Endogenous Aggregate Beliefs: Equity Trading under Heterogeneity in Ambiguity Aversion

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Endogenous Aggregate Beliefs: Equity Trading under Heterogeneity in Ambiguity Aversion"

Transcription

1 Endogenous Aggregate Beliefs: Equity Trading under Heterogeneity in Ambiguity Aversion Irasema Alonso Jose Mauricio Prado Preliminary incomplete March 5, 2009 Abstract We examine the potential importance of heterogeneity in consumers ambiguity aversion for asset pricing, portfolio allocation, the wealth distribution. Ambiguity aversion, which is a way of formalizing preferences that are consistent with the Ellsberg paradox, features first-order effects on utility even in an economy with a small amount of romness. Thus ambiguity aversion contrasts the stard model, where risk aversion leads to second-order effects on utility, it has sharp implications for portfolio dem for equilibrium asset returns. In the context of a simple, Mehra-Prescottstyle endowment economy, we consider two types of agents whose ambiguity aversions differ: some agents display ambiguity aversion while others do not. We show that the equilibrium belief of the ambiguity-averse consumer will evolve endogenously nontrivially over time as a result of the equilibrium interaction. Moreover, we show that stard agents will dominate in the pricing of the assets in the long run (but much less so in the short run), unless there is a recurrent influx of new ambiguity-averse consumers. Also, given the heterogeneity, the ambiguity-averse agents become (almost) non-participants in the stock market over time; thus we obtain endogenous limited participation. This occurs as the ambiguity-averse consumers will see their relative wealth decline over time. Introduction What is the role for heterogeneity in consumer tastes for understing macroeconomic phenomena? Indeed, individual decision-making is a key building block in micro-founded macroeconomic theorizing, though most of this theorizing relies on the representative-agent construct. Thus, the analysis relies on the premise either that, for the question at h, an aggregation theorem holds, or that any quantitative departure from it does not significantly irasema.alonso@yale.edu Postal address: Yale University. jm.prado@imtlucca.it Postal address: IMT Lucca Institute for Advanced Studies, Piazza San Ponziano, 6, 5500 Lucca, Italy. Tel.: Fax.:

2 alter the conclusions of the analysis. Some abstractions from heterogeneity are surely easy to motivate, but others, we think, do deserve scrutiny, especially when the taste heterogeneity impacts importantly on the decisions macroeconomists build their models around. In this paper the focus is on understing asset prices wealth inequality. If different portfolios deliver different return characteristics, if these characteristics have sufficiently different average returns, then in scenarios when different consumers have different portfolios of assets a presumption that appears very much in line with data one might well obtain sharp implications both for asset prices for the long-run distribution of wealth. In this paper, we consider one possible determinant of different portfolio preferences, modeled through taste differences, we look at its long-run effects on asset prices wealth inequality: differences in the degree of ambiguity aversion. Ambiguity aversion is a way of thinking more generally about belief formation, it has been used recently for understing how risky assets might also be perceived as ambiguous thus comm lower prices higher returns. Heterogeneity in ambiguity aversion is therefore a way of thinking about the possibility that consumers, despite their being rational, might have different beliefs about asset returns, thus leading to differences in their chosen portfolios. Since the ambiguity aversion we consider here is firmly based on axioms (see below), we are thus studying how differences in tastes might help us underst aggregates. Other approaches to understing the observed heterogeneity in consumers portfolios include (i) heterogeneous needs for risk sharing, (ii) heterogeneity in consumers costs of accessing different financial instruments, (iii) heterogeneity in information. Surely heterogeneity in risk sharing needs transactions costs are important; the present analysis should be viewed as a complement in that regard. As for differences in information across people, they are likely very important too, they are closely related to the object of study here, since they too lead to differences in consumer beliefs. However, they tend to be quite difficult to study in general equilibrium, since once needs to provide an analysis of why the price system does not reveal all privately held information. When it comes to the long-run effects on wealth inequality, in particular, we know of no study of it that is based on market interaction with partially revealing prices. Thus, one can perhaps view our current work as an alternative, more tractable, way of dealing with belief differences in general equilibrium. Moreover, unlike in most representative-agent studies of ambiguity aversion, where equilibrium beliefs end up being determined very directly based on the modeler s choice of the typical parameter for ambiguity aversion ( a below), in a model with heterogeneity in ambiguity aversion beliefs evolve endogenously entirely nontrivially as a function of the market interaction, as we show in this paper. Ambiguity aversion is a way of formalizing preferences that are consistent with the Ellsberg paradox, it captures a form of violation of Savage s axioms of subjective probability. Instead, consumers behave as if a range of probability distributions are possible as if they are averse toward the unknown. With the typical parameterized representation of ambiguity aversion, consumers have minmax preferences, thus maximizing utility based on the worst possible belief within some given set of feasible beliefs. Thus, in an economy with a small amount of romness, there are first-order effects on utility if there is ambiguity about this romness. Thus, ambiguity aversion is in contrast to the stard model, where risk aversion leads to second-order effects on utility. Previous papers, such as our own work, have analyzed the role of ambiguity aversion for 2

3 asset prices, but in representative-agent settings. Alonso Prado (2008) looks at asset pricing in a simple Mehra-Prescott-style endowment economy. There, we demonstrate how larger equity premia can be obtained by assuming ambiguity aversion, along with low riskfree rates. The key parameter in the model is the amount of ambiguity aversion, but it interacts nonlinearly with other parameters, such as the coefficient of relative risk aversion. We show a range of calibrations that match the average returns on risky riskless assets calibrate ambiguity aversion by using the volatility of short-term return on bonds the return on the long-term bonds. A question we thus ask with the present paper is to what extent the results in this previous work are robust to introducing heterogeneity in ambiguity aversion. We consider a simple model assume that half of the agents display a given amount of ambiguity aversion while the rest (the stard agents ) do not. In order to make the analysis as simple as possible, we specialize to a logarithmic period utility function iid symmetric shocks. For this particular case, we are able to show that the stard agents will increasingly dominate in the pricing of the assets over time. Furthermore, with this heterogeneity, the most ambiguity-averse agents become (almost) non-participants in the stock market over time; thus, we obtain endogenous limited participation. In conclusion, although ambiguity aversion shows great potential in providing new asset-pricing implications in allowing us to think of a reason why the elimination of aggregate fluctuations might be quite costly, heterogeneity in the degree of ambiguity aversion will tend to limit these implications mainly have effects on wealth distribution differences in portfolios across consumers. The implications for wealth inequality, however, are very striking deserve further study. The observed inequality in wealth is difficult to explain with stard versions of calibrated macroeconomic models, our present work seems to be one avenue for understing why some consumers are so rich others so poor. Finally, we note that our model has rather extreme long-run implications (both for asset prices for wealth) to a large extent because (i) agents live forever (ii) asset markets are complete. In this paper, we do not consider asset-market incompleteness (though it would seem fruitful to examine it). However, we study an extension of the setting above, which features overlapping generations : each period, there is an influx of ambiguity-averse consumers. Such an economy allows ambiguity to play a role also in the limit we characterize its long-run effects. 2 The economy This is an infinite-horizon exchange economy. Production is exogenous: the economy has a tree that pays dividends every period. The dividend grows at a rom rate, which has a two-state support given by (λ, λ 2 ) follows a first-order Markov process. The transition probabilities are given by φ ss the probability of going to state s if today s state is s, with s, s =, 2. When the consumer is ambiguous about these probabilities, he perceives them to be ( ) φ v Φ(v) = φ 2 + v, () φ 2 v 2 φ 22 + v 2 For a survey on the equity premium puzzle, see Kocherlakota (996). 3

4 where v s [ a, a] (s =, 2) with restrictions on a such that all probabilities are in [0, ]. Parameter a measures the amount of ambiguity in the economy. Preferences are given by the maxmin formulation V t (s t ) = u [ c(s t ) ] + β min E π V t+ (s t+ ), (2) π Π s t where c is consumption, u(c) is the period utility function, Π s t is a set of transition probability laws given the history s t today. Aversion to ambiguity is captured by the minimization part in the utility formulation above: the consumer behaves with pessimism, i.e., he assumes the worst possible probability distribution. For an axiomatic foundation for this preference formulation, see Gilboa Schmeidler (989) for the static setting Epstein Wang (994) Epstein Schneider (2003) for a multiperiod setting. We consider two types of agents whose ambiguity aversions differ. We look at a general planning problem first, then focus on the case with iid shocks. Later, we look at the case of serial correlation in more detail (NOT DONE YET). In section 3 we consider a model with both ambiguity-averse agents stard agents who do not view the economy as ambiguous. In section 4 we conclude. 3 Heterogeneity in ambiguity aversion 3. The planner s problem We first consider agents with a logarithmic period utility function. The state vector is (d, θ, s): today s dividend, the weight the planner puts on consumer, today s shock. The planner solves the problem V s (d, θ) = max θ log c + ( θ) log c 2 + c,c 2,z s,z 2s { } 2 2 +β min θ φ ss (v ) z s + min ( θ) φ ss (v 2 )z 2s v [ a,a ] v 2 [ a 2,a 2 ] subject to s = min V s θ (dλ s, θ s ) [θ s z s + ( θ s ) z 2s ] 0, (3) s s = c + c 2 = d, (4) where c i is agent i s consumption, i =, 2, z i is next period s present-value utility for agent i, φ s (v i ) = φ s v i, φ s2 (v i ) = φ s2 + v i. The first constraint (3) makes the problem recursive the second constraint (4) is the resource constraint. This formulation which is based on Lucas Stokey (984) is also used in Alonso (2007). Taking FOCs with respect to the consumption of agents 2, we have c = θd, (5) c 2 = ( θ)d, (6) 4

5 with respect to z () z 2 (), we obtain θ θ = θ(φ s v ) ( θ)(φ s v 2 ), (7) similarly with respect to z (2) z 2 (2) we have θ 2 θ 2 = θ(φ s2 + v ) ( θ)(φ s2 + v 2 ). (8) After some algebra where we use the law of motion for θ (s) (equations 7 8), we can rewrite the planner s problem as subject to V s (d, θ) = max θ log c + ( θ) log c 2 + c,c 2 { 2 } +β min φ ss [θv + ( θ)v 2 ] V s (dλ s, θ s ) v,v 2 s = θ s = θ φ ss (v ) φ ss [θv + ( θ)v 2 ], (9) c + c 2 = d. (0) Note that φ s [θv + ( θ)v 2 ] = φ s θv ( θ)v 2 φ s2 [θv + ( θ)v 2 ] = φ s2 + θv + ( θ)v A special case: no serial correlation a 2 = 0 In the simpler case where shocks are iid symmetric consumer 2 is not ambiguityaverse (v 2 = a 2 = 0), the planner s problem becomes 2 : subject to V (d, θ) = max θ log c + ( θ) log c 2 + c,c 2,θ s { 2 +β min v [ a,a] s = φ s (θv)v (dλ s, θ s ) } θ s = θ φ s (v) φ s (θv), () c + c 2 = d. (2). 2 From now on, we drop the subscript on v a, since it should be clear that they refer only to consumer 5

6 Using the FOCs for consumption, we obtain c = θd c 2 = ( θ)d, so we obtain with V (d, θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v [(φ θv)v (dλ, θ ) + ( φ + θv)v (dλ 2, θ 2)], θ = θ φ v φ θv, (3) θ 2 = θ φ + v φ + θv. (4) Here, we conjecture that V (d, θ) takes the form A log d + W (θ). This guess delivers A log d + W (θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v {(φ θv) [A log(dλ ) + W (θ )] + ( φ + θv) [A log(dλ 2 ) + W (θ 2)]}. Inspecting this functional equation, it can be seen that A = β W (θ) as { [ log λ +β min (φ θv) v [ a,a] β + W W (θ) = log θ θ ( θ) θ + ( θ φ v )] + ( φ + θv) φ θv works we can express [ ( log λ2 β + W θ φ + v )]}. φ + θv This is a one-dimensional dynamic programming problem delivering optimal v as a function of θ hence, a law of motion for θ. The variable θ also corresponds to the fraction of the total wealth the current dividend plus the value of the tree owned by agent in a complete-markets equilibrium. The following figures for W (θ) v(θ) below assume the following values for the parameters: λ =.02, λ 2 =.0, β = 0.98, φ = 0.5, a = 0.2. Figure, for W (θ), reveals a shape similar to log θ θ ( θ) θ, which is the (constant) flow utility of a planner in a two-type economy where no consumer has ambiguity aversion. Figure 2, for the optimal choice of v, shows that v is close to zero interior at first (for small θ s), then it increases monotonically in θ reaches the upper bound a for a value of θ a little above 0.9. We will interpret these findings in more detail in the following sections. 6

7 Figure : W (θ) Figure 2: v(θ) 7

8 3.2 The special (iid) case: the decentralized economy Markets are complete consumers trade in equity shares of the tree in a riskless bond that is in zero net supply. We denote the consumer s bond equity holdings b e, respectively. We assume that λ > λ 2 so that the bad outcome is state 2 the outcome where the dividend is low. The ambiguity-averse consumer puts a higher weight on the bad outcome than what is warranted by the objective probability; that is, he becomes pessimistic because he is worried about that outcome does not know its probability. The objective probability of this state is φ but he chooses the belief in the bad state. His belief is φ(v) = φ + v he chooses v from the set v [ a, a]. The higher is a, the more ambiguity there is in the economy. The consumer s problem is given recursively by { V (d, w, θ) = max c,b,e subject to the budget constraint the law of motion for θ s log c + β min v } 2 φ s (v)v (λ s d, w s, θ s ), s = c + p(d, θ)e + q(d, θ)b = w, (5) w s = b + e [λ s d + p(λ s d, θ s )], (6) given by θ s = g s (d, θ), (7) where (d, w, θ) is the state vector, w is the consumer s wealth today, p is the price of equity, e is the fraction of the equity share held by the consumer, q is the price today of a bond that pays one unit of the consumption good next period, b is the holdings of the bond. (The argument d is included for g only for completeness; it will not be there under the log assumption.) The consumers decision rules for all (d, w, θ) are c i (d, w, θ) (8) b i (d, w, θ) (9) e i (d, w, θ) (20) for i {, 2}. Total wealth in the economy when the state variable is (d, θ) is d + p(d, θ). Thus, market clearing requires, for all values of the arguments, c (d, θ [d + p(d, θ)], θ) + c 2 (d, ( θ) [d + p(d, θ)], θ) = d, (2) b (d, θ [d + p(d, θ)], θ) + b 2 (d, ( θ) [d + p(d, θ)], θ) = 0, (22) e (d, θ [d + p(d, θ)], θ) + e 2 (d, ( θ) [d + p(d, θ)], θ) =. (23) 8

9 The relative wealth dynamics, finally, is given by where g s (d, θ) = w s (d, θ) w s (d, θ) + w 2s (d, θ), (24) w s (d, θ) b (d, θ [d + p(d, θ)], θ) + e (d, θ [d + p(d, θ)], θ)(dλ s + p [dλ s, g s (d, θ)]), w 2s (d, θ) b 2(d, ( θ) [d + p(d, θ)], θ)+e 2 (d, ( θ) [d + p(d, θ)], θ)(dλ s +p [dλ s, g s (d, θ)]). Now we will show how to find prices portfolio allocations in this economy. We use the planning problem we identify the θ in that problem with the corresponding variable here: the planning weight on agent equals the relative fraction of total wealth held in equilibrium by this agent. To derive the prices for bonds equity, we take first-order conditions from the consumer s problem with respect to b e. The price of bonds, q(d, θ), then becomes [ φ q(d, θ) = β + φ ( + θv )] ˆq(θ). (25) λ λ 2 λ 2 λ The price of the bond is increasing in v. In addition here, the price of bonds is increasing in θ. We show below that the ambiguity-averse agents dem the bond. The bond is more valuable when marginal utility of consumption is high (which occurs in the bad state). As θ increases, there is a higher dem for the bond, so its price goes up. And the price of equity, p(d, θ), is given by { (φ θv) [λ d + p(λ d, θ p(d, θ) = β )] + ( φ + θv) [λ 2d + p(λ 2 d, θ } 2)], (26) λ λ 2 where we recall that θ = θ 2 = θ(φ v) φ θv θ( φ + v) φ + θv θ, (27) θ, (28) from the planning problem. (The inequalities above follow since v 0.) The latter laws of motion reveal that the ambiguity-averse agent gains in relative wealth when the state is bad loses when it is good: his probability beliefs are tilted toward the bad state. We see that p(d, θ) = dˆp(θ) solves this equation, delivering ˆp(θ) = β {(φ θv) [ + ˆp(θ )] + ( φ + θv) [ + ˆp(θ 2)]}. (29) 9

10 This is a functional equation: it holds for all θ (recall that v may also depend on θ). The solution to this functional equation is ˆp(θ) = β β, (30) p(d, θ) = d β β. (3) So the price of equity does not depend on θ. The equilibrium holdings of equity of consumer, which can be obtained by using the expression for future wealth, w s = b +e (λ s d+p s ), together with the equilibrium condition that w s = θ s (dλ s + p s ), are given by e (d, θ) = θ λ θ 2λ 2 λ λ 2 ê (θ). (32) Thus, the equity holdings of agent are independent of the level of d. We see that if v = 0, in which case θ = θ 2 = θ, then ê (θ) = θ: the consumer s share of the tree equals his initial share of total wealth. On the other h, when v > 0 (recall that wlog we use λ > λ 2 ), we know that θ < θ < θ 2, which makes the holdings of equity lower as compared to the case when v = 0. That is, the ambiguity-averse agent will have a smaller share of equity holdings than his overall wealth would otherwise prescribe: this is a portfolio composition effect. How much his portfolio composition will be changed must be numerically examined. We can also examine the portfolio effect by looking at the amount of bonds purchased by agent. Her equilibrium holdings of bonds are obtained as b (d, θ) = dλ β [θ ê (θ)]. (33) It is interesting to note here that bond holdings are proportional to d. Naturally, they are zero in the special case v = 0, when e = θ θ = θ. Moreover, θ ê (θ) = θ θ λ θ 2λ 2 = λ λ 2 = θ λ θ 2 λ θ 2 > 0, (34) λ λ 2 since θ 2 > θ, thus we conclude, consistently with the above insights regarding equity holdings, that the ambiguity-averse agent increases his bond holdings relative to the v = 0 zero-bonds case: his portfolio composition moves away from equity into bonds because he is more pessimistic than person 2 in his perception of the return (performance) of equity. The consumer is exposed to two sources of uncertainty in this economy: (i) the payoff of equity (ii) the price of the bond. The price of the bond depends on θ, the relative wealth of consumer, this variable is rom. In particular, since θ 2 > θ > θ, the price of the bond, q, increases if state 2 occurs it decreases if state occurs. 0

11 Below we numerically compute solutions for v(θ), θ (θ), θ p(θ)e(θ) 2(θ), e(θ),, q(θ), p(θ)e(θ)+q(θ)b(θ) b(θ) for agent. Once more, the parameter values are λ =.02, λ 2 =.0, β = 0.98, φ = 0.5, a = 0.2. As we see from the graphs in figure 3, the ambiguity-averse consumer short-sells equity for most values of θ. The reason for this is the following. State 2 is bad for the ambiguityaverse consumer for two reasons: (i) the payoff from equity is low (ii) the price of the bond increases so that it makes the good next period more expensive (this consumer does not own any goods next period). Therefore, to provide protection against the former type of uncertainty, the ambiguity-averse consumer buys bonds to provide protection against the latter type of uncertainty, the ambiguity-averse consumer sells equity short. We shall analyze the details of the graphs in figure 3 in what follows. Outcomes in the two extreme cases: θ = 0 θ = : When θ is 0 the stard agent has all the wealth asset pricing is stard because all assets are priced by the stard agent. In this case, there is voluntary non-participation in equity: at θ = 0, a measure-zero ambiguity-averse agent chooses not to participate in equity markets. He chooses v = 0 holds only bonds. Why? If he had positive equity, he would need to choose a v > 0, because his portfolio would do well in good times, so he would be pessimistic with regard to that state. But such beliefs would imply that selling equity short is optimal which is a contradiction. Similarly, negative equity implies v < 0, which implies that positive equity is optimal which again is a contradiction. So the only possibility for the ambiguity-averse agent at θ = 0 is to hold zero equity, hold bonds only, choose v = 0, have constant consumption. When θ is the ambiguity-averse agent has all the wealth asset pricing is non-stard. In particular, there is a high equity premium: since the representative agent, who must be holding all the equity no bonds, now is ambiguity-averse, v must be positive high (at its bound, if a is small). This means pessimism toward the good state, a very high bond price, a low risk-free rate. Thus, the equity premium becomes very high. With CRRA more than log curvature, the price of equity would fall the equity premium would be even higher. (No closed-form solutions for the heterogeneous-agent economy here, though.) The case with a representative agent with ambiguity aversion is treated in Appendix Intermediate values: θ > 0 but not too high Unless θ is quite high (in the numerical example), the ambiguity-averse agent is still at an interior solution: the present value utility next period is the same for each value of λ. When θ is positive but not too large, the ambiguity-averse agent short-sells the stock. Why? State 2 (the bad state) is now bad because it makes θ fall (equity does poorly, so the stard agent loses in relative terms). The price of the bond must then increase since ambiguity-averse agents become richer in relative terms dem more of it. A very small amount of pessimism rationalizes their choice, i.e., liking state 2 makes you sell equity short. Thus, you are still indifferent between which state occurs: if state occurs, the bond price is low (good, since they dem it); if state 2 occurs, their portfolio does well. v is set so that the present value utility is equal across the two outcomes. Intermediate values: nonlinearity If θ is positive but small, changes in θ do not have any considerable effects on q, so the romness in q is not so important. Then, ambiguity-averse consumers mainly hold bonds

12 e(θ) θ θ θ share of equity of agent b(θ) θ degree line θ θ θ θ Figure 3: From left to right from top to bottom: (a) v(θ), (b) law of motion for θ (θ below the 45 degree line; θ 2 above the 45 degree line), (c) e (θ), (d) share of equity of agent, (e) q(θ), (f) b(θ) 2

13 short-sell equity somewhat to protect against the uncertainty in p. This asset choice makes V (w, θ ) = V (w 2, θ 2) (35) for a small value of the belief v; that is, v is still an interior solution. The higher is θ, the more the bond price reacts: the ambiguity-averse agents now want to short-sell equity more, an even higher v is needed to justify this behavior. Agents buy bonds short-sell equity more heavily. To underst this in somewhat more detail, note that the value of v is larger, reflecting more pessimism about state 2. Since V is decreasing in θ increasing in w (the former is true because q is increasing in θ), since θ is much larger than θ 2, w 2 needs to be much larger than w in order to equate V (w, θ ) V (w 2, θ 2) hence still make v an interior solution. This is achieved by short-selling equity even more heavily. Thus, a high θ a high v are reinforcing; as can be seen, θ v appear multiplicatively in the bond-price formula above! I.e., we have a nonlinearity in the portfolio pattern. So when θ is high, ambiguity aversion makes the fluctuations in q very large. At some point, v hits the bound a. Beyond this bound, as the the ambiguity-averse agent has a higher fraction of total wealth, he will decrease the bond holding increase the equity holding, simply for market-clearing reasons (recall: at θ = he holds only equity). Over this range, the equity premium increases sharply, to motivate the ambiguity-averse agent to hold more equity less bonds. Close to θ =, the fluctuations in θ have become very small, the uncertainty resulting from changes in q is therefore also very small ambiguity-averse agents consequently do not need to short-sell the stock. 3.3 Relative consumption wealth in the long run We can analytically show 3 that E(θ θ) < θ, (36) i.e., that over time, the relative wealth of the ambiguity-averse agents decreases toward zero: these agents disappear, economically speaking. However, it can also be shown that ( θ ) E θ 0, (37) θ so the rate at which they disappear goes to zero: they remain with positive wealth for a long, long time. [to be continued] 4 Overlapping generations:an influx of ambiguity-averse consumers [to be completed] 3 The proofs of expressions (36) (37) are in the appendix. This result the following discussion are reminiscent of the analysis in Coen-Pirani (2004). 3

14 5 Conclusion [to be completed] References [] Alonso, Irasema (2007): Ambiguity in a Two-Country World, Yale University. [2] Alonso, Irasema Jose Mauricio Prado (2008): Ambiguity Aversion, Asset Prices, the Welfare Costs of Aggregate Fluctuations, Yale University IMT Lucca. [3] Coen-Pirani, Daniele (2004): Effects of Differences in Risk Aversion on the Distribution of Wealth, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 8, [4] Epstein, Larry G. Martin Schneider (2003): Recursive Multiple-Priors, Journal of Economic Theory, 3, -3. [5] Epstein, Larry G. Martin Schneider (2007): Ambiguity, Information Quality Asset Pricing, Journal of Finance, forthcoming. [6] Epstein, Larry G. Tan Wang (994): Intertemporal Asset Pricing under Knightian Uncertainty, Econometrica 62, [7] Gilboa, Itzhak David Schmeidler (989): Subjective Probability Expected Utility Without Additivity, Econometrica, 57, [8] Kocherlakota, Narayana R. (996): The Equity Premium: It s Still A Puzzle, Journal of Economic Literature, 34, [9] Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (2003): Macroeconomic Priorities, American Economic Review, 93, -4. [0] Lucas, Robert E. Jr. Nancy Stokey (984): Optimal Growth with Many Consumers, Journal of Economic Theory, 32, [] Mehra, Rajnish Edward C. Prescott (985): The Equity Premium: A Puzzle, Journal of Monetary Economics, 5,

15 Appendix A Heterogeneity in ambiguity aversion A. The planning problem We restate the planning problem: V s (d, θ) = max c,c 2 θ log c + ( θ) log c 2 + subject to +β min v,v 2 { 2 } φ ss [θv + ( θ)v 2 ] V s (dλ s, θ s ) s = θ s = θ φ ss (v ) φ ss [θv + ( θ)v 2 ], (38) c + c 2 = d. (39) Taking FOCs, we obtain c = θd c 2 = ( θ)d. The rewritten problem becomes: subject to V s (d, θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v,v 2 {[φ s θv ( θ)v 2 ] V (dλ, θ ) + [φ s2 + θv + ( θ)v 2 ] V 2 (dλ 2, θ 2)} θ s = θ φ ss (v ) φ ss [θv + ( θ)v 2 ]. (40) We conjecture that V s (d, θ) takes the form A log d + W s (θ). This guess delivers A log d + W s (θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v,v 2 {[φ s θv ( θ)v 2 ] [A log dλ + W (θ )] + [φ s2 + θv + ( θ)v 2 ] V 2 (dλ 2, θ 2)} A.. Special case: serial correlation a 2 = 0 In this case, we have subject to V s (d, θ) = max θ log c + ( θ) log c 2 + c,c 2,θ s { 2 +β min v s s = φ ss (θv)v s (dλ s, θ s ) } θ s = θ φ ss (v s) φ ss (θv s ), (4) 5

16 with c + c 2 = d. (42) Using the FOCs for consumption, we obtain c = θd c 2 = ( θ)d so we obtain V s (d, θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v s [(φ s θv s )V (dλ, θ ) + (φ s2 + θv s )V 2 (dλ 2, θ 2)] θ = θ φ s v s φ s θv s, (43) θ 2 = θ φ s2 + v s φ s2 + θv s. (44) Here, we conjecture that V s (d, θ) takes the form A log d + W s (θ). This guess delivers A log d + W s (θ) = log d + log θ θ ( θ) θ + +β min v s ((φ s θv s )(A log(dλ ) + W (θ )) + (φ s2 + θv s )(A log(dλ 2 ) + W 2 (θ 2))). Inspecting the above expression, it can be seen that A = β { [ log λ +β min (φ s θv s ) v s β + W W s (θ) = log θ θ ( θ) θ + ( θ φ )] s v s + (φ φ s θv s2 + θv s ) s works leaves [ ( log λ2 β + W 2 θ φ )]} s2 + v s φ s2 + θv s for s =, 2. This is a two-dimensional dynamic programming problem that delivers optimal v s, s =, 2, as a function of θ, hence a law of motion for θ. A.2 The decentralized economy The problem of the consumer is V s (d, w, θ) = max c,b,e subject to the budget constraint the law of motion for θ s { log c + β min v s } 2 φ ss (v s )V s (λ s d, w s, θ s ) s = c + p s (d, θ)e + q s (d, θ)b = w, (45) w s = b + e [λ s d + p s (dλ s, θ s )], (46) given by θ s = g s (d, θ, s) (47) where p is the price of equity, e is the fraction of the equity share held by the consumer, q is the price today of a bond that pays one unit of the consumption good next period, b 6

17 is the holdings of the bond. (The argument d is included for g only for completeness; it will not be there under the log assumption.) The consumers decision rules for all (d, w, θ, s) are c is (d, w, θ) (48) b is (d, w, θ) (49) e is (d, w, θ) (50) for i {, 2}. Total wealth in the economy when the state variable is (d, θ, s) is d + p s (d, θ). Thus, market clearing requires, for all values of the arguments, c s (d, θ [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) + c 2s (d, ( θ) [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) = d (5) b s (d, θ [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) + b 2s (d, ( θ) [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) = 0 (52) e s (d, θ [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) + e 2s (d, ( θ) [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) =, (53) The relative wealth dynamics, finally, are given by where g s (d, θ, s) = w s (d, θ, s) w s (d, θ, s) + w 2s (d, θ, s), (54) w s (d, θ, s) b s(d, θ [d + p s (d, θ)], θ) + e s (d, θ [d + p s (d, θ)], θ)(dλ s + p s [dλ s, g s (d, θ)]) w 2s (d, θ, s) b 2s(d, ( θ) [d + p s (d, θ)], θ)+e 2s (d, ( θ) [d + p s (d, θ)], θ)(dλ s +p s [dλ s, g s (d, θ)]) Now, we will show how to find prices portfolio allocations in this economy. We use the planning problem identify the θ in that problem with the corresponding variable here: the planning weight on agent equals the relative fraction of total wealth held in equilibrium by this agent. The Euler equation for bonds is given by q s (d, θ) c is (d, w, θ) = β ( φ s (v) c i (λ d, w i, θ ) + φ s2(v) c i2 (λ 2 d, w i2, θ 2) ), (55) since c s (d, w, θ) = θd ( c 2s (d, w, θ) = ( θ)d), we have ( φs (v) q s (d, θ) = βθ θ + φ ) s2(v) λ θ. (56) 2λ 2 Simplifying further using the law of motion for θ s deriving the Euler equation for equity in a similarly fashion, the prices of bonds, q s (d, θ), of equity, p s (d, θ), then become [ q s (d, θ) = β φ s (v) φ s θv + φ (φ s v)λ s2 (v) φ ] s2 + θv ˆq s (θ), (57) (φ s2 + v)λ 2 7

18 p s (d, θ) = β { (φs θv) [λ d + p (λ d, θ )] + (φ s2 + θv) [λ 2 d + p 2 (λ 2 d, θ } 2)] λ λ 2 (58) We see that p s (d, θ) = dˆp s (θ) solves this equation, delivering ˆp s (θ) = β {(φ s θv) [ + ˆp (θ )] + (φ s2 + θv) [ + ˆp 2 (θ 2)]} (59) This is a system of two functional equations. Asset holdings are the following. First, his equilibrium holdings of bonds are b s (d, θ) = [dλ + p (λ d, θ )] [θ e s (d, θ)] = dλ [ + ˆp (θ )] [θ ê s (θ)] It is interesting to note here that bond holdings are proportional to d. Naturally, they are zero in the special case v = 0, when e = θ θ = θ. And his equilibrium holdings of equity are e s (d, θ) = θ [dλ + p (λ d, θ )] θ 2 [dλ 2 + p 2 (λ 2 d, θ 2)] [dλ + p (λ d, θ )] [dλ 2 + p 2 (λ 2 d, θ 2)] = = θ λ [ + ˆp (θ )] θ 2λ 2 [ + ˆp 2 (θ 2)] λ [ + ˆp (θ )] λ 2 [ + ˆp 2 (θ 2)] ê s (θ) (60) This is once more a system of two functional equations. Neither bond holdings nor equity holdings depend directly on s, but they do through the dependence of the θ s on s. A.3 The special case where θ = 0 We solve the problem for an ambiguity-averse agent who is measure zero in the economy. This agent solves the problem subject to V (w, d) = max c,b,e The FOCs with respect to b are u(c) + min β [(φ v)v (w, dλ ) + ( φ + v)v (w 2, dλ 2 )] v c + qb + pde = w (6) w = b + (λ d + pλ d)e (62) w 2 = b + (λ 2 d + pλ 2 d)e (63) qu (w qb + pde) = = β {(φ v)u [b + eλ d( + p) qb pdλ e ] + ( φ + v)u [b + eλ 2 d( + p) qb pdλ 2 e ]} with respect to e, they are pdu (w qb + pde) = 8

19 = β{(φ v)u [b + eλ d( + p) qb pdλ e ] λ d( + p)+ +( φ + v)u [b + eλ 2 d( + p) qb pdλ 2 e ] λ 2 d( + p)} Using logarithmic utility, we see that these equations become [ φ v q = β b + eλ d( + p) qb pdλ e + p + p = β [ We guess that φ + v b + eλ 2 d( + p) qb pdλ 2 e ] (w qb + pde) ] (φ v)λ b + eλ d( + p) qb pdλ e + ( φ + v)λ 2 (w qb + pde). b + eλ 2 d( + p) qb pdλ 2 e b = α b w (64) ed = α e w. (65) Then q = { } φ v = β [α b + α e λ ( + p)] ( qα b pλ α e ) + φ + v ( qα b pα e ) [α b + α e λ 2 ( + p)] ( qα b pλ 2 α e ) p + p = { = β (φ v)λ [α b + α e λ ( + p)] ( qα b pλ α e ) + ( φ + v)λ 2 [α b + α e λ 2 ( + p)] ( qα b pλ 2 α e ) The problem of the consumer can be rewritten as subject to V (w) = max c,b,e log c + min β [(φ v)v (w ) + ( φ + v)v (w 2)] v } ( qα b pα e ) c + qb + pê = w (66) w = b + êλ ( + p) (67) w 2 = b + êλ 2 ( + p), (68) where ê de. The variable v will be chosen (due to the envelope theorem) so that V (w ) = V (w 2), i.e., so that w = w 2. That means that b = α b w ê = 0 the agent does not hold equity from the FOC above, that [ q = β φ v α b ( qα b ) + φ + v ] ( qα b ). (69) α b ( qα b ) This expression simplifies to then consumption is given by α b q = β (70) c = ( β)w. (7) 9

20 Since p +p Therefore, = β in the θ = case, this implies α b = (φ v)λ + ( φ + v)λ 2. (72) v = φλ + ( φ)λ 2 α b λ λ 2 = φ α b λ 2 λ λ 2 (73) For φ = 0.5, β = 0.98 λ =.02, λ 2 =.0, α b = 2λ λ 2 λ +λ 2, A2 Proofs of subsection 5.3 We want to proof that Since expression (76) becomes: Simplifying (78) yields: Since v 0, v = φ α b λ 2 λ λ 2. (74) v = φ λ 2 λ + λ 2 = (75) E(θ θ) < θ. (76) E(θ θ (φ v) θ ( φ + v) θ) = φ + ( φ) φ θv φ + θv, (77) θ (φ v) θ ( φ + v) φ + ( φ) φ θv φ + θv < θ. (78) θ 2 v 2 < θv 2. (79) θ <. (80) And condition (80) is always true in the case we study, otherwise we would be back to the case of one agent. ( ) ( ) θ The proof that lim θ 0 E θ = is even simpler. First, consider expression for E : θ θ Then, the limit becomes: ( θ ) E θ = φ φ v φ + v + ( φ) φ θv φ + θv. (8) lim φ φ v φ + v + ( φ) θ 0 φ θv φ + θv = φ φ v φ + ( φ) φ + v φ = φ v + φ + v =. (82) 20

21 A3 Representative-agent asset pricing In this section for simplicity, we first consider an ambiguity-averse representative agent with a logarithmic period utility function discount factor β. In addition, we first assume that shocks are iid symmetric, i.e., φ ss = 0.5. After that, we consider a CRRA period utility function assume serially correlated shocks. Then, we calibrate the economy report the model s performance. There is an equity share that is competitively traded a riskless bond that is in zero net supply. We denote the consumer s bond equity holdings b e, respectively. The representative agent holds the tree thus, his consumption in every period is the dividend of the tree. A log-period utility function together with the assumption of iid shocks imply that p, the price of the tree, will be linear in d, the dividend, independent of the state: p(d) = ˆpd. The ambiguity-averse consumer puts a higher weight on the bad outcome than what is warranted by the objective probability; that is, he becomes pessimistic because he is worried about that outcome does not know its probability. We assume that λ > λ 2 so that the bad outcome is state 2 the outcome where the dividend is low. The objective probability of this state is 0.5, but he chooses the belief in the bad state. His belief is φ(v) = 0.5 v he chooses v from the set v [ a, a]. The higher is a, the more ambiguity there is in the economy. The problem of the representative agent with wealth today given by w is subject to V (w) = max log [w p(d)e] + β min (φ v)v (w ) + ( φ + v)v (w 2) e v [ a,a] w = [λ d + p(dλ )] e, w 2 = [λ 2 d + p(dλ 2 )] e. Here, for ease of notation, we have excluded the bond (since bond holdings must be zero in equilibrium). Moreover, the budget constraint: c + p(d)e + q(d)b = w where w = [d + p(d)] e + b (e b are equity bond holdings chosen in the previous period) has been substituted away. The Euler equation for equity is p(d)u (d) = β {(φ a)[λ d + p(λ d)]u (λ d) + ( φ + a)[λ 2 d + p(λ 2 d)]u (λ 2 d)}. (83) Clearly, p is linear in d (a constant times d), whenever u (c) = c σ (here, σ = ). Since the period utility is logarithmic, the price of equity does not depend on beliefs because the payoff the inverse of marginal utility (u ) are proportional to λd so that the payoff times marginal utility is the same in both states. Thus, p(d) = d solves the Euler equation above: the price of equity is independent of φ a. Trivially here, since e = in equilibrium, w = λ d, β w 2 = λ 2d, then V β (w ) > V (w 2), so the solution for v is a corner, i.e., v = a. In section 5, we show that v can be an interior solution when the economy is populated by both ambiguity-averse stard consumers. β β 2

22 The Euler equation for bonds similarly gives q(d)u (d) = β {(φ a)u (λ d) + ( φ + a)u (λ 2 d)}. (84) We see that q depends on beliefs: [( φ q = β + φ ) λ λ 2 ( + a )]. (85) λ 2 λ The higher is a the more ambiguity aversion there is in the economy the higher is the belief that the bad state will happen, the higher is the present value of one unit tomorrow, since the probability weight placed on the state with a high marginal utility is higher. The net expected return on equity, ER e, is given by ER e = φλ + ( φ)λ 2 β, (86) it is independent of the belief. The net return on bonds, R b, decreases when ambiguity aversion increases, because R b = q. The equity premium in this economy is ER e R b = φλ + ( φ)λ 2 β λ λ 2 β [( φ)λ + φλ 2 + a(λ λ 2 )]. (87) If we make φ = 0.5, then the equity premium in this economy is ER e R b = λ + λ 2 2β λ λ 2 β [0.5(λ + λ 2 ) + a(λ λ 2 )]. (88) When ambiguity is most extreme, i.e., when a = 0.5, the equity premium becomes λ λ 2. 2β Using λ =.02, λ 2 =.0, β = 0.98, the equity premium is 0.5%, which is 200 times larger than the equity premium for the same parameter values when a = 0 the stard model. Although this is an example, not a calibration, it illustrates that the effect of ambiguity on asset prices/returns can be substantial. If the period utility is u(d) = d α, the price of equity depends on beliefs. In fact: α A3. Serial correlation ˆp = β [ (φ a)λ α + ( φ + a)λ α 2 β [ ]. (φ a)λ α + ( φ + a)λ α (89) 2 We now assume that the period utility is u(c) = c α the shocks are serially correlated. α The problem of the representative agent with wealth today given by w today s shock s is V s (w) = max u [w p s (d)e] + β min (φ s v s )V (w ) + (φ s2 + v s )V 2 (w 2) e v s [ a,a] 22 ]

23 subject to The Euler equation for equity is w = [λ d + p (dλ )] e, w 2 = [λ 2 d + p 2 (dλ 2 )] e. p s (d)u (d) = β {(φ s v s )[λ d + p (λ d)]u (λ d) + (φ s2 + v s )[λ 2 d + p 2 (λ 2 d)]u (λ 2 d)} (90) The price of equity is still linear in d, is now given by where p s (d) = k s d (9) k s = β [ (φ s v s )λ α ( + k ) + (φ s2 + v s )λ α 2 ( + k 2 ) ], (92) for s =, 2. Explicitly solving for k k 2, we obtain: k = β(φ [ ] a)λ α β(φ22 + a)λ α 2 + β(φ2 + a)λ α 2 + β 2 (φ 2 + a)(φ 2 a)(λ λ 2 ) α [ ] [ ] β(φ22 + a)λ α 2 β(φ a)λ α β 2 (φ 2 + a)(φ 2 a)(λ λ 2 ) α k 2 = β(φ [ ] 22 + a)λ α 2 β(φ a)λ α + β(φ2 a)λ α + β 2 (φ 2 a)(φ 2 + a)(λ λ 2 ) α [ ] [ ] β(φ22 + a)λ α 2 β(φ a)λ α β 2 (φ 2 + a)(φ 2 a)(λ λ 2 ) α Thus, wealth in the next period is: The price of the bond is given by [ q s (d) = β φ s λ α w = λ d( + k ), (93) w 2 = λ 2 d( + k 2 ). (94) + φ s2 λ α 2 for s =, 2. The conditional expected net return on equity is ( + a λ α 2 )] λ α ER e s = φ s [λ d + p (λ d)] + φ s2 [λ 2 d + p 2 (λ 2 d)] p s (d) for s =, 2, the unconditional expected net return on equity ER e, is where the invariant probability π solves πer e + ( π)er e 2 (95) (96) π = φ π + φ 2 ( π). (97) 23

24 Therefore, ER e = π φ [λ d + p (λ d)] + φ 2 [λ 2 d + p 2 (λ 2 d)] + p (d) +( π) φ 2 [λ d + p (λ d)] + φ 22 [λ 2 d + p 2 (λ 2 d)] p 2 (d) (98) ER e = π φ λ ( + k ) + φ 2 λ 2 ( + k 2 ) k + ( π) φ 2λ ( + k ) + φ 22 λ 2 ( + k 2 ) k 2 (99) The expected net return on the bond, R b, is given by β φ λ α + φ 2 λ α 2 π ( + a λ α 2 π q + ( π) q 2 = ) + λ α Finally, the equity premium is given by φ 2 λ α ER e R b. + φ 22 λ α 2 ( π) ( + a λ α 2 λ α ). (00) 24

Choice under Uncertainty

Choice under Uncertainty Choice under Uncertainty Part 1: Expected Utility Function, Attitudes towards Risk, Demand for Insurance Slide 1 Choice under Uncertainty We ll analyze the underlying assumptions of expected utility theory

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

The Real Business Cycle model

The Real Business Cycle model The Real Business Cycle model Spring 2013 1 Historical introduction Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynesian

More information

Margin Regulation and Volatility

Margin Regulation and Volatility Margin Regulation and Volatility Johannes Brumm 1 Michael Grill 2 Felix Kubler 3 Karl Schmedders 3 1 University of Zurich 2 Deutsche Bundesbank 3 University of Zurich and Swiss Finance Institute Workshop:

More information

Cash in advance model

Cash in advance model Chapter 4 Cash in advance model 4.1 Motivation In this lecture we will look at ways of introducing money into a neoclassical model and how these methods can be developed in an effort to try and explain

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper)

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research

More information

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti) Kjetil Storesletten September 10, 2013 Kjetil Storesletten () Lecture 3 September 10, 2013 1 / 44 Growth

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

1 Portfolio mean and variance

1 Portfolio mean and variance Copyright c 2005 by Karl Sigman Portfolio mean and variance Here we study the performance of a one-period investment X 0 > 0 (dollars) shared among several different assets. Our criterion for measuring

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 1 Consumption with many periods 1.1 Finite horizon of T Optimization problem maximize U t = u (c t ) + β (c t+1 ) + β 2 u (c t+2 ) +...

More information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information by Sanford Grossman This model shows how the heterogeneous information

More information

No-Betting Pareto Dominance

No-Betting Pareto Dominance No-Betting Pareto Dominance Itzhak Gilboa, Larry Samuelson and David Schmeidler HEC Paris/Tel Aviv Yale Interdisciplinary Center Herzlyia/Tel Aviv/Ohio State May, 2014 I. Introduction I.1 Trade Suppose

More information

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds

Empirical Applying Of Mutual Funds Internet Appendix for A Model of hadow Banking * At t = 0, a generic intermediary j solves the optimization problem: max ( D, I H, I L, H, L, TH, TL ) [R (I H + T H H ) + p H ( H T H )] + [E ω (π ω ) A

More information

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Daniele Coen-Pirani Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890, USA Abstract This paper studies

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 1 Introduction This note describes the canonical real business cycle model. A couple of classic references

More information

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Optimality Conditions Euler equation under uncertainty: u C (C t, 1 N t) = βe t [u C (C t+1, 1 N t+1)

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

The Equity Premium in India

The Equity Premium in India The Equity Premium in India Rajnish Mehra University of California, Santa Barbara and National Bureau of Economic Research January 06 Prepared for the Oxford Companion to Economics in India edited by Kaushik

More information

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model These notes consider the single-period model in Kyle (1985) Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica 15,

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2015 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 13 2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Introduction Simplistic RBC Model Simple stochastic growth model Baseline RBC model Introduction

More information

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet Econ 497 Barry W. Ickes Spring 2007 Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet 1. (25%) Consider a portfolio, c, comprised of a risk-free and risky asset, with returns given by r f and E(r p ), respectively. Let y be the

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle Simon Gilchrist Boston Univerity and NBER EC 745 Fall, 2013 Overview Some basic facts. Study the asset pricing implications of household portfolio

More information

7: The CRR Market Model

7: The CRR Market Model Ben Goldys and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney MATH3075/3975 Financial Mathematics Semester 2, 2015 Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein

More information

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk

3 Introduction to Assessing Risk 3 Introduction to Assessing Risk Important Question. How do we assess the risk an investor faces when choosing among assets? In this discussion we examine how an investor would assess the risk associated

More information

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Prep. Course Macroeconomics Prep. Course Macroeconomics Intertemporal consumption and saving decision; Ramsey model Tom-Reiel Heggedal tom-reiel.heggedal@bi.no BI 2014 Heggedal (BI) Savings & Ramsey 2014 1 / 30 Overview this lecture

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

Discrete Dynamic Optimization: Six Examples

Discrete Dynamic Optimization: Six Examples Discrete Dynamic Optimization: Six Examples Dr. Tai-kuang Ho Associate Professor. Department of Quantitative Finance, National Tsing Hua University, No. 101, Section 2, Kuang-Fu Road, Hsinchu, Taiwan 30013,

More information

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Week 5 Precepts October 21 Insurance, Portfolio Choice - Questions

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Week 5 Precepts October 21 Insurance, Portfolio Choice - Questions ECO 37 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Week 5 Precepts October 2 Insurance, Portfolio Choice - Questions Important Note: To get the best value out of this precept, come with your calculator or

More information

The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection

The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection The Effect of Ambiguity Aversion on Insurance and Self-protection David Alary Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA) Christian Gollier Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA and IDEI) Nicolas Treich Toulouse

More information

Health and Portfolio Choice in Retirement: The Impact of Ambiguity

Health and Portfolio Choice in Retirement: The Impact of Ambiguity Health and Portfolio Choice in Retirement: The Impact of Ambiguity Lei Guo University of Minnesota Hui He University of Hawaii 26th March 2010 Abstract This paper first documents that in the U.S., the

More information

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow EIEF October 9 202 Use a risk averse market making model to investigate. [Microstructural determinants of volatility, liquidity and

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK

WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK WORKING PAPER NO. 11-18 PRIVATE EQUITY PREMIUM IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF UNINSURABLE INVESTMENT RISK Francisco Covas Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Shigeru Fujita Federal

More information

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics Session IX: Stock Options: Properties, Mechanics and Valuation Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo Module: Economics of Financial Markets MSc. Financial Economics Department of Economics, City University, London Stock

More information

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions Franck Portier TSE Macro II 29-21 Chapter 3 Real Business Cycles 36 3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model Perfectly competitive economy Optimal growth model + Labor decisions 2 types of agents

More information

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives 1.1 Financial Markets Financial markets are markets for financial instruments, in which buyers and sellers find each other and create or exchange

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities

Asset Prices And Asset Quantities Asset Prices And Asset Quantities Monika Piazzesi University of Chicago, CEPR and NBER Martin Schneider NYU and FRB Minneapolis October 2006 Abstract We propose an organizing framework that determines

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge Stefano Eusepi, Marc Giannoni and Bruce Preston The views expressed are those of the authors and are not necessarily re

More information

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS

CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS CHAPTER 6: RISK AVERSION AND CAPITAL ALLOCATION TO RISKY ASSETS PROBLEM SETS 1. (e). (b) A higher borrowing is a consequence of the risk of the borrowers default. In perfect markets with no additional

More information

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS 1. Introduction All of the options that we have considered thus far have been of the European variety: exercise is permitted only at the termination of the contract. These

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles: Chapter 5 Real business cycles 5.1 Real business cycles The most well known paper in the Real Business Cycles (RBC) literature is Kydland and Prescott (1982). That paper introduces both a specific theory

More information

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options. Chapter 11 Options Road Map Part A Introduction to finance. Part B Valuation of assets, given discount rates. Part C Determination of risk-adjusted discount rate. Part D Introduction to derivatives. Forwards

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

A Log-Robust Optimization Approach to Portfolio Management

A Log-Robust Optimization Approach to Portfolio Management A Log-Robust Optimization Approach to Portfolio Management Dr. Aurélie Thiele Lehigh University Joint work with Ban Kawas Research partially supported by the National Science Foundation Grant CMMI-0757983

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 Options These notes consider the way put and call options and the underlying can be combined to create hedges, spreads and combinations. We will consider the

More information

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging 1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging 1.1 Dividends Since we are now in a continuous time framework the dividend paid out at time t (or t ) is given by dd t = D t D t, where as before D denotes

More information

Why Do Older People Quit The Stock Market?

Why Do Older People Quit The Stock Market? Why Do Older People Quit The Stock Market? Lei Guo University of Minnesota Hui He University of Hawaii Zheng Liu Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco February 13, 2009 Abstract We document that in the

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Real Business Cycle Models Lecture 2 Nicola Viegi April 2015 Basic RBC Model Claim: Stochastic General Equlibrium Model Is Enough to Explain The Business cycle Behaviour of the Economy Money is of little

More information

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function Jarek Hurnik Department of Economics Lecture III Jarek Hurnik (Department of Economics) Monetary Economics 2012 1 / 24 Basic Facts So far, the

More information

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options CS 5 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options 1. Definitions Equity. The common stock of a corporation. Traded on organized exchanges (NYSE, AMEX, NASDAQ). A common

More information

Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels

Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels Florian Scheuer 4/8/2014 Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels 1 Overview optimal insurance design, application: UI benefit level Baily (JPubE 1978), generalized by Chetty (JPubE 2006) optimal

More information

How Much Can Taxation Alleviate Temptation and Self-Control Problems?

How Much Can Taxation Alleviate Temptation and Self-Control Problems? How Much Can Taxation Alleviate Temptation and Self-Control Problems? Per Krusell, Burhanettin Kuruşçu, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. May 2009 Abstract We develop a quantitative dynamic general-equilibrium

More information

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix

Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks Online Appendix By Urban Jermann and Vincenzo Quadrini Data sources Financial data is from the Flow of Funds Accounts of the Federal Reserve Board. We report the

More information

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t. LECTURE 7: BLACK SCHOLES THEORY 1. Introduction: The Black Scholes Model In 1973 Fisher Black and Myron Scholes ushered in the modern era of derivative securities with a seminal paper 1 on the pricing

More information

Graduate Macroeconomics 2

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 1 - Introduction to Real Business Cycles Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 January About the course I. 2-hour lecture every week, Tuesdays from 10:15-12:15 2 big topics

More information

The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber

The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber 1 Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber January 2002 Consider a non-dividend paying stock whose price is initially S 0. Divide time into small

More information

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing.

Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of. International Consumption Risk Sharing. Volatility, Productivity Correlations and Measures of International Consumption Risk Sharing. Ergys Islamaj June 2014 Abstract This paper investigates how output volatility and productivity correlations

More information

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Willemien Kets Northwestern University w-kets@kellogg.northwestern.edu David M. Pennock Microsoft Research New York City dpennock@microsoft.com

More information

A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand. April 2005. Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East Lansing, MI 48824

A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand. April 2005. Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East Lansing, MI 48824 A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand April 2005 Donald J. Meyer Jack Meyer Department of Economics Department of Economics Western Michigan University Michigan State University Kalamazoo, MI 49008 East

More information

1 The Black-Scholes Formula

1 The Black-Scholes Formula 1 The Black-Scholes Formula In 1973 Fischer Black and Myron Scholes published a formula - the Black-Scholes formula - for computing the theoretical price of a European call option on a stock. Their paper,

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Real Business Cycle Theory Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Introduction to DSGE models Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models have become the main tool for

More information

On the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles*

On the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles* Review of Economic Dynamics 2, 245 272 (1999) Article ID redy.1998.0043, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on On the Welfare Effects of Eliminating Business Cycles* Per Krusell Department

More information

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully Review for Exam 2 Instructions: Please read carefully The exam will have 25 multiple choice questions and 5 work problems You are not responsible for any topics that are not covered in the lecture note

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Chapter 4 Real Business Cycle Theory This section of the textbook focuses on explaining the behavior of the business cycle. The terms business cycle, short-run macroeconomics, and economic fluctuations

More information

Internet Appendix for Money Creation and the Shadow Banking System [Not for publication]

Internet Appendix for Money Creation and the Shadow Banking System [Not for publication] Internet Appendix for Money Creation and the Shadow Banking System [Not for publication] 1 Internet Appendix: Derivation of Gross Returns Suppose households maximize E β t U (C t ) where C t = c t + θv

More information

Limited Market Participation and Asset Prices in the Presence of Earnings Management

Limited Market Participation and Asset Prices in the Presence of Earnings Management Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers Number 1019 June 011 Limited Market Participation and Asset Prices in the Presence of Earnings Management Bo Sun

More information

CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB

CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB CONTENTS OF VOLUME IB Introduction to the Series Contents of the Handbook Preface v vii ix FINANCIAL MARKETS AND ASSET PRICING Chapter 10 Arbitrage, State Prices and Portfolio Theory PHILIP H. DYBVIG and

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Phd Macro, 2007 (Karl Whelan) 1 Real Business Cycle Models The Real Business Cycle (RBC) model introduced in a famous 1982 paper by Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott is the original DSGE model. 1 The early

More information

International Stock Market Integration: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach

International Stock Market Integration: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach International Stock Market Integration: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach Harjoat S. Bhamra London Business School 2003 Outline of talk 1 Introduction......................... 1 2 Economy...........................

More information

Online Appendix for Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets

Online Appendix for Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets Online Appendix for Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets Hui Chen Scott Joslin Sophie Ni August 3, 2015 1 An Extension of the Dynamic Model Our model

More information

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Kang Shi The Chinese University of Hong Kong Juanyi Xu Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Simon Fraser University November

More information

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Jirô Akahori, Yuji Hishida and Maho Nishida Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, Ritsumeikan University 1-1-1 Nojihigashi, Kusatsu, Shiga 525-8577, Japan E-mail: {akahori,

More information

A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation

A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation Arnaud Costinot Guido Lorenzoni Iván Werning Central Bank of Chile, November 2013 Tariffs and capital controls Tariffs: Intratemporal

More information

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty 1. Introduction In this lecture we examine the theory of decision-making under uncertainty and its application to the demand for insurance. The undergraduate

More information

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Problem Set 9 Solutions Problem Set 9 s 1. A monopoly insurance company provides accident insurance to two types of customers: low risk customers, for whom the probability of an accident is 0.25, and high risk customers, for

More information

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Filipe R. Campante Davin Chor July 200 Abstract In this online appendix, we present the proofs for

More information

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem Gagan Deep Singh Assistant Vice President Genpact Smart Decision Services Financial

More information

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance

Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Exam Introduction Mathematical Finance and Insurance Date: January 8, 2013. Duration: 3 hours. This is a closed-book exam. The exam does not use scrap cards. Simple calculators are allowed. The questions

More information

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology March 24, 2005 1 Introduction The purchase of an options contract gives the buyer the right to buy call options contract or sell put options contract some

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

The Impact of Interlinked Insurance and Credit Contracts on Financial Market Deepening and Small Farm Productivity

The Impact of Interlinked Insurance and Credit Contracts on Financial Market Deepening and Small Farm Productivity The Impact of Interlinked Insurance and Credit Contracts on Financial Market Deepening and Small Farm Productivity June 2011 Summary Twin puzzles Ample evidence that uninsured risk depresses small holder

More information

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Zeldes, QJE 1989 Background (Not in Paper) Income Uncertainty dates back to even earlier years, with the seminal work of

More information

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold?

How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? How Much Equity Does the Government Hold? Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley and NBER January 2004 This paper was presented at the 2004 Meetings of the American Economic Association. I

More information

Online Supplementary Material

Online Supplementary Material Online Supplementary Material The Supplementary Material includes 1. An alternative investment goal for fiscal capacity. 2. The relaxation of the monopoly assumption in favor of an oligopoly market. 3.

More information

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY 1. The revised estimate of the expected rate of return on the stock would be the old estimate plus the sum of the products of the unexpected change in each factor times

More information

Ambiguous Business Cycles

Ambiguous Business Cycles Ambiguous Business Cycles Cosmin Ilut Duke University Martin Schneider Stanford University April 211 Abstract This paper considers business cycle models with agents who are averse not only to risk, but

More information

Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents

Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents William H. Sandholm January 6, 22 O.. Imitative protocols, mean dynamics, and equilibrium selection In this section, we consider

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices ANDREA M. BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY Boston University London School of Economics London School of Economics September, 2013 Abstract We study

More information