Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 7



Similar documents
3. The Economics of Insurance

Fund Manager s Portfolio Choice

3.2 Measures of Spread

Introduction to Game Theory IIIii. Payoffs: Probability and Expected Utility

Demand and supply of health insurance. Folland et al Chapter 8

Introduction to the Practice of Statistics Fifth Edition Moore, McCabe Section 4.4 Homework

= = 106.

University of California, Los Angeles Department of Statistics. Random variables

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

MEASURES OF VARIATION

Holding Period Return. Return, Risk, and Risk Aversion. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? An Example. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? 10% or 10?

Decision & Risk Analysis Lecture 6. Risk and Utility

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Example. A casino offers the following bets (the fairest bets in the casino!) 1 You get $0 (i.e., you can walk away)

Lecture 10 - Risk and Insurance

Intermediate Micro. Expected Utility

Risk and Uncertainty. Vani K Borooah University of Ulster

Mathematics of Risk. Introduction. Case Study #1 Personal Auto Insurance Pricing. Mathematical Concepts Illustrated. Background

Choice under Uncertainty

Answer Key to Problem Set #2: Expected Value and Insurance

Math 151. Rumbos Spring Solutions to Assignment #22

University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. Business 41000: Business Statistics

Chapter 4 Lecture Notes

Chapter 5 Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior

Lecture 11 Uncertainty

EDUCATION AND EXAMINATION COMMITTEE SOCIETY OF ACTUARIES RISK AND INSURANCE. Copyright 2005 by the Society of Actuaries

4. Continuous Random Variables, the Pareto and Normal Distributions

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

Choice Under Uncertainty

Chapter 5. Random variables

Probability Distribution for Discrete Random Variables

CHAPTER 6 RISK AND RISK AVERSION

Lecture 8. Confidence intervals and the central limit theorem

Random Variables. Chapter 2. Random Variables 1

Applied Economics For Managers Recitation 5 Tuesday July 6th 2004

Financial Services [Applications]

The Binomial Probability Distribution

An Introduction to Utility Theory

CA200 Quantitative Analysis for Business Decisions. File name: CA200_Section_04A_StatisticsIntroduction

Review of Random Variables

2. Filling Data Gaps, Data validation & Descriptive Statistics

MA 1125 Lecture 14 - Expected Values. Friday, February 28, Objectives: Introduce expected values.

STA 256: Statistics and Probability I

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov).

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

An Introduction to Basic Statistics and Probability

Lecture 15. Ranking Payoff Distributions: Stochastic Dominance. First-Order Stochastic Dominance: higher distribution

2. Information Economics

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Mathematical Expectation

Math 370/408, Spring 2008 Prof. A.J. Hildebrand. Actuarial Exam Practice Problem Set 5 Solutions

Math 370, Actuarial Problemsolving Spring 2008 A.J. Hildebrand. Practice Test, 1/28/2008 (with solutions)

Choice Under Uncertainty Insurance Diversification & Risk Sharing AIG. Uncertainty

Uncertainty, Asymmetric Information, and Market Failure

2INTERNET CHAPTER TWO

6 Hedging Using Futures

Business Statistics 41000: Probability 1

Pr(X = x) = f(x) = λe λx

Elementary Statistics and Inference. Elementary Statistics and Inference. 17 Expected Value and Standard Error. 22S:025 or 7P:025.

Midterm exam, Health economics, Spring 2007 Answer key

BNG 202 Biomechanics Lab. Descriptive statistics and probability distributions I

MBA 611 STATISTICS AND QUANTITATIVE METHODS

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

WHY THE LONG TERM REDUCES THE RISK OF INVESTING IN SHARES. A D Wilkie, United Kingdom. Summary and Conclusions

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk

Lecture 13: Risk Aversion and Expected Utility

Math 370/408, Spring 2008 Prof. A.J. Hildebrand. Actuarial Exam Practice Problem Set 2 Solutions

We hope you will find this sample a useful supplement to your existing educational materials, and we look forward to receiving your comments.

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University

Joint Exam 1/P Sample Exam 1

MAS108 Probability I

Summary of Formulas and Concepts. Descriptive Statistics (Ch. 1-4)

AMS 5 CHANCE VARIABILITY

Betting with the Kelly Criterion

Health Economics. University of Linz & Demand and supply of health insurance. Gerald J. Pruckner. Lecture Notes, Summer Term 2010

Math 431 An Introduction to Probability. Final Exam Solutions

Mean = (sum of the values / the number of the value) if probabilities are equal

Economics 1011a: Intermediate Microeconomics

Important Probability Distributions OPRE 6301

Problem Set 1 Solutions

Section 5 Part 2. Probability Distributions for Discrete Random Variables

Random variables P(X = 3) = P(X = 3) = 1 8, P(X = 1) = P(X = 1) = 3 8.

DECISION MAKING UNDER UNCERTAINTY:

Means, standard deviations and. and standard errors

Probability Models of Credit Risk

Of Burning Houses and Exploding Coke Bottles

Premium calculation. summer semester 2013/2014. Technical University of Ostrava Faculty of Economics department of Finance

Notes on Continuous Random Variables

Probability and Statistics Vocabulary List (Definitions for Middle School Teachers)

ECON1003: Analysis of Economic Data Fall 2003 Answers to Quiz #2 11:40a.m. 12:25p.m. (45 minutes) Tuesday, October 28, 2003

You Are What You Bet: Eliciting Risk Attitudes from Horse Races

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Economics 1011a: Intermediate Microeconomics

Lecture 3: Continuous distributions, expected value & mean, variance, the normal distribution

Definition: Suppose that two random variables, either continuous or discrete, X and Y have joint density

Lecture 6: Discrete & Continuous Probability and Random Variables

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Probability and Expected Value

MBA Math for Executive MBA Program

An Overview of Asset Pricing Models

Transcription:

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 7 C2. Health Insurance: Risk Pooling Health insurance works by pooling individuals together to reduce the variability of potential losses (or risk) faced by an insurance company. The example assumes knowledge of expected value and standard deviation for a random variable and the average of random variables. A review of these concepts is given at the end for completeness but is not essential. C2.1 Losses for an Individual Individuals face great variability in their health losses. A year of good health costs little. A year of bad health can be very costly. The possible outcomes for a given individual are summarized using the expected value and the standard deviation. Example Suppose a heart attack may occur with probability 0.01 and would cost $50,000 to treat. Let X denote health costs due to a heart attack. Then X = $50,000 with probability 0.01 = $0 with probability 0.99. Mean for an Individual The expected value of any random variable is the sum of its possible values weighted by the probability of each value: μ = E[X] = Pr[X=$50,000] 50,000 + Pr[X=$0] $0 = 0.01 $50,000 + 0.99 $0 = $500. Standard Deviation for an Individual To compute the standard deviation we first calculate the variance: σ 2 = V[X] = Pr[X=$50,000] ($50,000 - $500) 2 + Pr[X=$0] ($0 - $500) 2 = 0.01 ($49,500) 2 + 0.99 ($500) 2 = 24,502,500 + 247,500 in units of ($) 2 = 24,750,000. Then the standard deviation (which unlike the variance is measured in the same units as X) σ = S.D.[X] = (V[X]) 1/2 = (24,750,000) 1/2 = $4,975 Here the standard deviation is relatively large, being about ten times the expected value.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 8 C2.2 Losses for Health Insurance Company Health insurance pools a number of individuals together. The insurance company s costs are determined by the average level of annual claims per policy. The insurance company is concerned with both the expected value of average annual claims and the variability (the standard deviation) of average annual claims. Insurance works because the variability in the average annual claims for 100 policies, say, is much less than the variability in the annual claim on any single policy. Insurance companies are willing to sell insurance as pooling many people together reduces the variability of their possible losses. And individuals are willing to buy insurance as with insurance the variability of their potential losses is greatly reduced. A fundamental result is that the variability, as measured by the standard deviation, faced by insurance companies decreases by the square root of the number of people insured. A second fundamental result is that, for a large insurance pool, average annual claims will be normally distributed. If every person in the pool faces the same distribution of possible outcomes, this normal distribution has mean equal to the expected value of claims for any individual and standard deviation equal to the individual standard deviation divided by the square root of the number of people insured. Example We consider 10,000 people for each of whom a heart attack may occur with probability 0.01 and would cost $50,000 to treat. As shown earlier μ = E[X] = $500 and σ = E[X] = $4,975. Let X denote average loss due to heart attack for sample of size 10,000. Mean of the Average The expected value of X is E[ X ] = μ = $500 Standard deviation of the Average The standard deviation of X is S.D.[ X] = σ / n 1/2 = $4,975 / 10,000 1/2 = $49.75 Distribution of the Average The sample average X is normally distributed with mean $500 and standard deviation $49.75. From standard normal tables it can be shown that for 10,000 insured we can be 67% sure that average claims will be within $49.75 of $500 95% sure that average claims will be within 2 $49.75 = $99.50 of $500 If instead only 100 are insured we can only be 67% sure that average claims will be within $497.50 of $500.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 9 Normal Distribution The normal distribution is a bell-shaped curve with formula f(x) = (1/2пσ 2 ) 1/2 exp(-(x-μ) 2 /2σ 2 ) where μ = E[x] is the mean of the random variable x and σ = Sqrt(V[x]) is the standard deviation of the random variable x The normal distribution has the following bell-shape. Distribution of normally distributed random variable x with mean μ and standard deviation σ μ -2σ μ-σ μ μ+σ μ +2σ μ x The total area under the curve equals one. The area under the curve between any two points gives the probability of being between those points. The probability of being within one standard deviation of the mean is approximately 0.67. The probability of being within two standard deviations of the mean is approximately 0.95.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 10 Within one standard deviation of mean when average losses have mean $500 and st. deviation $50 Probability of being in this area is approx. 0.67 400 450 500 550 600 x Within two standard deviations of mean when average losses have mean $500 and st. deviation $50 Probability of being in this area is approx. 0.95 400 450 500 550 600 x

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 11 C2.3 More on mean and standard deviation of the Average The following uses simple numbers to demonstrate that the average X has mean E[ X] = μ and standard deviation S.D.[ X] = σ / n 1/2. i.e. average keeps the same mean but reduces the standard deviation. Suppose X = 1 with probability 0.5 = 3 with probability 0.5. Then μ = E[X] = 0.5 1 + 0.5 3 = 2. σ 2 = V[X] = 0.5 (1-2) 2 + 0.5 (3-2) 2 = 0.5 1 + 0.5 1 = 1 σ = S.D.[X] = (V[X]) 1/2 = (1) 1/2 = 1. Suppose we average two such people. i.e. X 1 is the outcome for the first person and takes values 1 or 3 each with probability 0.5, and X 2 is the outcome for the second person and takes values 1 or 3 each with probability 0.5. Then X=(X 1 + X 2 )/2. According to our theory X has mean μ =1 and standard deviation = σ / n 1/2 = 1 / 2 1/2 = 0.5 1/2 = 0.707. Let s check that from first principles. There are four possible outcomes for X 1 and X 2. These are X 1 = 1 and X 2 = 1 with probability 0.5 0.5 = 0.25, in which case X =(1 + 1)/2 = 1 These are X 1 = 1 and X 2 = 3 with probability 0.5 0.5 = 0.25, in which case X =(1 + 3)/2 = 2 These are X 1 = 3 and X 2 = 1 with probability 0.5 0.5 = 0.25, in which case X =(3 + 1)/2 = 2 These are X 1 = 3 and X 2 = 3 with probability 0.5 0.5 = 0.25, in which case X =(3 + 3)/2 = 3 Thus the random variable X =(X 1 + X 2 )/2 takes possible values X = 1 with probability 0.25 X = 2 with probability 0.5 X = 3 with probability 0.25 so the mean of X is E[ X ] = 0.25 1 + 0.5 2 + 0.25 3 = 2 And the variance of X is Var[ X ] = 0.25 (1-2) 2 + 0.5 (2-2) 2 + 0.25 (3-2) 2 = 0.25 1 + 0.25 1 = 0.5 And the standard deviation of X is S.D.[ X ] = (V[ X ]) 1/2 = (0.5) 1/2 = 0.707. So the original variance is divided by n = 2 and the standard deviation by the square root of this, as claimed by the general formula.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 12 C2.4 Addendum: Statistics Review of the Mean and Variance of the Sample Mean Random Variable X denotes the random variable of interest (for simplicity a discrete random variable). X takes several different values with different probabilities. A typical value is denoted x. Pr[X = x] denotes the probability that X takes value x. X = loss due to heart attack. X = $50,000 with probability 0.01 = $0 with probability 0.99. Mean of X The mean is a measure of where the range of values that X may take is centered. (Other alternative measures are the median and the mode). The mean is the weighted average of the different values X takes, where the weights are the probability of each particular value occurring. μ = E[X] = Σ x Pr[X=x] x where Σ x denotes the sum over the different possible values x E[X] = Pr[X=$50,000] 50,000 + Pr[X=$0] $0 = 0.01 $50,000 + 0.99 $0 = $500. Variance and standard deviation of X These are measures of the variation of the range of values that X may take. (Other alternative measures are the actual range and the inter-quartile range). The variance is the weighted average of the squared difference between each value X takes and the mean value of X, where the weights are the probability of each particular value occurring. The standard deviation is the square root of the variance. It is measured in the same units as X, whereas due to squaring the variance is measured in units of X-squared. σ 2 = V[X] = E[(X- E[X]) 2 ] = Σ x Pr[X=x] (x-e[x]) 2 where Σ x denotes the sum over x σ = S.D.[X] = (V[X]) 1/2 V[X] = Pr[X=$50,000] ($50,000 - $500) 2 + Pr[X=$0] ($0 - $500) 2 = 0.01 ($49,500) 2 + 0.99 ($500) 2 = 24,502,500 + 247,500 in units of ($) 2 = 24,750,000. S.D.[X] = (V[X]) 1/2 = (24,750,000) 1/2 = $4,975. In this example standard deviation is very large relative to the mean so there is large relative risk.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 13 C2.4 Addendum: Statistics Review (continued) Sample A random sample of size n draws randomly n different outcomes of the random variable X. The sample values are denoted x 1, x 2,, x n. Common statistics to explain the sample are the sample mean and sample standard deviation. Sample Mean X denotes the sample mean. It is the average of the n sample values denoted x 1, x 2,, x n. X= (X 1 + X 2 + + X n )/n The sample mean is a random variable, since different samples will give different values for X. Like other random variables, X has mean, variance and distribution. Mean of X E[ X] = E[ (X 1 + X 2 + + X n ) / n ] = (E[X 1 ] + E[X 2 ] + + E[X n ] ) / n = (μ + μ + + μ ) / n = μ Variance and standard deviation of X V[ X ] = E[( X - E[ X ]) 2 ] = E[( ( (X 1 + X 2 + + X n ) / n) - μ) 2 ] = E[( ( (X 1 -μ) + (X 2 -μ) + + (X n - μ) ) / n) 2 ] = E[ (X 1 -μ) 2 + (X 2 -μ) 2 + + (X n - μ) 2 ] / n 2 = (σ 2 + σ 2 + + σ 2 ) / n 2 = σ 2 / n S.D.[ X] = σ / n 1/2 Thus averaging reduces the standard deviation. Divide by the square root of n. Suppose X = average loss due to heart attack for sample of size 10,000. E[ X] = μ = $500. S.D.[ X] = σ / n 1/2 = $4,975 / 10,000 1/2 = $49.75 Distribution of X By the central limit theorem, even if each x 1, x 2,, x n is not normally distributed, as the sample size n increases the sample average X is normally distributed. From standard normal tables we know that a random variable lies within one standard deviation of its mean with probability 0.67 and within two standard deviations of its mean with probability 0.95. This implies that Pr{μ - σ / n 1/2 < X < μ - σ / n 1/2 } = 0.67 Pr{μ - 2 x σ / n 1/2 < X < μ - σ / n 1/2 } = 0.95.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 14 C3. Health Insurance: Risk Aversion Definition: A person is risk-averse if they prefer a certain outcome to a gamble that has expected outcome of the same value. E.g. prefer $100 for sure to a 50/50 coin toss with outcome either $0 or $200. A person is risk-prefer if instead the gamble is preferred to the certain outcome. A person is risk-neutral if indifferent between the gamble and the certain outcome. People can be risk-averse, risk-neutral or risk-prefer but it is felt that most people are riskaverse and we consider only this case. Why buy insurance if the premium is higher than the actuarially fair premium? Because of risk-aversion by the consumer, explained as follows. C3.1 Model for Insurance Let x denote a random outcome, such as health expenses or income net of health expenses. Let x = annual income (in thousands of dollars) and suppose x = 50 with probability 0.5 or x = 150 with probability 0.5 Then the expected income is E[x] = 0.5 50 + 0.5 150 = 100. We wish to compare the happiness of a certain 100 to the happiness of the uncertain outcome of either 50 with probability 0.5 or 150 with probability 0.5. Let U(x) denote the utility or happiness that comes from particular values of x. For concreteness assume the following Income x Utility U(x) Marginal Utility (per 50 change in x) 0 0 0 50 100 100 100 170 70 150 200 30 Utility is increasing in income, as expected, with first derivative U (x) > 0. This increase in utility declines as income increases, e.g. the first 50 leads to an increase in utility of 100; the next 50 leads to an increase of 70. This implies that the second derivative U (x) < 0. The expected utility is E[U(x)] = 0.5 U(50) + 0.5 U(150) = 0.5 100 + 0.5 200 = 150. For this consumer this is less than the utility of 100 with certainty, since U(100) = 170 > 150. The consumer will therefore consider purchase of insurance against the uncertain outcome, provided the premium is not too high.

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 15 C3.2 Risk Averse: Utility of Certain Income > Expected Utility of Uncertain Income Utility U(x) U(150)=200 U(E[x])=U(100)=170 E[U(x)] =.5*U(50)+.5*U(150) U(50)=100 50 E[x]=100 150 X = outcome Pr=0.5 Pr=0.5 The utility of the expected outcome is 170. This exceeds the expected utility, the average of the utility of 50 and the utility of 150. Hence the certain outcome is preferred, as 170 > 150 and the person is risk-averse. More generally it can be shown that for a risk-averse consumer the marginal utility of wealth decreases as wealth increases, giving a utility function that is concave to the origin. It is clear from the diagram that the benefit of insurance against the uncertain outcome is larger for more risk-averse individuals, i.e. greater curvature U (x) of the utility function. more exposure to risk, i.e. greater Var[x], the variance of x. A standard result, used for example in Roger Feldman (1981), A New Estimate of the Welfare Loss of Excess Health Insurance, American Economic Review, Vol.81, pp.297-301, is that the benefit of risk reduction equals R Var[x]/2, where R= -U (x)/ U (x) is called the coefficient of relative risk aversion. This benefit is larger for greater risk-aversion (R) and greater exposure to risk (Var[x]).