Economics 140A Identification in Simultaneous Equation Models Simultaneous Equation Models

Similar documents
CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

1.2 Solving a System of Linear Equations

160 CHAPTER 4. VECTOR SPACES

Partial Fractions Decomposition

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

IDENTIFICATION IN A CLASS OF NONPARAMETRIC SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS. Steven T. Berry and Philip A. Haile. March 2011 Revised April 2011

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

Lecture 1: Systems of Linear Equations

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

Chapter 3: The Multiple Linear Regression Model

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

3.3 Applications of Linear Functions

Solving Systems of Linear Equations Using Matrices

Demand. Lecture 3. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58

Corporate Income Taxation

Topic 1 - Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics?

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

The Binomial Distribution

Solutions to Math 51 First Exam January 29, 2015

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Systems of Linear Equations

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics Homework #1

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

Lecture 15. Endogeneity & Instrumental Variable Estimation

Empirical Methods in Applied Economics

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Chapter 5 Estimating Demand Functions

1 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

5 Systems of Equations

Math 1314 Lesson 8 Business Applications: Break Even Analysis, Equilibrium Quantity/Price

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Chapter 6 Cost-Volume-Profit Relationships

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis.

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

Sample Problems. Practice Problems

Row Echelon Form and Reduced Row Echelon Form

Session 7 Bivariate Data and Analysis

1 Present and Future Value

Lecture Notes 10

Financial Risk Management Exam Sample Questions/Answers

Section 1.5 Linear Models

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

Representation of functions as power series

Sample Problems. Practice Problems

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

CURVE FITTING LEAST SQUARES APPROXIMATION

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Use the following to answer question 9: Exhibit: Keynesian Cross

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Review of Chemical Equilibrium 7.51 September free [A] (µm)

Regression III: Advanced Methods

Lesson 5. Risky assets

Linear Algebra Notes

Productioin OVERVIEW. WSG5 7/7/03 4:35 PM Page 63. Copyright 2003 by Academic Press. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

As we explained in the textbook discussion of statistical estimation of demand

Adverse Selection. Chapter 3

Chapter 6. Linear Programming: The Simplex Method. Introduction to the Big M Method. Section 4 Maximization and Minimization with Problem Constraints

1 Determinants and the Solvability of Linear Systems

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan

The level of price and inflation Real GDP: the values of goods and services measured using a constant set of prices

To give it a definition, an implicit function of x and y is simply any relationship that takes the form:

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

Reduced echelon form: Add the following conditions to conditions 1, 2, and 3 above:

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

Supplement Unit 1. Demand, Supply, and Adjustments to Dynamic Change

Review Jeopardy. Blue vs. Orange. Review Jeopardy

Slope-Intercept Equation. Example

Mario Guarracino. Regression

Solving Systems of Linear Equations

The Cost of Production

The Basics of FEA Procedure

Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

4 THE MARKET FORCES OF SUPPLY AND DEMAND

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors

Microeconomics Topic 3: Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts

Panel Data Econometrics

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 8

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3: The Solow Growth Model

ECON 142 SKETCH OF SOLUTIONS FOR APPLIED EXERCISE #2

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS. + + x 2. x n. a 11 a 12 a 1n b 1 a 21 a 22 a 2n b 2 a 31 a 32 a 3n b 3. a m1 a m2 a mn b m

Transcription:

Economics 140A Identification in Simultaneous Equation Models Simultaneous Equation Models Our second extension of the classic regression model, to which we devote two lectures, is to a system (or model) of more than one equation Together, the equations describe the simultaneous evolution of multiple endogenous variables and are termed simultaneous equation models Up to this point, we have considered structures in which only one variable, the dependent variable, is endogenous We often think of the regressors as causing the movements in the dependent variable in that the regressors can be conditioned upon when studying the dependent variable In many cases of interest to economists the conditional structure of a single equation breaks down, as two or more quantities are jointly determined Perhaps the simplest such structure is to consider price and quantity for a speci c market (eg Vans tennis shoes in Santa Barbara) One might think of the following structure P t = 0 + 1 Q t + U t ; where P t is the price of a pair of shoes in period-t and Q t is the quantity of shoes sold in the corresponding period Without question, the price of shoes is a ected by the quantity available Surplus inventories are sold at discount and goods in short supply often sell at a premium Yet, unless the Santa Barbara market forms only a tiny portion of total supply, the price at which the shoes are sold a ects the quantity Shoes sold at discount re ect excess inventories and indicate that production should fall, the converse holds for shoes sold at a premium If the regressor is also a function of the dependent variable, it is clear that the regressor is correlated with the error and a classic assumption is violated To overcome the bias (and inconsistency) of the OLS estimators, one could proceed with IV estimation Yet not only is an adequate instrument rarely at hand, but often understanding of the economy requires that we more fully investigate the joint determination of the endogenous variables To do so, it is helpful to distinguish between the theoretical quantities Q D t, which is the quantity of shoes demanded by consumers, and Q S t, which is the quantity of shoes supplied by producers We think of Q D t as arising from a demand function Q D t = 1 + 2 P t + U 1t ;

where we expect 2 < 0 We think of Q S t as arising from a supply function Q S t = 1 + 2 P t + U 2t ; where we expect 2 > 0 The two quantities are theoretical because they are not separately observed, the equilibrium condition that Q D t = Q S t = Q t ensures that only Q t is observed It is not possible to estimate the parameters of the demand and supply functions by the method of OLS The reason is that the parameters are not identi ed Recall from our earlier discussion that if a parameter is not identi ed, then the population value of the parameter cannot be deduced (by any method) with an in nite amount of data For single equation models, identi cation fails if: the regressor does not vary over observations or if the population covariance of the regressor and the error is not zero As P t depends on Q t, the population covariance between the regressor and the error is not zero and identi cation fails (Use the graph from the bottom of page 2 of handwritten notes) Connecting the two observations from the shifted curves, we see that we would estimate a linear combination of the coe cients from the two equations To understand how to restore identi cation, we write the system as (the equilibrium condition allows us to replace both Q D t and Q S t with Q t, thereby reducing to a system of two equations) Q t = 1 + 2 P t + U 1t ; Q t = 1 + 2 P t + U 2t ; where the rst equation, again, captures demand and the second equation captures supply Suppose that demand depends not only on the price of the shoes but also on the average household income, Y t : Q t = 1 + 2 P t + 3 Y t + U 1t : As long as the quantity of shoes supplied does not depend on average household income in Santa Barbara, the supply equation is unchanged For such a system, if the average household income changes from one period to the next, then the demand curve shifts but the supply curve remains constant and the slope of the supply curve can be estimated 2

(Use the graph from the top of page 3 of handwritten notes) Now suppose that supply depends not only on the price of shoes but also on the hourly wage paid to shoe makers, W t : Q t = 1 + 2 P t + 3 W t + U 2t : As long as the quantity of shoes demanded in Santa Barbara does not depend on the wage paid to shoe makers, the demand equation is unchanged For such a system, if the hourly wage paid to shoe makers changes from one period to the next, then the supply curve shifts but the demand curve remains constant and the slope of the demand curve can be estimated (Graph shifting supply, constant demand) With both Y t and W t present, one might think that we were back to the system with both demand and supply curves shifting with no identi cation Yet there is an important di erence Both Y t and W t are observed For all observations with a given average income, we can trace out the supply curve, while for all observations with a given hourly wage rate we can trace out the demand curve Of course, it is possible that only one of the equations is identi ed Suppose that the demand for shoes depended on Y t but that the supply of shoes did not depend on W t Because the demand function has the necessary shifter, it is possible to trace out the supply curve and the supply equation is identi ed As there is no unique shifter of supply, it is not possible to trace out the demand curve, and the demand function is not identi ed To make the point mathematically, consider a linear combination of the two equations Q t = ( 1 + 2 P t + 3 Y t + U 1t ) + (1 ) ( 1 + 2 P t + U 2t ) ; where 0 < < 1 Rewriting the linear combination yields Q t = 1 + 2P t + 3Y t + U t ; which is observationally equivalent to the demand function When estimating the demand function, we cannot distinguish between estimation of ( 1 ; 2 ; 3 ) and ( 1; 2; 3) That is, we cannot distinguish between estimating the demand function and estimating a linear combination of the demand and supply functions and so the parameters of the demand function are not identi ed As the presence of 3 makes the equation distinct from the supply function, the parameters of the supply function are identi ed 3

The need for an exogenous (or predetermined) shifter in each equation points toward the necessary, but not su cient, condition for identi cation This condition, termed the order condition for each equation, is Order Condition: The number of predetermined variables in the system is greater than or equal to the number of slope coe cients in the equation To see that the order condition is only necessary, consider the case in which Z t = Y t, rather than W t, appeared in the supply function As we have two predetermined variables, Y t and Z t, and two slope coe cients in each equation, the order condition is satis ed Yet, because the supply function contains Y t, the linear combination is not distinct from the supply function, and identi cation of the supply equation fails It is necessary that the shifters to the two equations be distinct Linearly distinct predetermined variables is also not su cient We typically assume the predetermined variables are distinct and then ask if it is possible to distinguish each equation from all (nontrivial) linear combinations of the other equations in the system The su cient condition for identi cation is the Rank Condition For each equation: Each of the variables excluded from the equation must appear in at least one of the other equations (no zero columns) Also, at least one of the variables excluded from the equation must appear in each of the other equations (no zero rows) The condition is more commonly stated as Rank Condition For each equation: Consider the set of variables excluded from the equation The matrix of coe cients for these variables in the other equations must have full row rank A structural equation is identi ed only when the predetermined variables are arranged within the system so as to use the observed equilibrium points to distinguish the shape of the equation under study Consider applying the conditions to a general example of such a system Y 1t = 1 + 2 X 1t + 3 X 3t + U 1t ; Y 2t = 1 + 2 Y 3t + 3 X 1t + 4 X 2t + U 2t ; Y 3t = 1 + 2 Y 1t + 3 X 1t + 4 X 3t + U 3t ; for which Y 1t, Y 2t and Y 3t are the jointly endogenous variables The equations in the system are termed structural equations, as they characterize the economic theory underpinning the determination of each endogenous variable A variable is endogenous because it is jointly determined (a change in Y 1t leads to a change in Y 3t, which in turn leads to a change in Y 2t ) Exogenous variables may appear 4

in all equations, witness X 1t As to what is endogenous and what is exogenous, why that depends on the scope of the partial equilibrium model under study To verify the order condition, note that there are 3 predetermined variables in the system (X 1t ; X 2t ; X 3t ) and no more than 3 slope coe cients in any one equation To verify the rank condition, we use the following table, in which indicates a variable appears in the given equation and 0 indicates a variable does not appear in the given equation: Equation Y 1t Y 2t Y 3t X 1t X 2t X 3t 1 0 0 0 2 0 0 3 0 0 We study the 3 6 matrix of 0 s and s For equation i, rst select the columns corresponding to the variables that do not appear in equation i From this submatrix, delete row i If the remaining submatrix has rank greater than or equal to m 1, where m is the number of equations in the system, then the rank condition is satis ed for the equation and the parameters of the equation are identi ed Consider equation 1 The variables (Y 2t ; Y 3t ; X 2t ) are all excluded, so the relevant submatrix is 0 0 The two rows are linearly distinct, as there is no possible multiple of the rst row that equals the second The rank is 2 and the equation is identi ed For equation 2, the excluded variables are (Y 1t ; X 3t ), so the relevant submatrix is The two rows are linearly distinct as long as the coe cients of one row are not proportional to the coe cients of the other row Absent proportionality, the rank is 2 and the equation is identi ed For equation 3, the excluded variables are (Y 2t ; X 2t ), so the relevant submatrix is 0 0 5

The two rows are not linearly distinct, as multiplying the rst column by a constant (the proportional factor relating the two elements of the second row) produces the second column The rank is 1 and equation 3 is not identi ed An alternative way to see this is to return to our discussion of linear combinations of the equations A linear combination of any two equations is distinct from the rst and second equations A linear combination of the rst and third equations, however, is not distinct from the third equation What would restore identi cation? We need to ensure that equation 3 is distinct from a linear combination of equations 1 and 3 One way is to replace X 1t with X 2t The solution seems natural as now each of the 3 equations has a distinct shifter: (X 1 ; X 3 ) in equation 1, (X 1 ; X 2 ) in equation 2 and (X 2 ; X 3 ) in equation 3 Before both equation 1 and equation 3 shared the same shifter (X 1 ; X 3 ) Surprisingly, this is not the only way to restore identi cation Thus it is possible that both equation 1 and equation 3 share the same shifter (X 1 ; X 3 ) and yet are both identi ed To do so, add Y 2t to the rst equation Clearly, the third equation is now distinct from a linear combination of equations 1 and 3 and the equation is identi ed (By adding Y 2t we have made Y 1t a function of X 2t ) From the example it is clear that the distribution of the predetermined variables depends crucially on the distribution of the endogenous variables 6