IV. The Solow Growth Model (continued)

Similar documents
CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I

Chapter 7: Economic Growth part 1

Long Run Growth Solow s Neoclassical Growth Model

Chapters 7 and 8 Solow Growth Model Basics

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

The Solow Growth Model (and a look ahead)

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

The Solow Model. Savings and Leakages from Per Capita Capital. (n+d)k. sk^alpha. k*: steady state Per Capita Capital, k

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Economic Growth. Chapter 11

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

19 : Theory of Production

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT

Economic Growth: Lectures 6 and 7, Neoclassical Growth

5.4 Solving Percent Problems Using the Percent Equation

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3: The Solow Growth Model

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Real Business Cycle Models

Finance Solutions to Problem Set #3. Year Real GDP Real Capital Employment

Sample Midterm Solutions

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

The Real Business Cycle Model

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

4. In the Solow model with technological progress, the steady state growth rate of total output is: A) 0. B) g. C) n. D) n + g.

The previous chapter introduced a number of basic facts and posed the main questions

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

The Real Business Cycle model

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect?

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

INTRODUCTION TO ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS Preliminary Exam with answers September 2014

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

University of Saskatchewan Department of Economics Economics Homework #1

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Lecture 1: OLG Models

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Constrained optimization.

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Long-Term Debt Pricing and Monetary Policy Transmission under Imperfect Knowledge

Supply, Demand, Equilibrium, and Elasticity

5 Systems of Equations

SHORT-RUN FLUCTUATIONS. David Romer. University of California, Berkeley. First version: August 1999 This revision: January 2012

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Education and Economic Growth

The Baby Boom and Economic Growth. Peter S. Yoo

TAXATION AND SAVINGS. Robin Boadway Queen s University Kingston, Canada. Day Six

Figure 1: Real GDP in the United States

Economic Growth: Theory and Empirics (2012) Problem set I

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Introduction to the Economic Growth course

Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation.

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Advanced Macroeconomics (ECON 402) Lecture 8 Real Business Cycle Theory

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

A Model of the Current Account

Real Business Cycle Models

Problem 1. Steady state values for two countries with different savings rates and population growth rates.

Technology and Economic Growth

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Charles I. Jones Maroeconomics Economic Crisis Update (2010 års upplaga) Kurs 407 Makroekonomi och ekonomisk- politisk analys

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

Graduate Macroeconomics 2

Sources of U.S. Economic Growth in a World of Ideas

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

The Graphical Method: An Example

E-322 Muhammad Rahman. Chapter 7: Part 2. Subbing (5) into (2): H b(1. capital is denoted as: 1

GDP: The market value of final goods and services, newly produced WITHIN a nation during a fixed period.

Real Business Cycle Theory

Noah Williams Economics 312. University of Wisconsin Spring Midterm Examination Solutions

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

e) Permanent changes in monetary and fiscal policies (assume now long run price flexibility)

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Investment

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

Money and Capital in an OLG Model

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Money and Public Finance

Chapter 4 Technological Progress and Economic Growth

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory

Money. 1 What is money? Spring functions of money: Store of value Unit of account Medium of exchange

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

ECON Elements of Economic Analysis IV. Problem Set 1

CONVERGENCE ACROSS COUNTRIES AND REGIONS: THEORY AND EMPIRICS. Angel de la Fuente* D November 2002

Transcription:

IV. The Solow Growth Model (continued) (III) Shocks and Policies The Solow model can be interpreted also as a primitive Real Business Cycle (RBC) model. We can use the model to predict the response of the economy to productivity or taste shocks, or to shocks in government policies. Productivity (or Taste) Shocks Suppose output is given by or in intensive form Y t = A t F (K t, L t ) y t = A t f(k t ) where A t denotes total factor productivity. Consider a permanent negative shock in productivity. The G(k) and γ(k) functions shift down, as illustrated in Figure 4. The new steady state is lower. The economy transits slowly from the old steady state to the new. If instead the shock is transitory, the shift in G(k) and γ(k) is also temporary. Initially, capital and output fall towards the ow steady state. But when productivity reverts to the initial level, capital and output start to grow back towards the old high steady state. The effect of a productivity shock on k t and y t is illustrated in Figure 5. The solid lines correspond to a transitory shock, the dashed lines correspond to a permanent shock. Unproductive Government Spending Let us now introduce a government in the competitive market economy. The government spends resources without contributing to production or capital accumulation. 1

The resource constraint of the economy now becomes c t + i t + g t = y t = f(k t ), where g t denotes government consumption. It follows that the dynamics of capital are given by k t+1 k t = f(k t ) (δ + n)k t c t g t. Government spending is financed with proportional income taxation, at rate τ 0. The government thus absorbs a fraction τ of aggregate output: g t = τy t. Disposable income for the representative household is (1 τ)y t. We continue to assume that consumption and ivestment absorb fractions 1 s and s of disposable income: c t = (1 s)(y t g t ) i t = s(y t g t ). Combining the above, we conclude that the dynamics of capital are now given by γ t = k t+1 k t k t = s(1 τ)φ(k t ) (δ + n). where φ(k) f(k)/k. Given s and k t, the growth rate γ t decreases with τ. A steady state exists for any τ [0, 1) and is given by ( ) δ + n k = φ 1. s(1 τ) Given s, k decreases with τ. Productive Government Spending Suppose now that the production is given by y t = f(k t, g t ) = k α t g β t, 2

where α > 0, β > 0, and α + β < 1. Government spending can thus be interpreted as infrastructure or other productive services. The resources constraint is c t + i t + g t = y t = f(k t, g t ). We assume again that government spending is financed with proportional income taxation at rate τ, and that private consumption and investment are fractions 1 s and s of disposable household income: g t = τy t c t = (1 s)(y t g t ) i t = s(y t g t ). Substituting g t = τy t into y t = k α t g β t and solving for y t, we infer y t = k α where a α/(1 β) and b β/(1 β). 1 β t τ β 1 β k a t τ b We conclude that the growth rate is given by γ t = k t+1 k t k t = s(1 τ)τ b k a 1 t (δ + n). The steady state is ( ) s(1 τ)τ k b 1/(1 α) =. δ + n Consider the rate τ that maximizes either k, or γ t for any given k t. This is given by d dτ [(1 τ)τ b ] = 0 bτ b 1 (1 + b)τ b = 0 τ = b/(1 + b) = β. That is, the growth-maximization τ equals the elasticity of production with respect to government services. optimal provision. The more productive government services are, the higher their 3

(IV) Continuous Time and Convergence Rate The Solow Model in Continuous Time Recall that the basic growth equation in the discrete-time Solow model is k t+1 k t k t = γ(k t ) sφ(k t ) (δ + n). We would expect a similar condition to hold under continuous time. below. We verify this The resource constraint of the economy is C + I = Y = F (K, L). In per-capita terms, c + i = y = f(k). Population growth is now given by L L = n and the law of motion for aggregate capital is K = I δk. Let k K/L. Then, Substituting from the above, we infer k k = K K L L. k = i (δ + n)k. Combining this with we conclude i = sy = sf(k), k = sf(k) (δ + n)k. 4

Equivalently, the growth rate of the economy is given by k k = γ(k) sφ(k) (δ + n). (1) The function γ(k) thus gives the growth rate of the economy in the Solow model, whether time is discrete or continuous. Log-linearization and the Convergence Rate Define z ln k ln k. We can rewrite the growth equation (1) as ż = Γ(z), where Γ(z) γ(k e z ) sφ(k e z ) (δ + n). Note that Γ(z) is defined for all z R. By definition of k, Γ(0) = sφ(k ) (δ + n) = 0. Similarly, Γ(z) > 0 for all z < 0, Γ(z) < 0 for all z > 0. Finally, Γ (z) = sφ (k e z )k e z < 0 for all z R. We next (log)linearize ż = Γ(z) around z = 0 (first-order Taylor-series approximation of Γ(z) around z = 0): ż = Γ(0) + Γ (0) z or equivalently ż = λz where we substituted Γ(0) = 0 and let λ Γ (0). Straightforward algebra gives Γ (z) = sφ (k e z )k e z < 0 φ (k) = f [ (k)k f(k) = 1 f ] (k)k f(k) k 2 f(k) k 2 sf(k ) = (δ + n)k We infer Γ (0) = (1 ε K )(δ + n) < 0 5

where ε K F K K/F = f (k)k/f(k) is the elasticity of production with respect to capital, evaluated at the steady-state k. We conclude that where ( ) k k k = λ ln k λ = (1 ε K )(δ + n) < 0. The quantity λ is called the convergence rate. In the Cobb-Douglas case, y = k α, the convergence rate is simply λ = (1 α)(δ + n), where α is the capital income share. Note that as λ 0 as α 1. That is, convergence becomes slower and slower as the capital income share becomes closer and closer to 1. Indeed, if it were α = 1, the economy would be on a balanced growth path. Note that, around the steady state It follows that ẏ y = ε K k k and ln ( ) ẏ y y = λ ln. y ( ) ( ) y k = ε y K ln. k Thus, λ is the convergence rate for either capital or output. In the example with productive government spending, y = k α g β = k α/(1 β) τ β/(1 β), we get ( λ = 1 α ) (δ + n) 1 β The convergence rate thus decreases with β, the productivity of government services. And λ 0 as β 1 α. Calibration: If α = 35%, n = 3% (=1% population growth +2% exogenous technological process), and δ = 5%, then λ = 5.2%. This contradicts the data. But if α = 70%, then λ = 2.4%, which matches the data. 6

(V) The Golden Rule and Dynamic Inefficiency The Golden Rule: Consumption at the steady state is given by c = (1 s)f(k ) = f(k ) (δ + n)k Suppose the social planner chooses s so as to maximize c. Since k is a monotonic function of s, this is equivalent to choosing k so as to maximize c. Note that c = f(k ) (δ + n)k is strictly concave in k. The FOC is thus both necessary and sufficient. c is thus maximized if and only if k = k gold, where k gold solves f (k gold ) δ = n. Equivalently, s = s gold, where s gold solves s gold φ(k gold ) = (δ + n). The above is called the golden rule for savings, after Phelps. Dynamic Inefficiency: If s > s gold (equivalently, k > k gold ), the economy is dynamically inefficient: If the saving rate is lowered to s = s gold for all t, then consumption in all periods will be higher! On the other hand, if s < s gold (equivalently, k < k gold ), then raising s towards s gold will increase consumption in the long run, but at the cost of lower consumption in the short run. Whether such a trade-off between short-run and long-run consumption is desirable will depend on how the social planner weight the short run versus the long run. (VI) Cross-Country Differences The Solow model implies that steady-state capital, productivity, and income are determined primarily by technology (f and δ), the national saving rate (s), and population growth (n). 7

Suppose that countries share the same technology in the long run, but differ in terns of saving behavior and fertility rates. If the Solow model is correct, observed cross-country income and productivity differences should be explained by observed cross-country differences in s and n. Mankiw, Romer and Weil tests this hypothesis against the data. In its simple form, the Solow model fails to predict the large cross-country dispersion of income and productivity levels. Mankiw, Romer and Weil then consider an extension of the Solow model, that includes two types of capital, physical capital (k) and human capital (h). Output is given by y = k α h β, where α > 0, β > 0, and α + β < 1. The dynamics of capital accumulation are now given by k = s k y (δ + n)k ḣ = s h y (δ + n)h where s k and s h are the investment rates in physical capital and human capital, respectively. The steady-state levels of k, h, and y then depend on both s k and s h, as well as δ and n. Proxying s h by education attainment levels in each country, Mankiw, Romer and Weil find that the Solow model extended for human capital does a pretty good job in explaining the cross-country dispersion of output and productivity levels. 8