A primer on probability theory in financial modeling

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A primer on probability theory in financial modeling"

Transcription

1 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling Sergio M. Focardi Tel: +33 1/ The Intertek Group 94, rue de Javel F Paris Tutorial The objective of finance theory is to predict the future evolution of financial quantities, such as the price of a single asset or broad market movements. Uncertainty as to the future evolution of prices is a fundamental tenet of modern finance theory. The paradigm of choice for modeling uncertainty in finance is the probability theory. This tutorial presents the formal probabilistic concepts behind today s financial modeling. 1 Introduction The theory of finance is a mathematical theory that describes the time evolution of financial quantities. To describe the time evolution of quantities, finance theory uses a mathematical formalism similar to that of the physical sciences. The results - either actual or possible - of empirical observations can be predicted through a sequence of purely logical operations. Given today s low-cost high-performance computers, predictions are generally obtained by running mathematical models on computers. As in the physical sciences, the objective of finance theory is to make predictions. Predictions might concern phenomena such as the future value of a single stock or currency or future market movements in a given geographical block. But there are important differences between finance theory and theory in the physical sciences: Finance theory does not describe laws of nature but a complex human artifact, the financial markets. Physical sciences that describe a complex system, such as weather, are typically supported by basic physical laws; finance theory describes a complex system for which there is (presently) no description in terms of elementary laws or elementary components. 1

2 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 2 Finance theory lacks a mathematical theory that allows to compute the evolution of a system (in this case of a financial system) starting from initial conditions. In the absence of this, finance theory consists of two separate components: 1) a set of relationships that constrain the entire market from the time evolution of fundamental determinants and 2) a set of assumptions on the time evolution of fundamental determinants. The determination of the appropriate assumptions as regards the evolution of fundamental determinants is more the domain of financial econometrics than of finance theory. The above considerations are central to an understanding of financial modeling. In fact, derivatives asset pricing models are (generally) algorithms that compute the price evolution of derivatives starting from assumptions on the evolution of the price of the underlying. The choice of models must take into account the ability of the model to describe not only the underlying (such as the term structure of interest rates) but also the functioning of markets. Let s now briefly present the development of finance theory. 1.1 Competitive markets under uncertainty During the 1950s, the economists Kenneth Arrow and Georges Debreu proposed extending to financial markets the notions of microeconomics and, consequently, the analysis of competitive markets. A classical reference on microeconomics is Varian (1992). Let s review the fundamental points. Following classical notions, a competitive exchange market (without production) is a tool that allows N agents to exchange a given good. The fundamental notion of competitive exchange is that of supply and demand. It is assumed that each agent is characterized by a demand function which prescribes the quantity of a good that the agent is willing to buy at a given price. The aggregation of demand produces the market demand function, i.e., the total amount of the good that agents will purchase at any given price. There is a parallel function of supply which associates to each price the quantity of the good offered for sale. The supply function derives from the aggregation of the individual supply function of agents. The classical analysis makes the assumption of perfect competitive markets. Perfect competitive markets have a number of characteristics. First, there are no costs or constraints associated with the exchange of goods; price and quantity are the only determinants of exchange. Each agent is individually too small to influence the market; prices are determined by the collective action of agents. Given the market price, each agent will buy or sell exactly the quantity prescribed by its demand or supply function, under the constraint of their financial endowment which prescribes the maximum total amount that each can purchase. If there is not one but several goods to choose from, agents must select from a

3 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 3 panel of goods. It is assumed that agents are able to order their preferences, i.e., that they are able to decide if they are either indifferent to or have preferences for different panels of goods. It is possible to demonstrate that, under assumptions of continuity in the ordering of preferences, preferences themselves can be expressed through a utility function. A utility function is a numerical function defined over each panel of goods, i.e., it is a function that assigns a numerical utility index to each panel of goods. Preferences are expressed by higher values of the utility function. Therefore, in a competitive exchange market there are N agents, each characterized by a financial endowment and by a utility function. A panel of goods chosen by each agent corresponds to each set of prices of the goods. The aggregation of choices leads to the aggregate market demand for each good. The key point of microeconomic theory is to determine if and how the market reaches its equilibrium point which is defined as the point at which the aggregate demand is exactly equal to the aggregate offer. This might seem a banal problem, but it involves one of the key results of this century mathematics: Brouwer s fixed point theorem. The fixed-point theorem can be stated in many ways. In its simplest formulation, it states that a continuous function that maps an interval onto itself has a fixed point, i.e., a point where the argument of the function has the same value as the function itself. Each level of offer corresponds to a price which induces demand. The equilibrium problem is to find the fixed point of this supply and demand function. The above notion of competitive markets does not consider uncertainty. To extend classical microeconomic analysis to include uncertainty, Kenneth Arrow reasoned as follows. At every instant, agents exchange not only goods but also contracts that will be executed in the future. The future result of such contracts is uncertain. A stock, for example, is a contract that gives its holder the right to receive future dividends and the eventual final liquidation price, but the amount of these payments at time of execution is uncertain. Suppose, for simplicity, that there is only one period and thus two dates: the initial instant T 0 and the final instant T 1. At instant T 0, agents exchange contracts that give them the right to receive an uncertain amount of goods at instant T 1. Abstracting from physical goods, agents exchange at instant T 0 contracts that give them the right to receive an uncertain payment at instant T 1. Following Arrow, suppose that the economy might be, at instant T 1, in one of k possible different states. We can now observe that each couple good-state can be considered a different good with an associated market supply and demand and a

4 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 4 market price. Each contract will produce a different outcome in function of the state realized at instant T 1. Every contract is therefore a contingent claim, i.e., each contract gives the right to a payment or a delivery of goods contingent on the realized state. If we now assume that agents have utility functions defined on quantities for each state, we have placed the analysis of markets under uncertainty in the framework of the analysis of deterministic markets. If we now drop the single-period assumption, we can apply the same reasoning to a model that assumes that agents perform market operations (i.e., they exchange contracts or trade) at each of the M future dates. Utility functions must be defined for each good, for each state, and for each instant. The number of trading instants can be either finite or infinite. The above description of financial markets is highly idealized and serves only as a framework for models and application software. It is, however, the conceptual basis for understanding modern finance theory. In a number of applications, it is used directly. For example, optimization software used in investment management is based on the above theoretical model. Let s now explore how the previous framework translates into a mathematical probabilistic description of financial markets. It would seem natural to define the states of the economy as instantaneous states at each trading date. From the point of view of the mathematical description of the economy, however, it is more convenient to stipulate that states are an entire possible history of the economy over a given time period. The following paragraphs will describe how a probability structure can be imposed on this set of states. 2 The mathematical representation of uncertainty Today s finance theory is based on the hypothesis that uncertainty about future prices is ineliminable; a fundamental tenet is that no entity can attain a deterministic description of the evolution of the economy with the exception of the evolution of riskfree assets. A typical practical example of a riskfree asset is USA government debt. The inability to build purely deterministic models of the economy calls for the mathematical representation of uncertainty. Probability theory is the mathematical description of uncertainty that presently enjoys the broadest diffusion; it is the paradigm of choice for mainstream finance theory. But it is by no means the only one. Competing mathematical paradigms for uncertainty include, for example, fuzzy measures. Though probability as a mathematical axiomatic theory is well known, its interpretation is still the object of debate. There are three basic interpretations of

5 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 5 probability: Probability as intensity of belief, J.M. Keynes, 1921 Probability as relative frequency, R. von Mises, 1928 Probability as an axiomatic system, A. Kolmogorov, Developed primarily by the Russian mathematician Kolmogorov, the axiomatic theory of probability eliminated the logical ambiguities that plagued probabilistic reasoning prior to his work. Application of the axiomatic theory is, however, a matter of interpretation. In finance theory, probability might have two different meanings: 1) as a descriptive concept and 2) as a determinant of the agent decision-making process. As a descriptive concept, probability is used in the sense of relative frequency, similar to its use in the physical sciences. In this sense, the probability of an event is assumed to be approximately equal to the relative frequency of its manifestation in a large number of experiments. This interpretation is unsatisfactory in finance theory for a number of reasons: The approximate equality between relative frequency and theoretical probability cannot be made precise. More fundamentally, in a truly probabilistic environment there can be no definite link between probability and observation. Unless we rule out the possibility of low-probability events, any observation is compatible with any statement of probability. An additional complication comes from the fact that financial time series have only one realization. Every estimate is made on a single time-evolving series. If stationarity (or a well-defined time process) is not assumed, it is not possible to make statistical estimates. If by probability we refer to the agent decision-making process, there are problems here too. It is assumed that agents are able to associate probability numbers to future events and that decisions are made on the basis of these evaluations. Different assumptions can be made. The strictest assumption is that all agents share both the same probabilistic evaluations and the model assumptions. Billingsley (1986) and Chow and Teicher (1988) offer excellent presentations of probability theory. 2.1 Outcomes and events The axiomatic theory of probability is based on three fundamental concepts: 1) outcomes, 2) events and 3) measure. The outcomes are the set of all possible results of an experiment or an observation. The set of all possible outcomes is often written as the set Ω. For instance, in the dice game, a possible outcome is

6 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 6 a pair of numbers, one for each face, such as or 3 + 2; the space Ω is the set of all 36 possible outcomes. Events are sets of outcomes. Continuing with the example of the dice game, a possible event is the set of all outcomes such that the sum of the numbers is 10. Probabilities are defined on events, not on outcomes. To render definitions consistent, events must be a class F of subsets of Ω with the following properties: 1. F is not empty; 2. If A F then A F; (A is the complement of A made of all those elements of Ω that do not belong to A); 3. If A i F for i = 1, 2,... then A i F. Every such class is called a σ-algebra. Any class for which property 3 is valid only for a finite number of sets is called an algebra. Any set that belongs to a class G is said to be measurable with respect to G. Consider a class G of subsets of Ω and consider the smallest σ-algebra that contains G, defined as the intersection of all the sigma-algebras that contain G. That σ-algebra is indicated as σ(g) and is said to be the σ-algebra generated by G. A particularly important space in probability is the Euclidean space. Consider first the real axis R, i.e., the Euclidean space R 1 in one dimension. Consider the set formed by all intervals open to the left and all unions and intersections of intervals open to the left. The σ-algebra generated by this set is represented with the letter B; sets that belong to B are called Borel sets. Now consider, more in general, the n-dimensional Euclidean space R n, for n 1. (ennuples of real numbers). Consider the class of all generalized rectangles open to the left and their unions and intersections. The σ-algebra generated by this class is indicated as R n ; sets that belong to R n are called n-dimensional Borel sets. The above construction is not the only possible one. The R n, for any value of n, are also generated by open or closed sets. As we will see, the R n are fundamental to defining random variables. They define a class of subsets of Euclidean spaces on which it is reasonable to impose a probability structure: the class of every subset would be too big while the class of, say, generalized rectangles would be too small. The R n are an adequately rich class. 2.2 Probability Intuitively, probability is a set function that associates to every event a number between zero and one. Probability is formally defined by a triple (Ω, F, P ), which is called a probability space, where Ω is the set of all possible outcomes, F is

7 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 7 the event σ-algebra and P is a probability measure defined as follows. A probability measure P is a set function from F to R (the set of real numbers) that satisfies three conditions: 1. 0 P (A) 1 for every A F; 2. P ( ) = 0 and P (Ω) = 1; 3. P ( A i ) = P (A i ) for every finite or numerable sequence of disjoint events A i such that A i F. F does not have to be a σ-algebra. The definition of a probability space can be limited to algebras of events. It is however possible to demonstrate that a probability defined over an algebra of events H can be extended in a unique way to the σ-algebra generated by H. Two events are said to be independent if: P (A B) = P (A)P (B). (1) The probability of event A given event B, written as P(A/B), is defined as follows: P (A B) P (A/B) =. (2) P (B) It is immediate to deduct from simple properties of set theory and from the disjoint additivity of probability that: P (A B) = P (A) + P (B) P (A B) P (A) + P (B). (3) P (A) = 1 P (B). (4) Discrete probabilities are a special instance of probabilities. Defined over a finite or denumerable set of outcomes, discrete probabilities are non-zero over each outcome. The probability of an event is the sum of the probabilities of its outcomes. In the finite case, discrete probabilities are the usual combinatorial probabilities. 2.3 Measure A measure is a set function defined over an algebra of sets, denumerably additive, and such that it takes value 0 on the empty set but can otherwise assume any positive value including, conventionally, an infinite value. A probability is thus a measure of total mass 1, i.e., it takes value 1 on the set Ω. Measure can be formally defined as a function M(A) from an algebra F to R (the set of real numbers) that satisfies the following three properties:

8 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling M(A) for every A F; 2. M( ) = 0; 3. M( A i ) = M(A i ) for every finite or denumerable sequence A i of disjoints events such that A i F. If M is a measure defined over a σ-algebra F, the triple (Ω, F, M) is called a measure space (this term is not used if F is an algebra). The couple (Ω, F) is a measurable space if F is a σ-algebra. Measures in general, and not only probabilities, can be uniquely extended from an algebra to the generated σ-algebra. 2.4 Integrals The notion of measure allows to define a concept of integral that generalizes the usual concept of the Riemann integral. For each measure M, the integral is a number that is associated to every integrable function f. It is defined in two steps. First suppose that f is non-negative and consider a finite decomposition of the space Ω, that is to say a finite class of disjoint subsets A i of Ω whose union is Ω: (A i Ω; A i A j = for i j; A i = Ω). Then consider the sum: inf(f(ω) : ω Ai )M(A i ). The integral fdm is defined as the superior, if it exists, of all these sums over all possible decompositions of Ω. Second, given a generic function f not necessarily non-negative, consider its decomposition in its positive and negative parts. The integral of f is defined as the difference, if difference exists, between the integrals of its positive and negative parts with the sign changed. This definition of integral generalizes the usual definition of the Riemann integral. The integral can be defined not only on Ω but on any measurable set G. Given an algebra F, suppose that G and M are two measures and suppose that a function f exists such that G(A) = fdm, for A F. In this case G is said A to have density f with respect to M. 2.5 Measures and integrals over Euclidean spaces A number of integrals of interest for probability theory are defined over the real axis R and over the n-dimensional spaces R n (real numbers and ennuples of real numbers respectively). The definition of these integrals requires the definition of various measures with respect to which integrals are defined. Without formally defining each measure, let s recall that the following integrals are defined over Euclidean spaces:

9 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 9 the classical Riemann integral, defined with respect to the length of intervals or areas of rectangles; the Lebesgue integral, defined with respect to the measure space (Ω, R n, λ n ), where λ n is the Lebesgue measure, a measure that generalizes the concept of area; the Stieltjes integral, defined with respect to measures that are in turn defined over finite rectangles. 3 Random variables Probability is a set function defined over a space of events; random variables transfer probability from the original space Ω into the space of real numbers. Given a probability space (Ω, F, P ), a random variable X is a function X(ω) defined over the set Ω that takes values in the set R of real numbers and subject to the condition: the set (ω : X(ω) x) belongs to the σ-algebra F for every real number x. In other words, the inverse image of any interval (, x] is an event. It can be easily demonstrated that the inverse image of any union and product of intervals is also an event. A real-valued set function defined over Ω is called measurable with respect to a σ-algebra F if the inverse image of any Borel set belongs to F. A random variable which is measurable with respect to a σ-algebra cannot discriminate between events that are not in that σ-algebra. A random variable X is said to generate G if G is the smallest σ-algebra in which it is measurable. Given a probability space (Ω, F, P ) and a random variable X, the expected value of X is its integral with respect to the measure P : E[X] = XdP, where Ω integration is extended to entire space Ω. 3.1 Distributions and distribution functions Given a probability space (Ω, F, P ) and a random variable X, consider a set A of real numbers that belongs to R 1, i.e., A is a Borel set on the real line. Recall that a random variable is a real-valued measurable function defined over the set of outcomes. Therefore, the inverse image of A, X 1 (A) belongs to F and has a well-defined probability P (X 1 (A)). The measure P thus induces another measure on the real axis called distribution or distribution law of the random variable X given by: p(a) = P (X 1 (A)). It is easy to see that this measure is a probability measure. A random variable therefore transfers on the set of real numbers the probability originally defined over the space Ω.

10 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 10 The function F defined by: F (x) = p(, x) = P (X x) is the distribution function of the random variable X. Suppose that there is a function f such that P (A) = fdx for every set A that A belongs to R 1 and with respect to the Lebesgue measure. The function f is called a probability density function and the probability P is said to have density f. For every interval (a, b), the property F (a) F (b) = fdx where integration is extended to the interval (a, b) holds. 3.2 Random vectors The next step is to consider not only one but a set of random variables referred to as random vectors. Random vectors are formed by ennuples of random variables. Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P ). A random variable is a measurable function from Ω to R 1 ; a random vector is a measurable function from Ω to R n. We can therefore write a random vector as a function: f(ω) = (f 1 (ω), f 2 (ω),..., f n (ω)). Measurability is defined with respect to the Borel σ-algebras R n, with n = 1 for random variables. It can be demonstrated that the function f is measurable F if and only if each component function f i is measurable F. Conceptually, the key issue is to define joint probabilities, i.e., the probabilities that the n variables are in a given set. For example, consider the joint probability that the inflation rate is in a given interval and the growth rate in another given interval. Consider the Borel σ-algebra R n on the real n-dimensional space R n. It can be easily demonstrated that a random vector formed by n random variables X i, i = 1, 2,..., n induces a probability distribution over (R n, R n ). In fact, the set (ω Ω : (X 1 (ω), X 2 (ω),..., X n (ω)) H : H R n ) belongs to F, i.e., the inverse image of every set of the σ-algebra R n belongs to the σ-algebra F. It is therefore immediate to induce over every set H that belongs to R n a probability measure, the joint probability of the n random variables X i. In general, however, knowledge of the distributions and of distribution functions of each random variable is not sufficient to determine the joint probability distribution function. Two random variables X, Y are said to be independent if P (X A, Y B) = P (X A)P (Y B), A and B belong to R. This definition generalizes in obvious ways to any number of variables and therefore to the components of a random vector. It is easy to show that, if the variable components of a random vector are independent, the joint probability distribution is the product of distributions.

11 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 11 4 Stochastic processes Given a probability space (Ω, F, P ), a stochastic process is a set of random variables that are measurable with respect to F, indexed with an index t [0, T ] interpreted as time. A stochastic process is therefore an indexed random variable X t (ω). When it is necessary to emphasize the dependence of the random variable value from both time and the element ω, a stochastic process is explicitly written as a function of two variables: X = X(t, ω). Given ω, the function X(t, ) is a function of time that is called the path of the stochastic process. The variable X might be a single random variable or a multidimensional random vector. A stochastic process is therefore a function X(t, ω) from the product space [0, T ] Ω into the n-dimensional real space R n. Because to each ω corresponds a time path of the process - in general formed by a set of functions X i (t, ) - it is possible to identify the space Ω with a subset of the real functions defined over an interval [0, T ]. Let s now discuss how to represent a stochastic process X(t, ω) and the conditions of identity of two stochastic processes. As a stochastic process is a function of two variables, one can define equality as pointwise identity for each couple t, ω. However, as processes are defined over probability spaces, pointwise identity is seldom used; it is more fruitful to define equality modulo sets of measure zero or equality with respect to probability distributions. In general, two random variables X, Y will be considered equal if the equality X(ω) = Y (ω) holds for every ω with the exception of a set of probability zero. In this case, it is said that the equality holds almost always (a.a.). A rather general (but not complete) representation is given by the finite dimensional probability distributions. Given any set of indices (t 1,..., t m ), consider the distributions µ t1,...,t m (H) = P ((X t1,..., X tm ) H) where H R m. These probability measures are, for any choice of the t i, the finite-dimensional joint probabilities of the process. They determine many, but not all, properties of a stochastic process. For example, the finite dimensional distributions of a Brownian motion do not determine if the process paths are continuous or not. In general, one can define the three concepts of equality between stochastic processes described below: Two stochastic processes are equal if they have the same finite-dimensional distributions. This is the weakest concept of equality. The process X(t, ω) is said to be a modification of the process Y (t, ω) if the following equation holds: X(t, ω) = Y (t, ω) a.a., t. (5)

12 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 12 In other words, according to this definition, two stochastic processes are equal if, given any value of t, the random variables X(, ω), Y (, ω) are equal except over a set of probability zero. For each t, the set of measure zero over which the two processes are different might be different. Two processes are said to be indistinguishable if the following relationship holds: X(t, ) = Y (t, ) t, a.a.. (6) That is to say, two processes are indistinguishable if their paths coincide except (eventually) over a set of measure zero. It is quite obvious that property 3 implies property 2 which implies, in turn, property 1. Implications do not hold in the opposite sense. Two processes having the same finite distributions might have completely different paths. However if one assumes that paths are continuous functions of time, properties 2 and 3 become equivalent. 4.1 Assets, prices, dividends and economic states We are now in the position to summarize the probabilistic representation of financial markets. From a financial point of view, an asset is a contract which gives the right to receive a stream of future payments, generically indicated as dividends. In the case of a stock, the stream of payments will include the stock dividends and the proceedings of the eventual final liquidation of the firm. A bond is a contract that gives the right to receive coupons and the repayment of the principal. We will suppose that all payments are made at the trading dates and that no transactions take place between trading dates. Let s assume that all securities are traded (i.e., exchanged on the market) at either discrete fixed dates, variable dates or continuously. At each trading date there is a market price for each security. Each security is therefore modeled with two time series, a series of market prices and a series of dividends. As both series are subject to uncertainty, dividends and prices are time-dependent random variables, i.e., they are stochastic processes. The time dependence of random variables in this probabilistic setting is a delicate question and will be examined shortly. Following Kenneth Arrow and using a framework now standard, the economy and the financial markets in a situation of uncertainty are described with the following basic concepts: It is assumed that the economy might be in one of the states of a probability space (Ω, F, P ). Therefore, the economy is represented by a probability space (Ω, F, P ).

13 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 13 Every security is described by two stochastic processes formed by two timedependent random variables S t and d t, that represent prices and dividends of the same security. Therefore, every security is represented by two stochastic processes S t and d t. This representation is completely general and is not linked to the assumption that the space of states is finite. 4.2 Information structures Let s now turn our attention to the question of time. The previous paragraphs considered a space formed by states in an abstract sense. We have now to introduce an appropriate representation of time as well as rules that describe the evolution of information, i.e. information propagation, over time. The concepts of information and information propagation are fundamental in economics and finance theory. Information, in this context, is a concept different from both the intuitive notion of information and from that of information theory in which information is a quantitative measure related to the a priori probability of messages. In economics, information means the (progressive) revelation of the set of events to which the current state of the economy belongs. The concept of information in finance is a bit technical, but sheds light on the probabilistic structure of finance theory. (Readers not interested in the formal development of finance theory might skip this section.) The point is the following. Securities are represented by stochastic processes, i.e., time-dependent random variables. But the probabilistic states on which these random variables are defined represent entire histories of the economy. To embed time into the probabilistic structure of states in a coherent way calls for information structures and filtrations. Recall that it is assumed that the economy is in one of many possible states and that there is uncertainty on the state that has been realized. Consider a time period of the economy. At the beginning of the period, there is complete uncertainty on the state of the economy, i.e., there is complete uncertainty on what path the economy will take. Different events have different probabilities, but there is no certainty. As time passes, uncertainty is reduced as the number of states to which the economy can belong is progressively reduced. Revelation of information means the progressive reduction of the number of possible states; at the end of the period, the realized state is fully revealed. This progressive reduction of the set of possible states is formally expressed in the concepts of information structure and filtration. Let s start with information structures. Information structures apply only to discrete probabilities defined

14 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 14 over a discrete set of states. At the initial instant T 0, there is complete uncertainty on the state of the economy; the actual state is known only to belong to the largest possible event, i.e., the entire space Ω. At the following instant T 1, the states are separated into a partition, a partition being a denumerable class of disjoint sets whose union is the space itself. The actual state belongs to one of the sets of the partitions. The revelation of information consists in ruling out all other sets but one. In the discrete case, and only in the discrete case, partitions are determined by the value of all the random variables at time T 1. For all the states of each partition, and only for these, random variables assume the same values. Suppose, to exemplify, that only two securities exist in the economy and that each can assume only two possible prices and pay only two possible dividends. At every moment there are sixteen possible price-dividend combinations. We can thus see that at the moment T 1 all the states are partitioned into sixteen sets, each containing only one state. Each partition includes all the states that have a given set of prices and dividends at the moment T 1. The same reasoning can be applied to each instant. The evolution of information can thus be represented by a tree structure in which every path represents a state and every point a partition. Obviously the tree structure does not have to develop in a symmetrical way as in the above example. The tree might have a very generic structure of branches. 4.3 Filtration The concept of information structure based on partitions supplies a rather intuitive representation of the propagation of information through a tree of progressively finer partitions. However, this structure is not sufficient to describe the propagation of information in a general probabilistic context. In fact, the set of possible events is much richer than the set of partitions. It is therefore necessary to identify not only partitions, but also a structure of events. The structure of events used to define the propagation of information is called a filtration. In the discrete case, however, the two concepts, information structure and filtration, are equivalent. The concept of filtration is based on identifying all events that are known at any given instant. It is assumed that it is possible to associate to each trading moment t a σ-algebra of events F t contained in F and formed by all events that are known prior to or at time t. It is assumed that events are never forgotten, i.e., that F t F s if t < s. In this way, an ordering of time is created. This ordering is formed by an increasing sequence of σ-algebras, each associated to the time at which all its events are known. This sequence is called a filtration. Indicated as {F t }, a filtration is therefore the increasing sequence of all σ-algebras F t, each associated to the respective instant t. In the finite case, it is possible to create a mutual correspondence between fil-

15 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 15 trations and information structures. In fact, given an information structure, it is possible to associate to each partition the algebra generated by the same partition. Observe that a tree information structure is formed by partitions that create increasing refinement, that is to say that, by going from one instant to the next, every set of the partition is decomposed. One can then conclude that the algebras generated by an information structure form a filtration. On the other hand, given a filtration {F t }, it is possible to associate a partition to each F t. In fact, given any element ω, consider any other element ν such that, for each set of F t, both either belong to or are outside it. It is easy to see that classes of equivalence are thus formed, that these create a partition, and that the algebra generated by each such partition is exactly the F t that has generated the partition. A stochastic process is said to be adapted to the filtration {F t } if the variable X t is measurable with respect to the σ-algebra F t. It is assumed that the price and dividend processes S t and d t of every security are adapted to F t. This means that, for each t, no measurement of any price or dividend variable can identify events not included in the respective algebra. Every random variable is a partial image of the set of states seen from a given point of view and at a given moment. The concepts of filtration and of processes adapted to a filtration are fundamental. They ensure that information is revealed without anticipation. Consider the economy and associate at every instant a partition and an algebra generated by the partition. Every random variable defined at that moment assumes a value constant on each set of the partition. The knowledge of the realized values of the random variables does not allow identifying sets of events finer than partitions. One might well ask: Why introduce the complex structure of σ-algebras as opposed to simply defining random variables? The point is that, from a logical point of view, the primitive concept is that of states and events. The evolution of time has to be defined on the primitive structure - it cannot simply be imposed on random variables. In practice, filtrations become an important concept when dealing with conditional probabilities in a continuous environment. As the probability that a continuous random variable assumes a specific value is zero, the definition of conditional probabilities requires the machinery of filtration. 4.4 Conditional probability and conditional expectation Conditional probabilities and conditional averages are fundamental in the stochastic description of financial markets. For instance, one is often interested in the probability distribution of the price of a security at some date given its price at an earlier date. The widely used regression models are an example of conditional expectation models.

16 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 16 The conditional probability of event A given event B was defined in the above paragraphs on probability as P (A/B) = P (A B). This simple definition cannot P (B) be used in the context of continuous random variables because the conditioning event (i.e., one variable assuming a given value) has probability zero. To avoid this problem, one conditions on σ-algebras and not on single zero-probability events. In general, as each instant is characterized by a σ-algebra F t, the conditioning elements are the F t. The general definition of conditional expectation is the following. Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P ) and a σ-algebra G contained in F and suppose that X is an integrable random variable on (Ω, F, P ). We define the conditional expectation of X with respect to G, written as E[X/G], a random variable measurable with respect to G such that E[X/G]dP = XdP for every set G G. In G G other words, the conditional expectation is a random variable whose average on every event that belongs to G is equal to the average of X over those same events but it is measurable G whilst X is not. It is possible to demonstrate that such variables exist and are unique up to a set of measure zero. Econometric models usually condition a random variable given another variable. In the previous framework, conditioning one random variable X with respect to another random variable Y means conditioning X given σ(y ), i.e., given the σ- algebra generated by Y. Thus E[X/Y ] means E[X/σ(Y )]. One can define conditional probabilities starting from the concept of conditional expectations. Consider a probability space (Ω, F, P ), a sub-σ-algebra G of F and two sets A, B F. If I A, I B are the indicator functions of the sets A, B (the indicator function of a set assumes value 1 on the set, 0 elsewhere), we can define conditional probabilities of the event A, respectively, given G or given the event B as: P (A/G) = E[I A /G], P (A/B) = E[I A /I B ] (7) Using these definitions, it is possible to demonstrate that given two random variables X and Y with joint density f(x, y), the conditional density of X given Y is f(x, y) f(x/y) = f Y (y). (8) In the discrete case, the conditional expectation is a random variable (i.e., a realvalued function defined over Ω) that takes a constant value over the sets of the finite partition associated to F t. Its value for each element of Ω is defined by the classical concept of conditional probability. It is simply the average over a partition assuming the classical conditional probabilities. An important econometric concept related to conditional expectations is that of a martingale. Given a probability space (Ω, F, P ) and a filtration {F i },

17 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 17 a sequence of random variables X i measurable F i is called a martingale if the following condition holds: E[X i+1 /F i ] = X i. (9) A martingale translates the idea of a fair game as the expected value of the variable at the next period is the present value of the same value. 5 In summary This tutorial has reviewed the following key concepts used in the probabilistic description of financial markets: Probability and probability spaces: Probability is a set function defined over a class of events where events are sets of possible outcomes of an experiment. A probability space is a triple formed by a set of outcomes, a σ-algebra of events and a probability measure. Random variables and random vectors: A random variable is a real-valued function defined over the set of outcomes such that the inverse image of any interval is an event. n-dimensional random vectors are functions from the set of outcomes into the n-dimensional Euclidean space with the property that the inverse image of n-dimensional generalized rectangles is an event. Stochastic processes: Stochastic processes are time dependent random variables. Information structures and filtrations: An information structure is a class of partitions of the σ-algebra of events associated to each instant of time that become progressively finer with the evolution of time. A filtration is an increasing class of σ-algebras associated to each instant of time. The stochastic representation of financial markets: The states of the economy, intended as full histories of the economy, are represented as a probability space. The revelation of information with time is represented by information structures or filtrations. Prices and other financial quantities are represented by adapted stochastic processes. Conditional probabilities and conditional expectations: Conditioning means the change in probabilities due to the acquisition of some information. It is possible to condition with respect to an event if the event has non zero probability. In general terms, conditioning is conditioning with respect to a filtration or an information structure. Martingales: A martingale is a stochastic process such that the conditional expected value is always equal to its present value. It embodies the idea of a fair game, where today s wealth is the best forecast of future wealth.

18 A primer on probability theory in financial modeling 18 References [1] Billingsley, Patrick, Probability and Measure, 2nd edition, Wiley and Sons, New York, NY, [2] Chow, Yuan Shih and Henry Teicher, Probability Theory, Springer-Verlag, New York, NY, [3] Varian, Hal, Microeconomic Theory, W.W Norton & Company, 1992.

Elements of probability theory

Elements of probability theory 2 Elements of probability theory Probability theory provides mathematical models for random phenomena, that is, phenomena which under repeated observations yield di erent outcomes that cannot be predicted

More information

E3: PROBABILITY AND STATISTICS lecture notes

E3: PROBABILITY AND STATISTICS lecture notes E3: PROBABILITY AND STATISTICS lecture notes 2 Contents 1 PROBABILITY THEORY 7 1.1 Experiments and random events............................ 7 1.2 Certain event. Impossible event............................

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES Contents 1. Random variables and measurable functions 2. Cumulative distribution functions 3. Discrete

More information

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces Dan Collins The textbook defines a subspace of a vector space in Chapter 4, but it avoids ever discussing the notion of a quotient space. This is understandable

More information

How To Find Out How To Calculate A Premeasure On A Set Of Two-Dimensional Algebra

How To Find Out How To Calculate A Premeasure On A Set Of Two-Dimensional Algebra 54 CHAPTER 5 Product Measures Given two measure spaces, we may construct a natural measure on their Cartesian product; the prototype is the construction of Lebesgue measure on R 2 as the product of Lebesgue

More information

Financial Mathematics and Simulation MATH 6740 1 Spring 2011 Homework 2

Financial Mathematics and Simulation MATH 6740 1 Spring 2011 Homework 2 Financial Mathematics and Simulation MATH 6740 1 Spring 2011 Homework 2 Due Date: Friday, March 11 at 5:00 PM This homework has 170 points plus 20 bonus points available but, as always, homeworks are graded

More information

So let us begin our quest to find the holy grail of real analysis.

So let us begin our quest to find the holy grail of real analysis. 1 Section 5.2 The Complete Ordered Field: Purpose of Section We present an axiomatic description of the real numbers as a complete ordered field. The axioms which describe the arithmetic of the real numbers

More information

Chapter ML:IV. IV. Statistical Learning. Probability Basics Bayes Classification Maximum a-posteriori Hypotheses

Chapter ML:IV. IV. Statistical Learning. Probability Basics Bayes Classification Maximum a-posteriori Hypotheses Chapter ML:IV IV. Statistical Learning Probability Basics Bayes Classification Maximum a-posteriori Hypotheses ML:IV-1 Statistical Learning STEIN 2005-2015 Area Overview Mathematics Statistics...... Stochastics

More information

Math/Stats 425 Introduction to Probability. 1. Uncertainty and the axioms of probability

Math/Stats 425 Introduction to Probability. 1. Uncertainty and the axioms of probability Math/Stats 425 Introduction to Probability 1. Uncertainty and the axioms of probability Processes in the real world are random if outcomes cannot be predicted with certainty. Example: coin tossing, stock

More information

Probability Theory. Florian Herzog. A random variable is neither random nor variable. Gian-Carlo Rota, M.I.T..

Probability Theory. Florian Herzog. A random variable is neither random nor variable. Gian-Carlo Rota, M.I.T.. Probability Theory A random variable is neither random nor variable. Gian-Carlo Rota, M.I.T.. Florian Herzog 2013 Probability space Probability space A probability space W is a unique triple W = {Ω, F,

More information

Mechanics 1: Vectors

Mechanics 1: Vectors Mechanics 1: Vectors roadly speaking, mechanical systems will be described by a combination of scalar and vector quantities. scalar is just a (real) number. For example, mass or weight is characterized

More information

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition

Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Mathematics for Econometrics, Fourth Edition Phoebus J. Dhrymes 1 July 2012 1 c Phoebus J. Dhrymes, 2012. Preliminary material; not to be cited or disseminated without the author s permission. 2 Contents

More information

LEARNING OBJECTIVES FOR THIS CHAPTER

LEARNING OBJECTIVES FOR THIS CHAPTER CHAPTER 2 American mathematician Paul Halmos (1916 2006), who in 1942 published the first modern linear algebra book. The title of Halmos s book was the same as the title of this chapter. Finite-Dimensional

More information

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm Lecture notes prepared for MATH 326, Spring 997 Department of Mathematics and Statistics University at Albany William F Hammond Table of Contents Introduction

More information

MASTER OF SCIENCE FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ABAC SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTION UNIVERSITY OF THAILAND

MASTER OF SCIENCE FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ABAC SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTION UNIVERSITY OF THAILAND MASTER OF SCIENCE FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ABAC SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTION UNIVERSITY OF THAILAND ECO 5001 Mathematics for Finance and Economics The uses of mathematical argument in extending the range,

More information

8 Divisibility and prime numbers

8 Divisibility and prime numbers 8 Divisibility and prime numbers 8.1 Divisibility In this short section we extend the concept of a multiple from the natural numbers to the integers. We also summarize several other terms that express

More information

Lecture L3 - Vectors, Matrices and Coordinate Transformations

Lecture L3 - Vectors, Matrices and Coordinate Transformations S. Widnall 16.07 Dynamics Fall 2009 Lecture notes based on J. Peraire Version 2.0 Lecture L3 - Vectors, Matrices and Coordinate Transformations By using vectors and defining appropriate operations between

More information

Lecture Note 1 Set and Probability Theory. MIT 14.30 Spring 2006 Herman Bennett

Lecture Note 1 Set and Probability Theory. MIT 14.30 Spring 2006 Herman Bennett Lecture Note 1 Set and Probability Theory MIT 14.30 Spring 2006 Herman Bennett 1 Set Theory 1.1 Definitions and Theorems 1. Experiment: any action or process whose outcome is subject to uncertainty. 2.

More information

INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS

INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS STEVEN P. LALLEY AND ANDREW NOBEL Abstract. It is shown that there are no consistent decision rules for the hypothesis testing problem

More information

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces D. R. Wilkins Academic Year 1996-7 9 Vector Spaces A vector space over some field K is an algebraic structure consisting of a set V on which are

More information

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS 4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney Semester 2, 2015 B. Goldys and M. Rutkowski (USydney) Slides 4: Single-Period Market

More information

1 The Brownian bridge construction

1 The Brownian bridge construction The Brownian bridge construction The Brownian bridge construction is a way to build a Brownian motion path by successively adding finer scale detail. This construction leads to a relatively easy proof

More information

Introduction to Probability

Introduction to Probability Introduction to Probability EE 179, Lecture 15, Handout #24 Probability theory gives a mathematical characterization for experiments with random outcomes. coin toss life of lightbulb binary data sequence

More information

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015 ECON 459 Game Theory Lecture Notes Auctions Luca Anderlini Spring 2015 These notes have been used before. If you can still spot any errors or have any suggestions for improvement, please let me know. 1

More information

6.3 Conditional Probability and Independence

6.3 Conditional Probability and Independence 222 CHAPTER 6. PROBABILITY 6.3 Conditional Probability and Independence Conditional Probability Two cubical dice each have a triangle painted on one side, a circle painted on two sides and a square painted

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

Basics of Dimensional Modeling

Basics of Dimensional Modeling Basics of Dimensional Modeling Data warehouse and OLAP tools are based on a dimensional data model. A dimensional model is based on dimensions, facts, cubes, and schemas such as star and snowflake. Dimensional

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors

Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors Fall 2005 Unified Lecture # 4 Vectors These notes were written by J. Peraire as a review of vectors for Dynamics 16.07. They have been adapted for Unified Engineering by R. Radovitzky. References [1] Feynmann,

More information

Regular Languages and Finite Automata

Regular Languages and Finite Automata Regular Languages and Finite Automata 1 Introduction Hing Leung Department of Computer Science New Mexico State University Sep 16, 2010 In 1943, McCulloch and Pitts [4] published a pioneering work on a

More information

Fairfield Public Schools

Fairfield Public Schools Mathematics Fairfield Public Schools AP Statistics AP Statistics BOE Approved 04/08/2014 1 AP STATISTICS Critical Areas of Focus AP Statistics is a rigorous course that offers advanced students an opportunity

More information

Solving Systems of Linear Equations

Solving Systems of Linear Equations LECTURE 5 Solving Systems of Linear Equations Recall that we introduced the notion of matrices as a way of standardizing the expression of systems of linear equations In today s lecture I shall show how

More information

The Graphical Method: An Example

The Graphical Method: An Example The Graphical Method: An Example Consider the following linear program: Maximize 4x 1 +3x 2 Subject to: 2x 1 +3x 2 6 (1) 3x 1 +2x 2 3 (2) 2x 2 5 (3) 2x 1 +x 2 4 (4) x 1, x 2 0, where, for ease of reference,

More information

Chapter 3. Cartesian Products and Relations. 3.1 Cartesian Products

Chapter 3. Cartesian Products and Relations. 3.1 Cartesian Products Chapter 3 Cartesian Products and Relations The material in this chapter is the first real encounter with abstraction. Relations are very general thing they are a special type of subset. After introducing

More information

Vector and Matrix Norms

Vector and Matrix Norms Chapter 1 Vector and Matrix Norms 11 Vector Spaces Let F be a field (such as the real numbers, R, or complex numbers, C) with elements called scalars A Vector Space, V, over the field F is a non-empty

More information

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach Texas Christian University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Modeling Interest Rate Parity: A System Dynamics Approach John T. Harvey Department of Economics Texas Christian University Working

More information

Basic Probability Concepts

Basic Probability Concepts page 1 Chapter 1 Basic Probability Concepts 1.1 Sample and Event Spaces 1.1.1 Sample Space A probabilistic (or statistical) experiment has the following characteristics: (a) the set of all possible outcomes

More information

People have thought about, and defined, probability in different ways. important to note the consequences of the definition:

People have thought about, and defined, probability in different ways. important to note the consequences of the definition: PROBABILITY AND LIKELIHOOD, A BRIEF INTRODUCTION IN SUPPORT OF A COURSE ON MOLECULAR EVOLUTION (BIOL 3046) Probability The subject of PROBABILITY is a branch of mathematics dedicated to building models

More information

IEOR 6711: Stochastic Models I Fall 2012, Professor Whitt, Tuesday, September 11 Normal Approximations and the Central Limit Theorem

IEOR 6711: Stochastic Models I Fall 2012, Professor Whitt, Tuesday, September 11 Normal Approximations and the Central Limit Theorem IEOR 6711: Stochastic Models I Fall 2012, Professor Whitt, Tuesday, September 11 Normal Approximations and the Central Limit Theorem Time on my hands: Coin tosses. Problem Formulation: Suppose that I have

More information

INCIDENCE-BETWEENNESS GEOMETRY

INCIDENCE-BETWEENNESS GEOMETRY INCIDENCE-BETWEENNESS GEOMETRY MATH 410, CSUSM. SPRING 2008. PROFESSOR AITKEN This document covers the geometry that can be developed with just the axioms related to incidence and betweenness. The full

More information

Answer Key for California State Standards: Algebra I

Answer Key for California State Standards: Algebra I Algebra I: Symbolic reasoning and calculations with symbols are central in algebra. Through the study of algebra, a student develops an understanding of the symbolic language of mathematics and the sciences.

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 9-1 Explain what relationships are shown by (a) the consumption schedule, (b) the saving schedule, (c) the investment-demand curve, and (d) the investment schedule.

More information

Chapter 4 One Dimensional Kinematics

Chapter 4 One Dimensional Kinematics Chapter 4 One Dimensional Kinematics 41 Introduction 1 4 Position, Time Interval, Displacement 41 Position 4 Time Interval 43 Displacement 43 Velocity 3 431 Average Velocity 3 433 Instantaneous Velocity

More information

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Review of Fundamental Mathematics Review of Fundamental Mathematics As explained in the Preface and in Chapter 1 of your textbook, managerial economics applies microeconomic theory to business decision making. The decision-making tools

More information

On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference

On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference MICROECONOMICS LECTURE SUPPLEMENTS Hajime Miyazaki File Name: lexico95.usc/lexico99.dok DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS OHIO STATE UNIVERSITY Fall 993/994/995 Miyazaki.@osu.edu On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference

More information

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r). Chapter 4 Put-Call Parity 1 Bull and Bear Financial analysts use words such as bull and bear to describe the trend in stock markets. Generally speaking, a bull market is characterized by rising prices.

More information

Markov random fields and Gibbs measures

Markov random fields and Gibbs measures Chapter Markov random fields and Gibbs measures 1. Conditional independence Suppose X i is a random element of (X i, B i ), for i = 1, 2, 3, with all X i defined on the same probability space (.F, P).

More information

CHAPTER 2 Estimating Probabilities

CHAPTER 2 Estimating Probabilities CHAPTER 2 Estimating Probabilities Machine Learning Copyright c 2016. Tom M. Mitchell. All rights reserved. *DRAFT OF January 24, 2016* *PLEASE DO NOT DISTRIBUTE WITHOUT AUTHOR S PERMISSION* This is a

More information

Probability and Statistics Vocabulary List (Definitions for Middle School Teachers)

Probability and Statistics Vocabulary List (Definitions for Middle School Teachers) Probability and Statistics Vocabulary List (Definitions for Middle School Teachers) B Bar graph a diagram representing the frequency distribution for nominal or discrete data. It consists of a sequence

More information

Removing Partial Inconsistency in Valuation- Based Systems*

Removing Partial Inconsistency in Valuation- Based Systems* Removing Partial Inconsistency in Valuation- Based Systems* Luis M. de Campos and Serafín Moral Departamento de Ciencias de la Computación e I.A., Universidad de Granada, 18071 Granada, Spain This paper

More information

Time Value of Money. 2014 Level I Quantitative Methods. IFT Notes for the CFA exam

Time Value of Money. 2014 Level I Quantitative Methods. IFT Notes for the CFA exam Time Value of Money 2014 Level I Quantitative Methods IFT Notes for the CFA exam Contents 1. Introduction...2 2. Interest Rates: Interpretation...2 3. The Future Value of a Single Cash Flow...4 4. The

More information

Representing Reversible Cellular Automata with Reversible Block Cellular Automata

Representing Reversible Cellular Automata with Reversible Block Cellular Automata Discrete Mathematics and Theoretical Computer Science Proceedings AA (DM-CCG), 2001, 145 154 Representing Reversible Cellular Automata with Reversible Block Cellular Automata Jérôme Durand-Lose Laboratoire

More information

COMBINATORIAL PROPERTIES OF THE HIGMAN-SIMS GRAPH. 1. Introduction

COMBINATORIAL PROPERTIES OF THE HIGMAN-SIMS GRAPH. 1. Introduction COMBINATORIAL PROPERTIES OF THE HIGMAN-SIMS GRAPH ZACHARY ABEL 1. Introduction In this survey we discuss properties of the Higman-Sims graph, which has 100 vertices, 1100 edges, and is 22 regular. In fact

More information

7: The CRR Market Model

7: The CRR Market Model Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney MATH3075/3975 Financial Mathematics Semester 2, 2015 Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein

More information

Decision Making under Uncertainty

Decision Making under Uncertainty 6.825 Techniques in Artificial Intelligence Decision Making under Uncertainty How to make one decision in the face of uncertainty Lecture 19 1 In the next two lectures, we ll look at the question of how

More information

Chapter 4. SDP - difficulties. 4.1 Curse of dimensionality

Chapter 4. SDP - difficulties. 4.1 Curse of dimensionality Chapter 4 SDP - difficulties So far we have discussed simple problems. Not necessarily in a conceptual framework, but surely in a computational. It makes little sense to discuss SDP, or DP for that matter,

More information

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price Abstract: Chi Gao 12/15/2013 I. Black-Scholes Equation is derived using two methods: (1) risk-neutral measure; (2) - hedge. II.

More information

Binomial lattice model for stock prices

Binomial lattice model for stock prices Copyright c 2007 by Karl Sigman Binomial lattice model for stock prices Here we model the price of a stock in discrete time by a Markov chain of the recursive form S n+ S n Y n+, n 0, where the {Y i }

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Probability and statistics; Rehearsal for pattern recognition

Probability and statistics; Rehearsal for pattern recognition Probability and statistics; Rehearsal for pattern recognition Václav Hlaváč Czech Technical University in Prague Faculty of Electrical Engineering, Department of Cybernetics Center for Machine Perception

More information

Chapter 4. Probability and Probability Distributions

Chapter 4. Probability and Probability Distributions Chapter 4. robability and robability Distributions Importance of Knowing robability To know whether a sample is not identical to the population from which it was selected, it is necessary to assess the

More information

Extension of measure

Extension of measure 1 Extension of measure Sayan Mukherjee Dynkin s π λ theorem We will soon need to define probability measures on infinite and possible uncountable sets, like the power set of the naturals. This is hard.

More information

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1. MATH10212 Linear Algebra Textbook: D. Poole, Linear Algebra: A Modern Introduction. Thompson, 2006. ISBN 0-534-40596-7. Systems of Linear Equations Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column

More information

One Period Binomial Model

One Period Binomial Model FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 One Period Binomial Model These notes consider the one period binomial model to exactly price an option. We will consider three different methods of pricing

More information

14.30 Introduction to Statistical Methods in Economics Spring 2009

14.30 Introduction to Statistical Methods in Economics Spring 2009 MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.30 Introduction to tatistical Methods in Economics pring 2009 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.

More information

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1 Chapter 3 Continuity In this chapter we begin by defining the fundamental notion of continuity for real valued functions of a single real variable. When trying to decide whether a given function is or

More information

Lecture 17 : Equivalence and Order Relations DRAFT

Lecture 17 : Equivalence and Order Relations DRAFT CS/Math 240: Introduction to Discrete Mathematics 3/31/2011 Lecture 17 : Equivalence and Order Relations Instructor: Dieter van Melkebeek Scribe: Dalibor Zelený DRAFT Last lecture we introduced the notion

More information

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization 2.1. Introduction Suppose that an economic relationship can be described by a real-valued

More information

A Short Introduction to Credit Default Swaps

A Short Introduction to Credit Default Swaps A Short Introduction to Credit Default Swaps by Dr. Michail Anthropelos Spring 2010 1. Introduction The credit default swap (CDS) is the most common and widely used member of a large family of securities

More information

Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones

Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 9 (2002), No. 1, 301 307 Separation Properties for Locally Convex Cones Walter Roth Department of Mathematics, Universiti Brunei Darussalam, Gadong BE1410, Brunei Darussalam

More information

Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming

Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming Practical Guide to the Simplex Method of Linear Programming Marcel Oliver Revised: April, 0 The basic steps of the simplex algorithm Step : Write the linear programming problem in standard form Linear

More information

Lecture 13 - Basic Number Theory.

Lecture 13 - Basic Number Theory. Lecture 13 - Basic Number Theory. Boaz Barak March 22, 2010 Divisibility and primes Unless mentioned otherwise throughout this lecture all numbers are non-negative integers. We say that A divides B, denoted

More information

Covariance and Correlation

Covariance and Correlation Covariance and Correlation ( c Robert J. Serfling Not for reproduction or distribution) We have seen how to summarize a data-based relative frequency distribution by measures of location and spread, such

More information

15.062 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review

15.062 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review .6 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review The purpose of this document is to give a brief review of selected linear algebra concepts that will be useful for the course and to develop

More information

THE DIMENSION OF A VECTOR SPACE

THE DIMENSION OF A VECTOR SPACE THE DIMENSION OF A VECTOR SPACE KEITH CONRAD This handout is a supplementary discussion leading up to the definition of dimension and some of its basic properties. Let V be a vector space over a field

More information

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: QUOTIENT SPACES

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: QUOTIENT SPACES FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: QUOTIENT SPACES CHRISTOPHER HEIL 1. Cosets and the Quotient Space Any vector space is an abelian group under the operation of vector addition. So, if you are have studied

More information

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function 171 10 The Cobb-Douglas Production Function This chapter describes in detail the most famous of all production functions used to represent production processes both in and out of agriculture. First used

More information

3. INNER PRODUCT SPACES

3. INNER PRODUCT SPACES . INNER PRODUCT SPACES.. Definition So far we have studied abstract vector spaces. These are a generalisation of the geometric spaces R and R. But these have more structure than just that of a vector space.

More information

TOPOLOGY: THE JOURNEY INTO SEPARATION AXIOMS

TOPOLOGY: THE JOURNEY INTO SEPARATION AXIOMS TOPOLOGY: THE JOURNEY INTO SEPARATION AXIOMS VIPUL NAIK Abstract. In this journey, we are going to explore the so called separation axioms in greater detail. We shall try to understand how these axioms

More information

6 Scalar, Stochastic, Discrete Dynamic Systems

6 Scalar, Stochastic, Discrete Dynamic Systems 47 6 Scalar, Stochastic, Discrete Dynamic Systems Consider modeling a population of sand-hill cranes in year n by the first-order, deterministic recurrence equation y(n + 1) = Ry(n) where R = 1 + r = 1

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Cartesian Products and Relations

Cartesian Products and Relations Cartesian Products and Relations Definition (Cartesian product) If A and B are sets, the Cartesian product of A and B is the set A B = {(a, b) :(a A) and (b B)}. The following points are worth special

More information

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002). Description of the model. This is a special case of a Mirrlees model.

More information

How To Find The Sample Space Of A Random Experiment In R (Programming)

How To Find The Sample Space Of A Random Experiment In R (Programming) Probability 4.1 Sample Spaces For a random experiment E, the set of all possible outcomes of E is called the sample space and is denoted by the letter S. For the coin-toss experiment, S would be the results

More information

Discrete Mathematics and Probability Theory Fall 2009 Satish Rao, David Tse Note 10

Discrete Mathematics and Probability Theory Fall 2009 Satish Rao, David Tse Note 10 CS 70 Discrete Mathematics and Probability Theory Fall 2009 Satish Rao, David Tse Note 10 Introduction to Discrete Probability Probability theory has its origins in gambling analyzing card games, dice,

More information

Regular Expressions and Automata using Haskell

Regular Expressions and Automata using Haskell Regular Expressions and Automata using Haskell Simon Thompson Computing Laboratory University of Kent at Canterbury January 2000 Contents 1 Introduction 2 2 Regular Expressions 2 3 Matching regular expressions

More information

The sample space for a pair of die rolls is the set. The sample space for a random number between 0 and 1 is the interval [0, 1].

The sample space for a pair of die rolls is the set. The sample space for a random number between 0 and 1 is the interval [0, 1]. Probability Theory Probability Spaces and Events Consider a random experiment with several possible outcomes. For example, we might roll a pair of dice, flip a coin three times, or choose a random real

More information

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Capital Structure. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Capital Structure Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Debt and Equity There are two main types of financing: debt and equity. Consider a two-period world with dates 0 and 1. At

More information

Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans

Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans Market Commentary July 2015 PUBLIC PENSION PLANS HAVE a single objective to provide income for a secure retirement for their members. Once the

More information

Numeraire-invariant option pricing

Numeraire-invariant option pricing Numeraire-invariant option pricing Farshid Jamshidian NIB Capital Bank N.V. FELAB, University of Twente Nov-04 Numeraire-invariant option pricing p.1/20 A conceptual definition of an option An Option can

More information

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position Chapter 27: Taxation 27.1: Introduction We consider the effect of taxation on some good on the market for that good. We ask the questions: who pays the tax? what effect does it have on the equilibrium

More information

Reading 13 : Finite State Automata and Regular Expressions

Reading 13 : Finite State Automata and Regular Expressions CS/Math 24: Introduction to Discrete Mathematics Fall 25 Reading 3 : Finite State Automata and Regular Expressions Instructors: Beck Hasti, Gautam Prakriya In this reading we study a mathematical model

More information

Mechanics 1: Conservation of Energy and Momentum

Mechanics 1: Conservation of Energy and Momentum Mechanics : Conservation of Energy and Momentum If a certain quantity associated with a system does not change in time. We say that it is conserved, and the system possesses a conservation law. Conservation

More information

Linear Programming. March 14, 2014

Linear Programming. March 14, 2014 Linear Programming March 1, 01 Parts of this introduction to linear programming were adapted from Chapter 9 of Introduction to Algorithms, Second Edition, by Cormen, Leiserson, Rivest and Stein [1]. 1

More information

Real Roots of Univariate Polynomials with Real Coefficients

Real Roots of Univariate Polynomials with Real Coefficients Real Roots of Univariate Polynomials with Real Coefficients mostly written by Christina Hewitt March 22, 2012 1 Introduction Polynomial equations are used throughout mathematics. When solving polynomials

More information

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Econometrics Simple Linear Regression Burcu Eke UC3M Linear equations with one variable Recall what a linear equation is: y = b 0 + b 1 x is a linear equation with one variable, or equivalently, a straight

More information

Lecture 16 : Relations and Functions DRAFT

Lecture 16 : Relations and Functions DRAFT CS/Math 240: Introduction to Discrete Mathematics 3/29/2011 Lecture 16 : Relations and Functions Instructor: Dieter van Melkebeek Scribe: Dalibor Zelený DRAFT In Lecture 3, we described a correspondence

More information

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics

Metric Spaces. Chapter 7. 7.1. Metrics Chapter 7 Metric Spaces A metric space is a set X that has a notion of the distance d(x, y) between every pair of points x, y X. The purpose of this chapter is to introduce metric spaces and give some

More information

WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT?

WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT? WHAT ARE MATHEMATICAL PROOFS AND WHY THEY ARE IMPORTANT? introduction Many students seem to have trouble with the notion of a mathematical proof. People that come to a course like Math 216, who certainly

More information

Introduction to time series analysis

Introduction to time series analysis Introduction to time series analysis Margherita Gerolimetto November 3, 2010 1 What is a time series? A time series is a collection of observations ordered following a parameter that for us is time. Examples

More information