Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Faculty of Bioscience Engineering



Similar documents
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Faculty of Agricultural and Applied Biological Sciences

How To Understand The Economic Theory Of Trade

Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Faculty of Agricultural and Applied Biological Sciences

EASYPol Module 148. DrumNet An Enterprising Third Party Transaction Manager

PJ 22/12. 7 February 2012 English only. Projects Committee/ International Coffee Council 5 8 March 2012 London, United Kingdom

Exchanging Agricultural Market Information through SMS in Cambodia

EB 3946/ May 2008 Original: English. Executive Board/ International Coffee Council May 2008 London, England

Financial Instruments Traded on the Commodity Exchange

How To Help The World Coffee Sector

PJ 24/ February 2012 English only. Projects Committee/ International Coffee Council 5 8 March 2012 London, United Kingdom

LAUNCHING A SUCCESSFUL COMMODITY EXCHANGE IN TANZANIA. Godfrey Malekano, Director Market Supervision & Market Development-CMSA

Food & Farming. Focus on Market Safety Nets. December Agriculture and Rural Development

DAIRY MARKETS And POLICY

MARKET INFORMATION SYSTEMS AND PARTNERSHIPS IN MOZAMBIQUE. Lara Carrilho WFP Mozambique António Paulo SIMA/MINAG. Background

Farmer field school networks in Western Kenya

Mitigation of Investment Risk

CF 2/12. 3 April 2012 Original: English. 2 nd Consultative Forum on Coffee Sector Finance 6 March 2012 London, United Kingdom

THE PROCESS OF PLANNING AND INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK FOR POVERTY REDUCTION STRATEGY: THE CASE OF UGANDA.

Ministerie van Toerisme, Economische Zaken, Verkeer en Telecommunicatie Ministry of Tourism, Economic Affairs, Transport and Telecommunication

2. The second generation of MIS: a diversity of models

NETWORK SUSTAINABILITY 1. Guillermo Rivero, Financial Services Manager, Pact HQ. USA

Food Security Through Commercialization. International Agribusiness Forum EMRC Kampala Uganda, October 3 th -6 th, 2010

7. ASSESSING EXISTING INFORMATION SYSTEMS AND INFORMATION NEEDS: INFORMATION GAP ANALYSIS

FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF NIGERIA. Unity and Faith, Peace and Progress

Chapter 6 Marketing services

NIGERIA S EXPORT TRADE OF AGRICULTURAL COMMODITIES: QUALITY CONTROL AND STANDARDS 2004 PRESENTED

Food Security: A Priority for the Inter American Social Protection Network

CORAF/WECARD - VACANCY POSITION

Making the Most of Africa s Commodities: Industrializing for Growth, Jobs and Economic Transformation

Facilitating Remittances to Help Families and Small Businesses

THE IMPACT OF MOVING TO KNOWLEDGE BASED ECONOMY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR

2. The proposal has been sent to the Virtual Screening Committee (VSC) for evaluation and will be examined by the Executive Board in September 2008.

The role of Agricultural cooperatives in accessing input and output markets An overview of experiences of SRFCF, SNNPR, Ethiopia

Agricultural Statistics Assessment in Cameroon: Developing the Agricultural Data Quality Assessment Framework (DQAF)

TRADE AND FOOD SECURITY: A GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE

PUBLIC POLICY IN FOOD AND AGRICULTURE - Food Security and Government Intervention - Samarendu Mohanty, E. Wesley F. Peterson

Orange's services for agriculture in Africa. external diffusion

Scope of Work Consultancy Services of Communication Specialist for the Development of Project Communication Strategy and Plan 1. PURPOSE The purpose

Poultry Production and Marketing Project. Kitui County. Terms of Reference. For. An End of Project Evaluation

GLOBAL ALLIANCE FOR CLIMATE-SMART AGRICULTURE (GACSA)

The UNIDROIT/FAO/IFAD Legal Guide on Contract Farming

Governance as Stewardship: Decentralization and Sustainable Human Development

Agricultural Investment Funds (AIFs) Nomathemba Mhlanga, Ph.D. Rural Infrastructure and Agro-Industries Division (AGS) FAO-Rome

Organic farming. A guide on support opportunities for organic producers in Europe. Agriculture and Rural Development

EB 3776/01 Rev March 2002 Original: English. Rules on Statistics. Indicator prices

Council Conclusions on Finance for Growth and the Long-term Financing of the European Economy. ECOFIN Council meeting Brussels, 9 December 2014

Terms of Reference (TOR) For Impact Evaluation of ANN Project

Opportunities for Financing the Agricultural Sector in Turkey

UNCTAD GLOBAL COMMODITIES FORUM 2013 Recommitting to commodity sector development as an engine of economic growth and poverty reduction

Bridging funding for the Agricultural Commodity Exchange for Africa Trust Quarterly Progress report

Transforming and Improving livelihoods through Market Development and Smallholder Commercialization in Sub- Saharan Africa

Business as Usual is Not an Option: Trade and Markets

ENCOURAGING A DYNAMIC LIFE INSURANCE INDUSTRY: ECONOMIC BENEFITS AND POLICY ISSUES

Business Support Services to small producers. Report of the workshop organised in Dar es Salaam September 24 th Page 1 of 9

Research to improve the use and conservation of agricultural biodiversity for smallholder farmers

Strategic Industrial Intelligence and Governance

How To Finance A Value Chain

Prudential Standards, Guidelines and Rating System for SADC DFIs 2013 Results

There is strong Government. Uganda: performance contracting, budget reporting and budget monitoring SUMMARY

Prepared by the Commission on Environment & Energy

Financing Smallholder Farmers. to Increase Incomes and Transform Lives in Rural Communities

Web Annex 6: Output indicators and targets

EVOLUTION OF THE MARKET A ZAMBIAN CASE STUDY

Note No. 137 March Countries in Asia, Europe, and North and South America are introducing reforms to boost

RURAL AND AGRICULTURE FINANCE Prof. Puneetha Palakurthi School of Community Economic Development Sothern New Hampshire University

Salzburg ii recommendations. EuroPEan universities achievements SincE 2005 in implementing the Salzburg PrinciPlES

NOTIFICATION. To enhance understanding of the relationship between these areas and their link to country development strategies;

Have Recent Increases in International Cereal Prices Been Transmitted to Domestic Economies? The experience in seven large Asian countries

TELECOMMUNICATION IN ETHIOPIA

Cameroon CFSVA April/May Cameroon Comprehensive Food Security and Vulnerability Analysis. April/May Page 1

LEARNING CASE 9: GENDER AND RURAL INFORMATION AND COMMUNICATIONS TECHNOLOGY 1

How to Design and Update School Feeding Programs

Competition policy and Law in Nepal.

Patrice Annequin Senior Market Information Specialist AfricaFertilizer.org coordinator Africa Committee Meeting Accra, Sept 2012.

Okinawa Charter on Global Information Society

Strengthening the impact of African agricultural MISs on policies and market efficiency

viewpoint MEDIA FREEDOM AND PLURALISM

Representatives from National and International Research Institutions;

2 nd EUA Funding Forum: Strategies for efficient funding of universities

Registration Form for Companies

TIPS. Performance Monitoring and Evaluation BUILDING A RESULTS FRAMEWORK. What Is a Results Framework? What Functions Does a Results Framework Serve?

Risk Management Tools in Europe: Agricultural Insurance, Futures, and Options

CROSS-BORDER TRADE FLOW IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS IN WEST AFRICA December, 2013

PRESENTATION ON GHANA S NATIONAL COCOA PLAN

Task Allocation and Human Resource Management at Glasshouse Holdings in the Flanders

Building Partnerships for Aid Effectiveness. 1. Introduction

GBMC (Global Business & Management Consulting)

Attachment Gérard Biraud

FEED THE FUTURE LEARNING AGENDA

Knowledge Management and Networking in Extension using ICTs

These commodity markets have their own peculiar features, including :

Economics and Trade Branch as of 16 November 2009

PPIAF Assistance in Afghanistan

Overview of food security projects funded by EKN Addis Ababa in 2016

Distance learning program for agricultural education in Southern Africa. Mungule Chikoye, Krishna Alluri, Richard Siaciwena, and Rainer Zachmann *

INCORPORATING SMALL PRODUCERS INTO FORMAL RETAIL SUPPLY CHAINS SOURCING READINESS CHECKLIST 2016

U.S. Agriculture and International Trade

Microfinance and the growth of small-scale agribusinesses in Malawi

How to Influence EU Public Opinion about Agricultural Biotechnology

THE ROLE OF VET IN FACILITATING DEVELOPMENT OF AGRICULTURAL SECTOR IN TANZANIA

Transcription:

Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Faculty of Bioscience Engineering Working Paper 2006 / 94 MANUAL ON COCOA MARKET INFORMATION SYSTEMS BASED ON EXPERIENCES IN NIGERIA, CAMEROON AND CÔTE D IVOIRE Eric TOLLENS October 2006 Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project, Component 2: Development of an information system for cocoa production and marketing. This paper (pdf) can be downloaded following the link: http://www.biw.kuleuven.be/aee/clo/wp/tollens2006a.pdf Financing: CFC-ICCO-Governments of Nigeria, Cameroon and Côte d Ivoire Management: UNOPS, Dakar Centre for Agricultural and Food Economics Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Willem de Croylaan 42, B-3001 Leuven Belgium Tel. +32-16-321614, Fax +32-16-321996

Tollens, E. "Manual on cocoa market information systems based on experiences in Nigeria, Cameroon and Côte d Ivoire." Working Paper, n 94, Centre for Agricultural and Food Economics, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, 2006. Prof. Eric Tollens, Centre for Agricultural and Food Economics, K.U.Leuven, de Croylaan 42, B-3001 Leuven (Heverlee), Belgium Phone: +32 16 32 16 16, Fax: +32 16 32 19 96, eric.tollens@biw.kuleuven.be Copyright 2006 by Eric Tollens. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies. 2

Abstract A performing market information system (MIS) is a key accompanying measure to market liberalization. This manual discusses the objectives and purposes of a MIS, its ideal characteristics and its concept and implementation, based on experiences with the cocoa and coffee MIS set up and presently operating in three liberalized African export commodity markets. A phased approach is suggested, with each phase being well defined and launched sequentially. The timing and location of the MIS unit, the dissemination strategy and the financing are discussed. An appropriate dissemination strategy is of vital importance to reach all intended beneficiaries. The success or failure of a MIS hinges on a successful dissemination strategy. Sustainable financing is best based on a specific levy at export. Finally, suggestions are given for a performing MIS. In the presentation, examples will be shown from the operation of the MIS in the three countries. Keywords: cocoa, coffee, market information system, market liberalization, West Africa 3

Introduction Most sub-sahara African countries have liberalized their export commodity subsectors as a result of structural adjustment policies and economic liberalization. This concerns in particular cocoa and coffee, the focus of this paper, but also cotton in certain countries (Côte d'ivoire) and other export cops. Market liberalization is the most important change in many tropical agricultural commodities over the past decade. Historically, internal markets, particularly in many African countries were regulated by marketing board or 'caisse de stabilisation' mechanisms, with the overt purpose of reducing the variability of farm prices. In certain instances, these schemes enjoyed a measure of success, particularly where the macroeconomic environment was one of stable exchange rates, but more usually they served as taxation mechanisms (Knudsen and Nash, 1990) (Gilbert, 1998). Often, the intervention organizations ended up insolvent and, partly through domestic and partly through donor pressure, they have been either abolished or stripped of their powers. At the same time, all the limited number of economically interventionist international commodity agreements (ICAs) which had the objective of smoothing international price variability, have either collapsed or seen their economic clauses lapse (Gilbert, 1996). Liberalization was often promoted by multilateral and national aid agencies, in particular the World Bank, the European Union (EU) and USAID, but were also in certain cases instigated solely by national governments. These programmes were motivated by a number of distinct concerns, including (Tollens and Gilbert, 2002): to reduce the absorption of resources by parastatal intervention agencies; to increase the efficiency of commodity marketing; 4

to raise prices received by farmers and hence to stimulate increased levels of production; to promote the development of modern agribusiness industries. These objectives have been met with varying degrees of success, but at the same time, a number of problems have emerged. Among these is the concern that market liberalization may result in less transparent marketing and loss of market power by farmers. The need for a performing market information system (MIS) then comes up. This manual focuses on three African countries with substantial cocoa-coffee subsectors which have liberalized their markets, Nigeria already in 1986, Cameroon in 1992 for arabica coffee and in 1994 for robusta coffee and cocoa, and Côte d'ivoire in 1998 for coffee and in 1999 for cocoa. Nigeria only started a MIS for cocoa (CMIS-Cocoa Marketing Information System) in 2002 in the framework of the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project 1. Coffee is not important in Nigeria. Cameroon had an Arabica Marketing Information System (AMIS) operational in 1993, which was expanded to include robusta coffee and cocoa in 1994 (CRAMIS/ Cocoa, Robusta and Arabica Marketing Information System), and which was discontinued in 1996 for lack of funding. It was relaunched in 2001-2002 as SIF (Système d'information des Filières Cacao et Café) in the framework of the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project. Côte d'ivoire initiated a Coffee and Cocoa MIS in 1998 at the start of the coffee market liberalization, called PRIMAC (Programme d'information sur les Marchés du Café et du Cacao), under the responsibility of the Nouvelle Caistab. And PRIMAC continued after the Nouvelle 1 A Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project is currently in operation in the three countries, financed by the International Cocoa Organization (ICCO), the Common Fund for Commodities (CFC), and the respective countries 5

Caistab was terminated and a new market management structure, BCC (Bourse du Café et du Cacao), set up. The market information component is an essential element of the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project. The general objective is to achieve that markets function efficiently, what is only possible with full and equal access of all market participants to all relevant market information. The author of this paper was a MIS consultant in this project and has worked on MIS in other African countries. The main aim of the manual is to analyze the concept and implementation of a MIS, to discuss experiences in the three countries, and to provide suggestions for the successful launching and operation of a performing MIS for export commodities. Objectives and purposes of a market information system The main objective of a public Market Information System is to enhance competition in the market by increasing market transparency for all market participants, and in particular the weakest who are smallholder farmers. Thus, a MIS means empowerment of farmers by strengthening their bargaining power in order to increase their share of the export proceeds of their produce. Market transparency is a condition for effective competition and good marketing performance in liberalized markets. It can be defined as the degree of information that farmers, cooperatives, traders, exporters and market control institutions, including the government, have about parameters relevant to their decision making. Adequate knowledge of prevailing prices, quantities, qualities and conditions of sale in the markets are indispensable for rational production and marketing decisions (Shepherd, 1997). 6

From the farmer's point of view, market transparency allows them to adjust their production and consumption decisions, to derive the proper incentives from the market and to adjust their sales strategy in order to maximize their welfare. From a macro-economic point of view, market transparency allows vertical coordination in the marketing chain whereby price signals play their proper role in adjusting production and consumption such that maximum efficiency is attained and overall welfare is optimized. This results in maximum economic growth in the economy. Transparency in agricultural markets results in the following effects: - the farmers receive the proper production incentives, will adjust their production accordingly and will seize on market opportunities; - information can improve the bargaining position of the weaker participants in a marketing system who are usually the smallholder farmers; - competition is enhanced in markets, resulting in fair prices for all participants; - market information signals profit opportunities and thus creates incentives for market participants; - seasonal and erratic price variations will be reduced and arbitrage between markets will take place, thereby reducing price differentials between markets. In completely transparent and efficient markets, price differentials reflect only transaction costs (mainly transport costs) between markets; - overall risk is reduced for all market participants, resulting in more stable markets, improved long term planning and investment decisions; - improved government regulation of markets: better agricultural and marketing policies and public investments as the government will be adequately informed about market conditions and performance. 7

Characteristics of a performing market information system A performing MIS serves the information system needs of the market participants or target group. One of the main target groups are the smallholder farmers and their cooperatives. To this could be added small scale traders and emerging traders which have information needs very similar to those of the farmers as they also lack bargaining power vis-à-vis large scale established traders and exporters which have their own private MIS. Cooperatives and their unions also may belong to this target group. In order to render markets transparent and fulfill the information needs of the main target group, market information must be: - relevant, i.e. its content must be related to the information needs of the target group taking into consideration the local conditions; - meaningful, i.e. precisely specified with regard to location, time and other features and formulated in a way which can be easily understood, i.e. local language; - reliable and impartial, i.e. accurate, without bias or pressure group (lobby) influence and regularly collected and transmitted; - promptly available, i.e. timely for commercial transactions, and up to date. Particularly price information is considered a perishable commodity as its value erodes over time. Up-to-datedness is very important implying a weekly or biweekly updating; - easily accessible, i.e. public market information is a public good which must be accessible by everybody who wants it. In this respect, the radio will be the preferred mode of dissemination as radios are available in every village. For the same reason, TV and newspapers are ruled out as the main mode of diffusion although they can be used as a secondary mode; 8

- simple, i.e. there are a lot of advantages in a simple system. It can be more easily understood by the farmers and it will be cheaper and thus be more cost effective. Keeping it simple and cost effective will be a major consideration. Reliability, neutrality, impartiality and simplicity are stressed in particular. The target group - farmers and their cooperatives - must have confidence and trust in the message and in the institution collecting and diffusing the information. The "public good" nature of public marketing information implies that everybody can have access to it and that everybody can be a "free rider". This is a strong argument for public involvement with this service, although this does not necessarily imply that the State needs to perform this service or pay for it. As a lot of cocoa and coffee are exported, a small tax or levy on the export can easily pay for the service. The ultimate measure of performance is that farmers that make use of the MIS will obtain higher market prices for their produce than other farmers. Also, market prices will be more stable, markets will be better integrated with less price differences between areas and overall transaction costs in the sub sectors will have decreased. The liberalized produce market will have a competitive character and all market participants will receive a fair and equitable share of the export proceeds and the local produce use value. The concept and implementation of a performing Cocoa and Coffee Market Information System The concept of MIS In order to facilitate the start-up and operation of the MIS, it is important to keep it simple, but also regular and reliable. A phased approach is recommended to facilitate the operation of the system. Three phases are suggested: 9

Phase 1: external market information collected daily and disseminated via the media. This concerns mainly the London CIF price for standard cocoa and robusta traded at LIFFE, and the New York "C" Arabica price traded at the New York Coffee, Sugar and Cocoa Exchange. Later on, futures prices - 3 months and 6 months ahead - can be added. The LIFFE market at London is indicated for cocoa and robusta as this is the main market for these products; New York is indicated for Arabica as that is the major market for that product. The daily price should be converted to local currency using the official exchange rate, and the used exchanged rate should always be indicated. From the daily price (CIF), the main port of export FOB price can be derived easily by deducting the CIF costs which comprise: - sea freight costs export port - northern Europe (or New York) - maritime insurance - financing costs - product losses during sea transport ("freintes") The CIF costs can be determined once a month, and every month, by consulting a minimum of three shippers/forwarders in the port of export (transit/shipping agencies) and taking the simple average. The export port FOB price has the advantage of being closer to farmers than the London or New York price. In principle, freight costs should follow the % distribution sacks/bulk appropriate for the particular product, but this distribution is usually not known. It is thus suggested that freight costs be recorded are those for sacks. Only when over half of exports occur in bulk (containers) should bulk freight costs be taken. 10

To start Phase 1, only the CIF daily price in local currency can be taken - later on, the local export port FOB price can be added, and at an even later stage, the futures prices and a break down of market prices into related prices receivable at lower levels of the marketing chain. Such a breakdown reflects the link between world market prices and local price formation. Particularly truly fixed costs in the marketing chain, such as taxes and levies, can be deducted from the export price in order to come closer to the farmer paid price. As there is usually a differential for each origin, a correction for "origin" needs to be applied for the FOB export port price. The differential relates to quality and other characteristics of the origin as against the term, in particular good business practices and abiding by contractual obligations. Quality of coffee is more easy to determine (assess defective coffee beans) than cocoa where a proper cut test is necessary. Whenever there is an origin differential, positive or negative, it should be applied to the FOB export port price, which is derived from the London or New York CIF daily prices. It is however not easy to determine the origin differential, as the trade representatives need to be consulted on this. LIFFE or New York data can also indicate the differential, but it is often speculative and refers to futures market operations only (hedging, speculation). 11

Phase 2 2 : internal market information, in particular the prices received (farm gate) by cocoa and coffee farmers for each particular grade. Such prices need to be collected weekly, in the most important producing areas. In each area, ideally two or three collaborating institutions such as cooperatives or farmer's organizations, or their representatives, NGOs or other institutions should collect weekly prices paid to farmers and transmit that information to the central MIS office. The prices collected should be in the form of a minimum-maximum range, with the range not being too broad, and the average price. It is important that the prices collected are representative of the prices paid (to farmers) prevailing at that week in the area. Pure statistical representativeness based on random sampling is not always required, as this may be too expensive. Rather, purposive sampling or sampling of preferred witnesses should be pursued. In addition, one needs to avoid asking buyers and traders for the prices paid to farmers, as they have no incentive to communicate the correct prices that are actually paid. Experience shows that there is often a difference between the prices buyers say they are paying, and the prices actually paid. Often, buyers collude to offer the same buying price but in the end are prepared to pay a higher price. Moreover, prices need to be per kg weight, not per bag of unspecified weight converted to a 2 In Cameroon, in 1993-1994, a Phase 2 AMIS was launched with the aim to disseminate producer prices being offered by arabica coffee buyers. The cooperatives duly submitted their offering prices, which differed from cooperative to cooperative, but the private sector buyers got together and decided, in perfect collusion, to give one equal offering price for all. In practice, they all paid different prices but the collusion in announcing only one offering price went against the principles of economic liberalization. It was therefore decided not to repeat this experience and this type of Phase 2 was thus scrapped and replaced by an observation of buying prices actually paid to growers. 12

standard weight per bag. In this respect, it may be necessary to distribute some weighing scales to the collaborating institutions. The price range (minimum-maximum) is important because prices vary in an area, even for the same grade and, for instance, cooperatives which are financed from an exporter, as is often the case, usually have to accept the price "dictated" by the exporter, which is normally somewhat lower than the price paid by a buyer who pays on the spot "cash-against-produce". In addition, the range of prices conveys the message that prices are negotiable and variable, and follow international market swings. These points of transmission of prices need to be equipped with a fax machine or the Internet, the budget allowing. It is important to keep in mind that the communication equipment (fax, PC-Internet) will work two-ways, i.e. to send market information to the central office, and to receive MIS bulletins. Thus, they will also serve as privileged dissemination points (see further: dissemination strategy). Phase 3: MIS moves towards a fully web-based strategy and adds to its website other information besides price information. Such information could include: - production data per area - structure of plantations: age of cocoa and coffee groves and area of new plantings - tonnage of local processing of cocoa and coffee, domestic consumption, and exports - statistics from the Produce Quality Inspection Services - a list of registered warehouses and warehouse stocks (quantity, quality, date of storage) in the system of structured trade financing. Information on stocks in the country is of vital importance in the price formation process. 13

The MIS website should have links to collaborating, affiliated or other organizations with which it has contacts regularly. A web-based strategy also implies that most of the data collected in the field is transmitted to the central MIS office via the web, and that most of the dissemination of information also occurs via the web. The strategy thus also depends on the development of the Internet in the country. In Côte d'ivoire, a web based strategy has been adopted and is now being gradually implemented. Timing A phased approach is indicated in order to plan well ahead and to have an orderly implementation. Each new phase should start at the beginning of the main produce marketing season. Phase 3 can only start when the Internet is fully operational and when sufficient budget is available to pay for all hardware and software requirements. Location of the central MIS unit At the start of a MIS project, the government or the national parastatal body in charge of cocoa and coffee usually houses the unit. This may inspire confidence in the system and will facilitate the setting-up and launching. But once fully operational and performing, there may be benefit in spinning it off to a trade association or private entity, with a Ministry or parastatal body still in a supervisory role. For an organization such as a trade association to operate the MIS satisfactorily, it will require adequate staffing, financing, and budgetary/administrative autonomy of the unit running CMIS. This is necessary to shield the unit from any undue influence possibly exercised by members of the trade (exporters, buyers, banks, processors ). Experience shows that in particular the exporters and/or processors may exert undue 14

influence on a MIS. This was notably the case in Cameroon ("C RAMIS is killing us" was often heard). There is always the tendency to turn in to their competitive advantage. In Cameroon, the National Cocoa and Coffee Board (NCCB) operated AMIS and SIMARC-CRAMIS. Presently, SIF is run from the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project with the collaboration of the NCCB. It is intended that SIF becomes an independent, autonomous body when the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project ends. In Côte d'ivoire, PRIMAC was set up by the Nouvelle Caistab, a parastatal organization, and is now run by BCC, in principle a private entity where all participants in the cocoa-coffee trade are represented, under the supervision of ARCC (Autorité de Régulation du Café et du Cacao), the governmental regulatory body for cocoa-coffee. In Nigeria, the Federal Ministry of Commerce at Abuja - Commodity Department - initiated and runs the CMIS (Cocoa Market Information System), in good collaboration with the Cocoa Association of Nigeria at Akure which will maybe take responsibility for it at a later stage. Dissemination strategy Means of dissemination Adequate collection and processing of market information, in particular prices, is of no use if the intended clients/beneficiaries or target group has no access to the information. This is why an appropriate dissemination of diffusion strategy is vital and of paramount importance. Thousands of cocoa and coffee farmers need to be reached and this is a huge challenge. The success or failure of a MIS hinges on a successful dissemination strategy. 15

As a large number of clients need to be reached, on a regular basis, the mass media need to be relied on. The press should not be relied on as the main vehicle of dissemination. Many farmers do not read newspapers, or if they do, it is irregularly. Still, the press may be important to reach buyers, cooperatives, middlemen, etc.. Experience has shown that the rural or local radio, in local language, is the most effective means of reaching farmers as almost all of them listen to the radio on a daily basis. This was notably the case in Cameroon with AMIS and SIMARC- CRAMIS which was diffused by the radio in six local languages in the West province and 26 in the North-West province in addition to pidgin. In the case of Nigeria, this means relying on State radio (more than national radio) and emerging local private radios. In Cameroon and Côte d'ivoire, the provincial radios are most important. Ideally, the provincial or State Radio should broadcast the MIS information in local language in short messages, one minute duration, but repeated several times a day. If only a weekly broadcast is done on a fixed day, for budgetary reasons, then the message still needs to be repeated at least several times a day and in the most important cocoa and coffee areas. In Cameroon, the main dissemination strategy is now via mobile telephone (GSM) with the SMS service (Short Messaging Service). Everyday, the London cocoa and Robusta prices, and the derived FOB Douala prices are disseminated via a short message, either on a regular subscription basis or on a call basis via a dedicated call number. This requires that the GSM covers most of the rural cocoa and coffee growing areas, which is already the case in Cameroon, and to some extent in western Nigeria, because of the high rural population density, but not yet in Côte d'ivoire. One particular advantage of this system is that the proceeds from the GSM system are shared between the mobile phone operators, the SMS intermediary service company 16

and the content provider, i.e. the MIS institution. This thus contributes to the financial sustainability of the MIS institution. In Côte d'ivoire, where a web based diffusion strategy is pursued, ten key cocoa cooperatives have been equipped with computers and internet access and the necessary training has also been provided. They can consult the PRIMAC (MIS) website at any time and obtain the needed information, which they can then further disseminate to their cooperative members via leaflets and information boards at warehouses and collection centers in villages. At the same time, the collection of relevant data in the rural areas will be done by ANADER (the National Agricultural Extension System) and the transmission of the data to the central PRIMAC unit in Abidjan will also be done via the web. Finally, television coverage (one minute broadcast) on a regular basis, once weekly, may also be a cost-effective instrument to reach large numbers of interested persons. The television is used in Nigeria, Cameroon and Côte d Ivoire for this purpose. A budget has to be foreseen for dissemination. Almost all of the media require payment for regular diffusion of messages of commercial interest, even if they are in the national interest. Also, experience has shown that regular service against payment is best, because then only can regular performance be assured. Thus, a budget must be made available for the dissemination strategy to work. Types of dissemination bulletins and frequency Two types of bulletins need to be prepared: a daily (working day) bulletin with Phase 1 information: the London or New York CIF daily price, in local currency, to be complemented (later) by a derived FOB 17

daily export port price. The used official exchange rate must be listed. This bulletin is small, not necessarily larger than a business card. This bulletin only contains Phase 1 information. a weekly bulletin, for distribution once every week on a fixed day, e.g. every Friday. It will contain Phase 1 + Phase 2 information, i.e. in addition to the information of the daily bulletin, the once weekly prices paid (range) to the farmers in the main producing areas. This bulletin will be about 1/3 to half a page A4. In the annex, an example of the dissemination bulletins for the press used in Nigeria, Cameroon and Côte d Ivoire are given. Only Nigeria and Côte d Ivoire have a weekly bulletin with Phase 2 type information. The daily and weekly bulletins should ideally be included in the listed newspapers and be read on provincial or State radio. In Cameroon, the daily bulletin is available through the cellular mobile phone SMS service. The weekly bulletin could be included on national TV, once a week, after the main news, as a rolling news bulletin - one minute duration but this will cost money and may not be feasible. The weekly bulletin should also be sent out by fax or email to the collaborating organizations and to anybody who requests it. In addition, it is suggested that the daily and weekly bulletins are read on an automatic reply telephone number, accessible by national telephone and mobile cellular telephone in local languages. If dissemination of the daily bulletin through the press proves too expensive, then a once weekly schedule should be adopted. In Côte d Ivoire, the daily and weekly bulletins are included in the BCC PRIMAC website at www.bcc.ci or www.primac.ci. 18

Financing of the MIS Financing of the dissemination strategy should be viewed in the context of the sustainability of the MIS. Sustainable financing will be problematic as long as income is not assured in an automatic, regular way. A small levy at export for MIS appears to be the most attractive proposition. In Cameroon, it was estimated that the MIS will require annually about $ 120.000 or about 1 F.CFA/kg coca and coffee exported. This includes everything, office rent, salaries of all personnel, dissemination, etc. In addition, a start-up once-only budget was required for equipment of $ 130.000. It is not known how much the MIS costs in Côte d'ivoire and Nigeria. In Côte d'ivoire, BCC operates the system on its own resources based on a levy at export. In Nigeria, the Federal Ministry of Commerce pays the operation from its federal budget while in Cameroon, financing is a recurring problem and the major constraint. It is now foreseen that a specific MIS levy will be introduced after the new cocoa and coffee marketing law is passed. Minimal reliance on recurrent government budgets or on donor financing is best to ensure sustainable financing of the system. Autonomy of the MIS unit Usually, the MIS unit is located in a governmental or parastatal organization or private organization directly supervised by a government body. In Nigeria, the MIS unit is located in the Federal Ministry of Commerce; in Cameroon, it is in the National Cocoa and Coffee Board, where also the Cocoa Marketing Improvement Project is located; in Côte d'ivoire, in BCC, a private company, but created by the government (represented by ARCC) and charged with a public role, the defense of the interests of the cocoa and coffee sector. The MIS unit needs to be impartial, objective and inspire trust. It should be free from influence by policy makers, traders, exporters, 19

cooperatives, etc. It needs to provide a public service function, respond to needs an operate efficiently and in a timely manner. For all these reasons, experience shows that it is best to set up the unit as an autonomous body, with its own budget and staff, a flexible organization, shielded from politics and influence peddling. This implies that the unit has a head of unit, some permanent core staff, an annually approved budget, an annual plan of work and full accountability for its actions and accounts. This proves to be rather difficult as the institutions wherein the MIS unit is located usually want to maintain full control over the unit. They realize that market information is market power and influence, which is not easily given up. Suggestions and Conclusions Suggestions Based on the experiences in the three countries, suggestions are made in order to launch and implement a MIS and make it performing. 1. It is suggested to adopt a phased approach to the implementation of a MIS. 2. The dissemination strategy is crucial for the success of the MIS. A specific budget must be available for the dissemination strategy. 3. For the dissemination, agreements need to be drawn up with the media partners: press, radio and television and mobile phone companies. The public service role of MIS should be stressed in order to attract favorable advertising rates for the placement of the MIS bulletins. In any case, payment - against - performance must be the norm. One can start with a weekly frequency but in order to be really effective, daily frequency is needed for external market information. It is suggested that the dissemination be closely monitored, and that after an initial 20

one-two years of operation, a dissemination impact survey be held with cocoa and coffee farmers in the major cocoa producing States or areas. 4. It is suggested to closely collaborate with the trade association for the launching and operation of a MIS. They are potentially an institution that could take over the running of the MIS. But to start with, they should be a privileged collaborating institution for the collection and dissemination of the market information. 5. It is suggested that the MIS unit elaborates a specific logo for the MIS, given MIS a proper identity and constructs a website for the MIS. Depending n the development of the Internet, Phase 3 o f MIS could start and will eventually become very important. 6. It is suggested that standardized forms be developed for MIS daily and weekly bulletins and for the collection of Phase 2 information from the collaborating institutions. 7. Once Phase 1 launched and operational, and Phase 2 planned and started on a pilot scale in one area, a training needs assessment should be made. Although a simple concept is envisioned - straightforward, training may be needed in the future, particularly as it relates to the definitions used (e.g. farm gate price use of proper weights to determine the price, the use of the PC and the Internet. Also, the proper role of a MIS in a liberalized market context may need to be exposed to the collaborating institutions. There may be a need to explain to market participants, particularly cocoa and coffee farmers and their cooperatives, the relationship between local prices, national prices, export prices and world market prices, i.e. the price formation process throughout the marketing chain. 21

8. It is suggested that the launching of a MIS, Phase 1, be accompanied by a sensibilisation campaign in the media. This could take the form of an official launching day, presented to the media by the responsible Minister, articles in the major newspapers, on radio and TV, and a sensibilisation mission to the major cooperatives in the cocoa and coffee producing areas. 9. It is suggested that the MIS unit which manages the market information collection, processing and diffusion be accorded a certain degree of management autonomy. Conclusions It is important to start a MIS, using the phased approach outlined. Once the MIS operational, improvements can be made in the concept and in the implementation. Also, the scope of the MIS can be gradually extended. The main constraint will be the dissemination strategy, for which a budget must be planned. The dissemination hinges on the collaboration of the media (press, radio, TV, GSM), for which a budget must be made available. Dissemination can start on a limited scale, with once weekly frequency. But coverage of the media, and frequency, must eventually be expanded in order to reach the cocoa and coffee producers, the principal clients of the MIS. Thus, a pragmatic, sequential and progressive approach is suggested. Once the beneficial effects of MIS become apparent, it will become easier to find funds for the financing of the system. In the end, sustainable financing must be secured for continuous operation and enduring performance of a MIS. Close contact and collaboration with the trade association will be important in order to secure harmonious development of the MIS. Undoubtedly, some members will be against, as their interests are not served by more price transparency in 22

commodity markets. It is even expected that attempts will be made to shut down the system, and one of the most effective ways of doing that is by starving it of funds. Also, the concept itself will be attacked as price information, whatever the definition of prices used, will never be perfect and will always lend itself to contest and criticism. In the end, one must recognise that a MIS is an accompanying measure to economic liberalisation, in order to create more (price) transparency and to foster price competition. Particularly small cocoa and coffee producers who are in an unfavourable bargaining position with buyers may benefit the most from it. Empowerment of their bargaining position in a liberalised market is one of the major aims. If a MIS succeeds, thousands of small cocoa and coffee producers will receive (marginally) higher prices, not a spectacular result, but important by aggregation in terms of poverty alleviation, income and welfare of smallholder families. Market information is a perishable commodity. But information is also power, and information asymmetry in primary commodity markets dominated by smallholders, as is the case in the three countries, is usually quite important, to the detriment of producers. Timely, accurate and representative market information is a powerful tool in the empowerment of farmers in a liberalized marketing system. It is hoped that cooperatives and producers organizations will become the major ally of the MIS. Their role over the years has become more and more that of local collection and bulking, and bargaining on behalf of their members with major buyers and exporters. They should seize on the opportunities created by having better market information. To the extent that they truly represent their members - they should become the major actors of the MIS, in terms of receiving and sending market information. The system cannot really succeed without their unconditional support. 23

But this has proven very difficult in the three countries, and the cooperatives in the process of liberalization have suffered a lot, victims of their unfavourable marketing cost structure. In Cameroon and Nigeria, none of the cooperatives still export directly to overseas buyers. In Côte d'ivoire, attempts are now being made to strengthen the cooperatives and to increase the small amounts they export directly. 24

References Akiyama, T. (2001), "Coffee market liberalization since 1990", in Akiyama, A., J. Baffes, D. Larson and P. Varangis eds., Commodity Market Reforms: Lessons of Two Decades, Washington, D.C., World Bank, 83-120. Gilbert, C.L. (1996), "International commodity agreements: an obituary notice", World Development, 24, 1-19. Gilbert, C.L. (1998), Cocoa Market Liberalization: Its Effects on Quality, Futures Trading and Prices, London, Cocoa Association of London. Gilbert, C.L., and E.F. Tollens (assisted by S-P. Essomba_Abanada, H. Fankman, F. Kamajou and A. Nchare) (1999) "Effets de la libéralisation dans les soussecteurs café-cacao au Cameroun", Volume 1, report for the European Commission, Vrije Universiteit, Amsterdam. Knudsen, O., and J. Nash (1990), "Domestic price stabilization schemes in developing countries", Economic Development and Cultural Change, 38, 539-58. Shepherd, Andrew W. (1997), Market Information Services - Theory and practice, FAO Agricultural Services Bulletin: 125, Rome, 58 p. Shepherd, A.W., and S. Farolfi (1999), "Export crop liberalization in Africa: a review", FAO Agricultural Services Bulletin, 135, Rome, FAO. Tollens, E., and C. Gilbert (2002), Does liberalization jeopardize export quality? Cameroonian Cocoa, 1998-2000, submitted to the Journal of African Economics. Varangis, P., and G. Schreiber (2001), "Cocoa market reforms in west Africa" in Akiyama, A., J Baffes, D. Larson and P. Varangis eds., Commodity Market Reforms: Lessons of Two Decades, Washington, D.C., World Bank, 35-82. 25

ANNEX CMIS DISSEMINATION BULLETINS IN THE PRESS IN NIGERIA, CAMEROON AND CÔTE D IVOIRE 26

Nigeria CMIS bulletin in the newspapers This Day, Punch, The Guardian 27

Cameroon CMIS bulletin in the newspapers Cameroon Tribune 28

Côte d Ivoire CMIS bulletin in nine newspapers (daily and weekly) 29

List of Available Working Papers 1. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Criteria ter evaluatie van 'duurzame landbouw', Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 35 p. 2. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van herbicide-resistente planten aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 39 p. 3. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van bovine somatotropine aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 63 p. 4. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van gemanipuleerde planten met biopesticide eigenschappen afkomstig van Bacillus thuringiensis aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 32 p. 5. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van haploide planten aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 17 p. 6. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van genetische technieken voor diagnosebepaling, immunologische technieken ter verbetering van de landbouwproduktie en transgene dieren en planten als bioreactor aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 28 p. 7. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van verbetering van de stikstoffixatie bij planten aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 17 p. 8. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van porcine somatotropine aan criteria voor duurzamelandbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, januari 1994, 29 p. 9. BEERLANDT, H. en L. DRIESEN, Evaluatie van tomaten met een langere houdbaarheid aan criteria voor duurzame landbouw, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, februari 1994, 30 p. 10. CHRISTIAENSEN, L., Voedselzekerheid: van concept tot actie: een status questionis, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, april 1994, 106 p. 11. CHRISTIAENSEN, L. and J. SWINNEN, Economic, Institutional and Political Determinants of Agricultural Production Structures in Western Europe, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, May 1994, 40 p. 12. GOOSSENS, F., Efficiency and Performance of an Informal Food Marketing System, The case of Kinshasa, Zaire, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, July 1995, 41 p. 13. GOOSSENS, F., Failing Innovation in the Zairian Cassava Production System, A comparative historical analysis, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, July 1995, 18 p. 14. TOLLENS, E., Cadre conceptuel concernant l'analyse de la performance économique des marchés, Projet-FAO "Approvisionnement et Distribution Alimentaires des Villes de l'afrique Francophone", Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, août 1995, 35 p. (Deuxième version, avril 1996, 77 p.) 15. TOLLENS, E., Les marchés de gros dans les grandes villes Africaines, diagnostic, avantages et éléments d'étude et de développement, Projet-FAO "ApprovisioMement et Distribution Alimentaires des Villes de l'afrique Francophone", Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, août 1995, 23 p. (Deuxieme version, septembre 1996, 32 p.) 16. ENGELEN, G., Inleiding tot de landbouwvoorlichting (heruitgave), Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, augustus 1995, 17 p. 17. TOLLENS, E., Agricultural Research and Development towards Sustainable Production Systems: I. Information Sources, Surveys; II. Conceptualisation of the Change Process, 30

NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 1, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, August 1995 18. TOLLENS, E., Planning and Appraising Agricultural Development programmes and Projects: I. Farm Planning; II. Aggregation, Sensitivity Analyses and Farm Investment Analysis; III. Guidelines on Informal Surveys and Data Collection, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 2, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 19. TOLLENS, E., Structural Adjustment and Agricultural Policies: I. Market Theory: the State and the Private Sector; II. Output Markets and Marketing Institutions; III. Input Markets; IV. Case Study: Cameroon, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 1, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 20. TOLLENS, E., Theory and Macro-Economic Measures of Structural Adjustment Methods of Evaluation and Linkages to the Agricultural Sector: I. Development Models and the Role of Agriculture, NATURA -NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 2, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 21. TOLLENS, E., Theory and Macro-Economic Measures of Structural Adjustment Methods of Evaluation and Linkages to the Agricultural Sector: II. Implementation of Policy Reforms: Case Study of Market Liberalisation in Cameroon for Cocoa and Coffee, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 2, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 22. TOLLENS, E., Supply Response within the Farming Systems Context: I. Input Supply and Product Markets; II. Agricultural Supply Response Assessment, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 3, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 23. GOOSSENS, F., Agricultural Marketing and Marketing Analysis: I. Agricultural Marketing Research Frameworks. II. Agricultural Market Performance Criteria and The Role of Government Intervention, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 3, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 24. GOOSSENS, F., Agricultural Marketing and Marketing Analysis: Demand Analysis, NATURA-- NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 3, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1995 25. CHRISTIAENSEN, L. en H. BEERLANDT, Belgische voedselhulp geanalyseerd met betrekking tot voedselzekerheid, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, november 1994, 15 p. 26. CHRISTIAENSEN, L. en H. BEERLANDT, De Belgische ontwikkelingssamenwerking met Rwanda geanalyseerd met betrekking tot voedselzekerheid, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, KU.Leuven, november 1995, 36 p. 27. BEERLANDT, H., Identificatie van de meest kwetsbaren in Monduli distrikt, Arusha regio, Tanzania, A.C.T.- Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, april 1995, 40 p. 28. BEERLANDT, H., TOLLENS, E. and DERCON, S., Methodology for Addressing Food Security in Development Projects, Identification of the Food Insecure and the Causes of Food Insecurity based on Experiences from the Region of Kigoma, Tanzania, Department of Agricultural Economics and Centre for Economic Research, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Leuven, December 1995, 19 p. 29. BEERLANDT, H., Koppelen van noodhulp en strukturele ontwikkelingssamenwerking: opties voor een Belgisch beleid, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, december 1995, 23 p. 30. TOLLENS, E., La crise agraire au Zaïre: pour quelle politique de développement dans la phase de transition?, Une contribution au colloque Le Zaïre en Chantier: Quels Projets de Société, Anvers, 18 février 1993, December 1995, 14 p. 31. GOOSSENS, F., Rôle des systèmes d'alimentation dans la sécurité alimentaire de Kinshasa, Une contribution au projet GCP/RAF/309, AGSM, FA0, mai 1996, 78 p. 31

32. BEERLANDT, H., DERCON, S., and SERNEELS, I., (Project co-ordinator: E. TOLLENS), Tanzania, a Food Insecure Country?, Department of Agricultural Economics, Center for Economic Research, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, September 1996, 68 p. 33. TOLLENS, E., Food security and nutrition 2. Case study from Tanzania, Nectar Programme, Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms, module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Septembre 1996, 47 p. 34. BEERLANDT, H., en SERNEELS, J., Voedselzekerheid in de regio Kigoma, Tanzania, Afdeling Landbouweconomie en Centrum voor Economische Studiën, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, september 1996, 45 p. 35. BEERLANDT, H., Identificatie van verifieerbare indicatoren ter toetsing van de voedselzekerheidssituatie in de regio Arusha, Tanzania, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, november 1996, 60 p. 36. GOOSSENS, F., Commercialisation des vivres locaux en Afrique Subsaharienne, le secteur informel dans un perspectif dynamique, Une contribution au projet GCP/RAF/309, AGSM, FAO, novembre 1996, 58 p. 37. GOOSSENS, F., The Economics of Livestock Systems: I. Marketing Problems and Channels of Livestock in Subsahara Africa, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, November 1996. 38. GOOSSENS, F., The Economics of Livestock Systems: II. Price Stabilization in the Livestock Sector, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development", module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, November 1996. 39. GOOSSENS, F., The Economics of Livestock Systems: III. Consumer Demand for Livestock Products, NATURA -NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, November 1996. 40. JASPERS, N., I. La Seguridad Alimenticia en el departamento de Quiché: Identificación e Impacto del Programa de Créditos, II. Informe Sobre Estudio Seguridad Alimenticia, ACT - Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, November 1996, 39 p. 41. TOLLENS, E., Social indicators with an illustration from Thailand, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, January 1997, 38 p. 42. BEERLANDT, H., en SERNEELS, J., Handleiding voor een voedselzekerheidsdiagnose, Afdeling Landbouweconomie en Centrum voor Economische Studiën, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, februari 1997, 131 p. 43. BEERLANDT, H., and SERNEELS, J., Manual for a Food Security Diagnosis, Department of Agricultural Economics and Center for Economic Research, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, March 1997, 125 p. 44. GOOSSENS, F., Aangepaste vormen van samenwerking als hefboom voor de sociaal-economische promotie van boeren in het zuiden - algemene conclusies, Seminarie georganizeerd door Ieder Voor Allen, Brussel, 17-18 maart 1997, 8 p. 45. GOOSSENS, F., Commercialisation des vivres locaux en Afrique Subsaharienne - neuf études de cas, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Mai 1997, 50 p. 46. BEERLANDT, H., en SERNEELS, J., Food Security in the Kigoma Region of Tanzania, Department of Agricultural Economics and Center for Economic Research, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, May 1997, 42 p. 47. BEERLANDT, H., and SERNEELS, J., Manuel Pour un Diagnostic de Securité Alimentaire, Département d Economie Agricole et le Centre d Etudes Economiques, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Juillet 1997, 134 p. 48. GOOSSENS, F., Rural Services and Infrastructure - Marketing Institutions, NATURA-NECTAR course: "Agricultural Economics and Policy Reforms", module 4, Afdeling Landbouweconomie, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, June 1997, 20 p. 32