuss how the average variable costs curve looks and how it relates to the marginal costs curve. In our example, the xed costs are FC =50andthevariablecostsarehence VC() =2 3 18 2 +60: Average costs are generally costs per item produced, so the average variable cost function is in our example 50 40 30 20 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 AV C () = VC() =2 2 18 +60: As the graph indicates, the AVC curve is U-shaped, i.e., it is strictly convex and has a unique absolute minimum at Min =4:5. The minimum average variable costs are calculated as AV C Min = AV C (4:5) = 19:5 To see algebraically that the AVC curve is indeed U-shaped with the describe properties we a) di erentiate b) solve the rst order condition AV C 0 () =4 18; AV C 0 () =4 18 = 0 or = 18 4 =4:5;

c) observe that there is a unique solution at 4:5; d) di erentiate again AV C 00 () =4> 0 and observe hence that our function is indeed strictly convex. In particular, Min =4:5is theabsoluteminimum. Recall that the marginal costs are the derivative of the total or variable costs (the latter two di er only by a constant term). They are MC () = dt C = dv C =62 36 +60 2 The relation between AVC, MC and supply Whenever the AVC curve is U-shaped, i.e., strictly convex with a unique absolute minimum, the following applies: 1) The AVC curve and the MC curve intersect in two points, once on the vertical axis and one in the minimum of the AVC curve. 2) In the downward-sloping part of the AVC curve the MC curve is below the AVC curve, in the upward-sloping part it is above. 3) Above the AVC curve marginal costs are strictly increasing. The following picture illustrates these facts in our example: 100 MC 80 60 40 20 AVC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Moreover, 4) The individual supply curve is given by the part of the MC curve above the AVC curve. More precisely: A) When the price is below the minimum average variable costs, it is optimal for the rm not to produce any output. B) When the price is above the minimum average variable costs, it is optimal for the rm to produce a positive amount of output. Namely, it is optimal to produce the largest quantity for which the price equals the marginal costs. C) When the price is exactly equal to the minimum average variable costs, two quantities are optimal to produce, namely zero and the quantity which minimizes AVC. Applied to our example this means the following: At prices below 19.5 it is optimal to produce zero. 2

or When the price is exactly 19.5, both =0an =4:5 are optimal. When the price is, for instance, P =30wemust rstsolvetheequationp = MC () 30 = 6 2 36 +60 0 = 6 2 36 +30=6 2 6 +5 =6( 1) ( 2) Here both =1an = 5 solve this equation. The larger of the two, =5,isthe pro t maximizing quantity. Using the genreal formula to solve quadratic equations one can obtain the supply function explicitly as follows: P = 6 2 36 +60 0 = 6 2 36 +60 P 0 = 2 6 +10 P q 6 1=2 = 6 36 4 s 10 P 6 36 4 10 P 6 = 3 2 4 r = 3 9 10 + P 6 and, by taking the larger root, one obtains the supply function r P S =3+ 6 1 valid for prices above 19:5. 3 Sketch of arguments Read this part only if you like math! Finally we indicate why the four facts stated above hold. For a more verbal presentation see Begg, Fischer, and Dornbusch (2000). Variable costs are, by de nition, the product of quantity and average variable costs: VC() = AV C () We can di erentiate this equation using the product rule and obtain MC () =AV C ()+ dav C From this equation we see that marginal costs are equal to average variable costs at the minimum of the AVC curve (since there dav C = 0), they are below the AVC curve when 3

the latter is downward-sloped ( dav C ( dav C > 0).1 Di erentiating again gives dmc = dav C + dav C < 0) and above when the latter is upward sloped + d2 AV C 2 =2 dav C 0. In the upward- dmc > 0andgetoverall > 0, i.e., the We have >0and,sincetheAV C curve is strictly convex, d2 AV C 2 slopingpartoftheavccurvewehave dav C + d2 AV C 2 marginal cost curve is increasing above the AVC curve. To see that the AVC curve and the MC curve meet on the vertical axis one has to know the de nition of the derivative as a limit of di erence quotient (or \rates of change") (see Ho mann and Bradley (2000), Chapter 2, Section 1). Actually, AV C () = VC() is a di erence quotient at zero and therefore MC (0) = dv C = VC() VC(0) 0 VC() VC(0) (0) = lim!0 0 = lim!0 AV C () : (AV C (0) is, of course, not de ned.) We have shown the statements 1-3 above. Concerning statement 4 I skip the very technical argument why an absolute pro t maximum always exists when the AVC curve is U-shaped. (Essentially one can show that the pro t function must be decreasing for very large quantities.) Assuming it exists, it can either be at = 0 or it can be at a positive quantity. In the latter case it must be a \peak" and hence the rst order condition P = MC () must be satis ed. It follows that the part of a supply curve where a strictly positive quantity is produced must be a part of the marginal cost curve. When zero output is produced, only the xed costs are to be paid: (0) = FC.For >0 we can rewrite the pro t function as follows: () = P VC() FC = P AV C () FC = (P AV C ()) FC For prices below the minimum average variable costs P AV C () is negative for all quantities >0. Therefore () < FC = (0) and it it is optimal to produce zero. In words: one loses on average more on variable costs per item produced than one gains in revenues and hence it is better to produce nothing. (The xed costs must be paid anyway.) For prices P>AVC Min only the largest solution to the equation P = MC () gives a point on the MC curve which is above the AVC curve. For this solution P = MC () > AV C () is satis ed and hence () > (0). For all other solutions () < (0). Hence this solution is the only candidate for the pro t maximum. Since we assumed one, this must be it. When P = AV C Min one has P = MC Min = AV C Min. Hence (0) = Min. All other critical points of the pro t function can be ruled out, so these two quantities must be optimal. 1 The AVC curve cannot have saddle points since it is assumed to be strictly convex. This rules out = 0 except for the minimum.. dav C 4

References Begg, D., S. Fischer, and R. Dornbusch (2000): Economics. McGraw Hill, London, sixth edn. Hoffmann, L. D., and G. L. Bradley (2000): Calculus for Business, Economics and the Social Sciences. McGraw Hill, Boston, 7th, international edn. 5