Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities

Similar documents
Implied Volatility of Leveraged ETF Options

Mathematical Finance

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

Lecture. S t = S t δ[s t ].

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

The Black-Scholes Formula

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

Stochastic Volatility and Option Pricing in the Brazilian Stock Market: An Empirical Investigation

Finite Differences Schemes for Pricing of European and American Options

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

Private Equity Fund Valuation and Systematic Risk

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

Option Pricing. Chapter 9 - Barrier Options - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 9th December 2013

Exam MFE Spring 2007 FINAL ANSWER KEY 1 B 2 A 3 C 4 E 5 D 6 C 7 E 8 C 9 A 10 B 11 D 12 A 13 E 14 E 15 C 16 D 17 B 18 A 19 D

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

Numerical methods for American options

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Methods to Evaluate Option Prices under Multi-factor Stochastic Volatility Models

Lecture 6 Black-Scholes PDE

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

A Vega-Gamma Relationship for European-Style or Barrier Options in the Black-Scholes Model

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Stanford Financial Mathematics Seminar February 28, 2003

Vanna-Volga Method for Foreign Exchange Implied Volatility Smile. Copyright Changwei Xiong January last update: Nov 27, 2013

Black-Scholes and the Volatility Surface

Option Pricing. Chapter 11 Options on Futures. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13/01/2014 at 14:25

Risk-Neutral Valuation of Participating Life Insurance Contracts

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Option Pricing. Chapter 12 - Local volatility models - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13th January 2014

Implied Volatility of Leveraged ETF Options: Consistency and Scaling

On the Valuation of Power-Reverse Duals and Equity-Rates Hybrids

A new Feynman-Kac-formula for option pricing in Lévy models

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

LOG-TYPE MODELS, HOMOGENEITY OF OPTION PRICES AND CONVEXITY. 1. Introduction

More Exotic Options. 1 Barrier Options. 2 Compound Options. 3 Gap Options

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

Properties of the SABR model

Arbitrage-Free Pricing Models

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

Volatility Index: VIX vs. GVIX

Hedging Exotic Options

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

TULLIE, TRACEY ANDREW. Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation of. for the evolution of an asset price under constant volatility.

Article from: Risk Management. June 2009 Issue 16

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Stock Price Dynamics, Dividends and Option Prices with Volatility Feedback

Oscillatory Reduction in Option Pricing Formula Using Shifted Poisson and Linear Approximation

LECTURE 9: A MODEL FOR FOREIGN EXCHANGE

Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems

ON DETERMINANTS AND SENSITIVITIES OF OPTION PRICES IN DELAYED BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Stephane Crepey. Financial Modeling. A Backward Stochastic Differential Equations Perspective. 4y Springer

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model

On the Existence of a Unique Optimal Threshold Value for the Early Exercise of Call Options

Master s Thesis. Pricing Constant Maturity Swap Derivatives

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

Invesco Great Wall Fund Management Co. Shenzhen: June 14, 2008

Two-State Option Pricing

Some Practical Issues in FX and Equity Derivatives

Options 1 OPTIONS. Introduction

Explicit Option Pricing Formula for a Mean-Reverting Asset in Energy Markets

The real P&L in Black-Scholes and Dupire Delta hedging

Implied Volatility Surface

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Derivation of Local Volatility by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

Consistent Pricing of FX Options

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

where N is the standard normal distribution function,

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

Understanding Options and Their Role in Hedging via the Greeks

Additional questions for chapter 4

Implied Volatility of Leveraged ETF Options: Consistency and Scaling

ELECTRICITY REAL OPTIONS VALUATION

Lecture 11: The Greeks and Risk Management

Alternative Price Processes for Black-Scholes: Empirical Evidence and Theory

Chapter 6: The Black Scholes Option Pricing Model

Pricing American Options without Expiry Date

Valuation, Pricing of Options / Use of MATLAB

Black-Scholes Equation for Option Pricing

Binomial lattice model for stock prices

Markov modeling of Gas Futures

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Online Appendix. Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and. Equilibrium Prices. by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos

Barrier Options. Peter Carr

The Heston Model. Hui Gong, UCL ucahgon/ May 6, 2014

Computational Finance Options

Quantitative Strategies Research Notes

Barrier Option Pricing

Lecture 1: Stochastic Volatility and Local Volatility

Hedging Barriers. Liuren Wu. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College (

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Transcription:

Calibration of Stock Betas from Skews of Implied Volatilities Jean-Pierre Fouque University of California Santa Barbara Joint work with Eli Kollman (Ph.D. student at UCSB) Joint Seminar: Department of Systems Engineering and Engineering Management Department of Statistics March 19, 009 The Chinese University of Hong Kong 1

Capital Asset Pricing Model The original discrete time CAPM model defined the log price return on individual asset R a as a linear function of the risk free interest rate R f, the log return of the market R M, and a Gaussian error term: R a R f = β a (R M R f ) + ǫ a The beta coefficient β a was originally estimated using historical returns on the asset and market index, by a simple linear regression of asset returns on market returns. Fundamental flaw: it is inherently backward looking, and used in forward looking portfolio construction.

Previous Attempt to Forward Looking Betas Christoffersen, Jacobs, and Vainberg (008, McGill University, Canada) have attempted to extract the beta parameter from option prices on the underlying market and asset processes: β a = ( SKEWa SKEW M )1 3 ( V AR a V AR M )1, where V AR a (resp. V AR M ), and SKEW a (resp. SKEW M ) are the variance, and the risk-neutral skewness of returns of the asset (resp. of the market). Then, they use results from Carr and Madan (001) which relate these moments to options prices (Quad and Cubic) on the asset (resp. on the market). The advantage of this approach is that option prices are inherently forward looking on the underlying price processes. 3

Continuous Time CAPM The market price M t and an asset price X t evolve as follows: dm t M t = µdt + σ m dw (1) t, dx t X t = β dm t + σdw () t, M t for constant positive volatilities σ m and σ. In this model we assume independence between the Brownian motions driving the market and asset price processes: d W (1), W () t = 0, so that ( ) Cov dxt X t, dm t M t V ar dm t M t = = Cov Cov ( β dm t M t + σdw () t V ar dm t M ( ) t β dm t M t, dm t M t V ar dm t M t = β. ), dm t M t 4

Beta Estimation with Constant Volatility CAPM Observe that the evolution of X t is given by dx t X t = βµdt + βσ m dw (1) t + σdw () t, that is a geometric Brownian motion with volatility β σ m + σ Even if this quantity is known, along with the volatility σ m of the market process, one cannot disentangle β and σ. Then, one has to rely on historical returns data. This drawback, along with the fact that constant volatility does not generate skews, motivates us to introduce stochastic volatility in the model. 5

Stochastic Volatility in Continuous Time CAPM We introduce a stochastic volatility component to the market price process, that is we replace σ m by a stochastic process σ t = f(y t ): dm t M t = µdt + f(y t )dw (1) dx t X t = β dm t + σdw () t, M t t, dy t = 1 ǫ (m Y t)dt + ν ǫ dz t. In this model, the volatility process is driven by a mean-reverting OU process Y t with a large mean-reversion rate 1/ε and the invariant (long-run) distribution N(m, ν ). This model also implies stochastic volatility in the asset price through its dependence on the market return. It allows leverage: d W (1),Z t = ρ dt. However, we continue to assume independence between W () t and the other two Brownian motions W (1) t and Z t in order to preserve the interpretation of β. 6

Pricing Risk-Neutral Measure The market (or index) and the asset being both tradable, their discounted prices need to be martingales under a pricing risk-neutral measure. Setting with (W (1) t, W () t, W (3) t dm t M t = rdt + f(y t ) dx t X t = rdt + βf(y t ) Z t = ρ dw (1) t + 1 ρ dw (3) t, dy t = 1 ǫ (m Y t)dt ν [ ρ µ r ε + ν ( [ρ dw (1) ǫ t ) being three independent BMs, we write: ( dw (1) t + µ r ) f(y t ) dt, ( dw (1) t + µ r ) ( f(y t ) dt + σ dw () t + f(y t ) + ] 1 ρ γ(y t ) dt + µ r ) f(y t ) dt + ( 1 ρ (β 1)r σ ) dt, dw (3) t + γ(y t )dt) ]. 7

Market price of risk and risk-neutral measure γ(y t ) is a market price of volatility risk, and we defined the combined market price of risk: Setting Λ(Y t ) = ρ µ r f(y t ) + 1 ρ γ(y t ). dw (1) t = dw (1) t dw () t = dw () t + + µ r f(y t ) dt, (β 1)r σ dw (3) t = dw (3) t + γ(y t )dt, by Girsanov theorem, there is an equivalent probability IP (γ) such that (W (1) t, W () t, W (3) t ) are independent BMs under IP (γ), called the pricing equivalent martingale measure and determined by the market price of volatility risk γ. dt, 8

Dynamics under the risk-neutral measure Under IP (γ), the model becomes: dm t M t = rdt + f(y t )dw (1) t, dx t X t = rdt + βf(y t )dw (1) t + σdw () t, dy t = 1 ǫ (m Y t)dt ν ε Λ(Y t )dt + ν ǫ dz t, Z t = ρw (1) t + 1 ρ W (3) t. We take the point of view that by pricing options on the index M and on the particular asset X, the market is completing itself and indirectly choosing the market price of volatility risk γ. 9

Market Option Prices Let P M,ǫ denote the price of a European option written on the market index M, with maturity T and payoff h, evaluated at time t < T with current value M t = ξ. Then, we have P M,ǫ = IE (γ) { e r(t t) h(m T ) F t } = P M,ǫ (t, M t, Y t ), By the Feynman-Kac formula, the function P M,ǫ (t, ξ, y) satisfies the partial differential equation: where L ǫ P M,ǫ = 0, P M,ǫ (T, ξ, y) = h(ξ), L ǫ = 1 ǫ L 0 + 1 ǫ L 1 + L 10

Operator Notation L 0 = ν y + (m y) y L OU L 1 = ρν f(y)ξ ξ y ν Λ(y) y L = t + 1 f(y) ξ ξ + r(ξ ξ ) L BS(f(y)) Here L BS (σ) denotes the Black-Scholes operator with volatility parameter σ. The next step is to expand P M,ǫ in powers of ǫ P M,ǫ = P M 0 + ǫp M 1 + ǫp M + ǫ 3/ P M 3 + 11

Expanding Expansion of the solution ( 1 ǫ L 0 + 1 ǫ L 1 + L )(P M 0 + ǫp M 1 + ǫp M + ǫ 3/ P M 3 + ) = 0, one cancel the terms in 1/ε and 1/ ε by choosing P M 0 and P M 1 independent of y (observe that L 1 takes derivatives with respect y). The terms of order ε 0 lead to L 0 P M + L P M 0 = 0, which is a Poisson equation associated with L 0. The centering condition for this equation is L P M 0 = L P M 0 = 0, where denotes the averaging with respect to the invariant distribution of Y t with infinitesimal generator L 0. 1

Noting that Leading order term L = t + 1 σ ξ ξ + r(ξ ξ ) = L BS( σ), with σ = f, and imposing the terminal condition P0 M (T, ξ) = h(ξ), we deduce that P0 M is the Black-Scholes price of the option computed with the constant effective volatility σ. We also have P M = L 1 0 (L L )P M 0. so that the terms of order ε lead to L 0 P3 M + L 1 P M + L P1 M = 0, which is again a Poisson equation in P3 M which requires the solvability condition L 1 P M + L P1 M = 0. 13

Equation for the first correction L P M 1 + L 1 P M = L P M 1 L 1 L 1 0 (L L ) P M 0 = 0. Therefore P1 M is the solution to the Black-Scholes equation with constant volatility σ, with a zero terminal condition, and a source term given by L 1 L 1 0 (L L ) P0 M. In order to compute this source term we introduce a solution φ(y) of the Poisson equation L 0 φ(y) = f(y) f, so that L 1 L 1 0 (L L ) P M 0 = = ( 1 L 1 φ(y)ξ ξ = ρν φ f ξ ξ ( ξ P M 0 ξ ( ) 1 L 1 L 1 0 (f(y) f )ξ P M ξ 0 ) P0 M = 1 L 1φ ξ P0 M ξ ) ν φ Λ ξ P M 0 ξ 14

First correction and market parameters The first correction term ε P M 1 L ( ε P M 1 ) + V M,ε ξ P M 0 ξ ( ε P M 1 )(T, ξ) = 0. solves the following problem: + V M,ε 3 ξ ( ξ P M ) 0 = 0, ξ ξ with V M,ǫ = ǫν φ Λ and V M,ǫ ǫρν 3 = φ f. In fact, the solution is given explicitly by ( ε P M 1 = (T t) V M,ε ξ P0 M ξ + V M,ε 3 ξ ξ One can then deduce the price approximation ( P M,ε = P0 M + (T t) V M,ε ξ P0 M ξ + V M,ε 3 ξ ξ ( ξ P M 0 ξ ( ξ P M 0 ξ )). )) + O(ε). 15

Parameter Reduction One of the inherent advantages of this approximation is parameter reduction. While the full stochastic volatility model requires the four parameters (ǫ, ν, ρ, m) and the two functions f and γ, our approximated option price requires only the three group parameters: The effective historical volatility σ The volatility level correction V M,ǫ due to the market price of volatility risk The skew parameter V M,ǫ 3 proportional to ρ We can further reduce to only two parameters by noting that V M,ǫ is associated with a second order derivative with respect to the current market price ξ. As such, it can be considered as a volatility level correction and absorbed into the volatility of the leading order Black-Scholes price. 16

Adjusted effective volatility We introduce the adjusted effective volatility σ M = σ + V M,ε, and we denote by P M the corresponding Black-Scholes option price. Next, we define the first order correction εp1 M solution to L BS (σ M )( ε P1 M ) + V M,ε 3 ξ (ξ P M ) 0 = 0, ξ ξ ( ε P M 1 )(T, ξ) = 0. It is indeed given explicitly by ε P M 1 = (T t)v M,ε 3 ξ ξ (ξ P M 0 ξ and one can show that the order of accuracy is preserved: P M,ε = P0 M + (T t)v M,ε 3 ξ (ξ P M ) 0 + O(ε) ξ ξ ), 17

Observe that and therefore Proof of order of accuracy L BS (σ M ) = L BS ( σ) + 1 L BS ( σ)(p M 0 (P M 0 P M 0 )(T, ξ) = 0. (V M,ε )ξ ξ, P0 M ) = V M,ε ξ P0 M ξ, Since the source term is O( ε) because of the V M,ε factor, the difference P0 M P0 M is also O( ε). Next we write P M,ε (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ) P M,ε (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ) + (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ) (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ), which, combined with the previous accuracy result, shows that the only quantity left to be controlled is the residual R (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ) (P M 0 + ε P M 1 ). 18

Proof of order of accuracy (continued) From the equations satisfied by P0 M, ε P1 M, P0 M, ε P1 M, it follows that L BS ( σ)(p M 0 + ε P M 1 ) + V M,ε ξ P M 0 ξ L BS (σ M )(P M 0 + ε P M 1 ) + V M,ε 3 ξ ξ ( ξ P0 M ξ + V M,ε 3 ξ ξ (ξ P0 M ) ξ = 0. ) = 0 Denoting by H ε = V M,ε ξ ξ + V M,ε 3 ξ ξ H ε = V M,ε 3 ξ ) (ξ, ξ ξ (ξ ), ξ one deduces that the residual R satisfies the equation: 19

L BS ( σ)(r) = H ε P M 0 ( ) L BS (σ M ) V M,ε ξ ξ (P0 M + ε P1 M ) = H ε P M 0 + H ε P M 0 + V M,ε = H ε (P M 0 P M 0 ) + V M,ε = O(ε), ξ M (P ξ ξ M (P ξ 1 ) 0 + ε P M 0 P M 0 + ε P M where we have used in the last equality that H ε = O( ε), V M,ε = O( ε), P0 M P0 M = O( ε), and ε P1 M = O( ε). Since R vanishes at the terminal time T, we deduce R = O(ε) which concludes the proof. The new approximation has now only two parameters to be calibrated σ M and V M,ǫ 3, while preserving the accuracy of approximation. This parameter reduction is essential in the forward-looking calibration procedure presented next. 1 ) 0

Asset Option Approximation Let P a,ǫ denote the price of a European option written on the asset X, with maturity T and payoff h, evaluated at time t < T with current value X t = x. Then, we have P a,ǫ = IE (γ) { e r(t t) h(x T ) F t } = P a,ǫ (t, X t, Y t ). By the Feynman-Kac formula, the function P a,ǫ (t, x, y) satisfies the partial differential equation: where L a,ǫ P a,ǫ = 0, P a,ǫ (T, x, y) = h(x), 1

L a,ǫ = 1 ǫ L 0 + 1 ǫ L a 1 + L a, with L 0 = ν y + (m y) y, L a 1 = ρν βf(y)x x y ν Λ(y) y, L a = t + 1 ( β f(y) + σ ) x x + r(x x ) L BS( β f(y) + σ ). Observe that the only differences with options on the market index is the factor β in L a 1, and the modified square volatility β f(y) + σ in L a. it is easy to see that the only modifications in the approximation are:

1. σ is replaced by σ a = β σ + σ. V M,ε is replaced by V a,ε = β V M,ε = V a,ǫ = β ǫν φ Λ 3. V M,ε 3 is replaced by V a,ε 3 = β 3 V M,ε 3 = V a,ǫ 3 = β3 ǫρν φ f 4. σ M is replaced by σ a = β σ + σ + V a,ε 5. The option price approximation becomes P a,ε = P a 0 + (T t)v a,ε 3 x x (x P a 0 x ) + O(ε), where P a 0 is the Black-Scholes price with volatility σ a 6. Only the parameters V a,ε 3 and σ a need to be calibrated 3

Beta Estimation From the expressions for V M,ε 3 and V a,ε 3, one deduces that V a,ε 3 = β 3 V M,ε 3. It is then natural to propose the following estimator for β: β = ( V a,ǫ 3 V M,ǫ 3 Therefore in order to estimate the market beta parameter in a forward looking fashion using the implied skew parameters from option prices we must calibrate our two parameters V a,ǫ 3 and V M,ǫ 3. Next we show how to do that by using the implied volatility surfaces from options data. ) 1 3. 4

Calibration Method We know that a first order approximation of an option price (on the market or the individual asset) with time to maturity τ = T t, and in the presence of fast mean-reverting stochastic volatility, takes the following form: P ǫ P BS + τv ǫ 3 x x ( x P BS x ), where P BS is the Black-Scholes price with volatility σ. The European call option price PBS with current price x, time to maturity τ, and strike price K is given by the Black-Scholes formula P BS = xn(d 1) Ke rτ N(d ), where N is the cumulative standard normal distribution and d 1, = log(x/k) + (r ± 1 σ )τ σ τ. 5

Recall the relationship between Vega and Gamma for plain vanilla European options: P BS σ = τσ x P BS x, and rewrite our price approximation as P ǫ PBS + V 3 ǫ σ x x ( P BS σ ). Using the definition of the implied volatility P BS (I) = P ε, and expanding the implied volatility as I = σ + ǫi 1 + ǫi +, we obtain: P BS (σ ) + ǫi 1 P BS (σ ) σ + = PBS + V 3 ǫ σ x x ( P BS σ ) +. 6

By definition P BS (σ ) = PBS, so that ǫi1 = V ǫ 3 σ ( P BS σ ) 1 x x ( P BS σ ). Using the explicit computation of the Vega P BS σ = x τ e d 1 /, π and consequently x x ( P BS σ ) = ( 1 d 1 σ τ ) P BS σ, we deduce by using the definition of d 1: ǫi1 = V 3 ǫ ( ) σ 1 d 1 σ = V 3 ǫ τ σ ( 1 r σ ) + V 3 ǫ log(k/x) σ 3. τ 7

Define Log-Moneyness to Maturity Ratio (LMMR) LMMR = log(k/x) τ we obtain the affine LMMR formula I σ + ǫi 1 = b + a ǫ LMMR, with the intercept b and the slope a ε to be fitted to the skew of options data, and related to our model parameters σ and V3 ε by: b = σ + V 3 ǫ σ a ǫ = V 3 ǫ σ 3., ( 1 r ) σ, 8

Calibration Formulas for V ε 3 We know that b and σ differ from a quantity of order ε. Therefore by replacing σ by b in the relation V3 ǫ = a ǫ σ 3, the order of accuracy for V3 ε is still ε since a ε is also of order ε. Consequently we deduce V ǫ 3 = a ǫ σ 3 a ǫ b 3 V ε 3. It is indeed also possible to extract σ as follows. b = σ + aε σ ( 1 r ) ) = σ a (r ε σ. σ Using again the argument that b and σ differ from a quantity of order ε and a ε is also of order ε, by replacing σ by b in the last term in the relation above, the order of accuracy is still ε, and we conclude that σ b + a ǫ (r b ) σ. 9

Beta Calibration Defining the market fitted parameters as a M,ǫ and b M and the asset parameters as a a,ǫ and b a, we obtain our main formula: ˆβ = V a,ǫ 3 V M,ǫ 3 1/3 = ( a a,ǫ a M,ǫ ) 1/3 ( b a b M where b a + a a,ǫ LMMR (resp. b M + a M,ǫ LMMR) is the linear fit to the skew of implied volatilities for call options on the individual asset (resp. on the market index). Observe the similarity with the formula ), β a = ( SKEWa SKEW M )1 3 ( V AR a V AR M )1, used by Christoffersen, Jacobs, and Vainberg (008). 30

In the following figure: LMMR fit examples Implied volatilities of June 17, 009 maturity options for the S&P 500 and Amgen, plotted against the option s Log-Moneyness to Maturity Ratio (LMMR). These are for February 18, 009 option prices. The blue line is the affine fit of implied volatilities on LMMR by which the V 3 parameter is fit. The parameters fit for each series are S&P 500 Fit: a M,ǫ = 0.11 and b M = 0.48 V M,ǫ 3 = 0.0095 Amgen Fit: a a,ǫ = 0.18 and b a = 0.434 V a,ǫ 3 = 0.010 The beta estimate for Amgen on that day is then 1.03 31

LMMR fits: S&P500 and Amgen 0.55 S&P 500 0.55 AMGN 0.5 0.5 Implied Vol 0.45 0.4 Implied Vol 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.35 0.3 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 LMMR 0.3 1 0.5 0 0.5 1 LMMR 3

Forward and Backward Looking Betas In the following figure: The solid blue line is the forward looking beta (y-axis) calibrated on June 17, 009 expiration call options over the course of 10 market days (x-axis) from February 9, 009 to February 3, 009. The dashed red line is the corresponding historical beta calibrated on a series of historical prices of the same length as the time to maturity of the options. 33

4 AA 4 AMGN 4 AMZN 0 4 5 10 ATI 0 4 5 10 CEG 0 4 5 10 GE 0 4 5 10 GOOG 0 4 5 10 GS 0 4 5 10 IBM 0 4 5 10 PEP 0 4 5 10 XOM 0 5 10 0 5 10 0 5 10 34

THANKS FOR YOUR ATTENTION 35