Coherent Measures of Risk An Exposition for the Lay Actuary by Glenn Meyers Insurance Services Office, Inc.

Similar documents
On characterization of a class of convex operators for pricing insurance risks

An axiomatic approach to capital allocation

The Cost of Financing Insurance. Glenn G. Meyers, FCAS, MAAA

What Is a Good Risk Measure: Bridging the Gaps between Robustness, Subadditivity, Prospect Theory, and Insurance Risk Measures

How To Calculate A Capital Buffer

Regulatory Impacts on Credit Portfolio Management

Manual for SOA Exam MLC.

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

CEA Working Paper on the risk measures VaR and TailVaR

COHERENT MEASURES OF RISK. DAVID HEATH Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh

What Is a Good Risk Measure: Bridging the Gaps between Data, Coherent Risk Measures, and Insurance Risk Measures

Lecture 2 of 4-part series. Spring School on Risk Management, Insurance and Finance European University at St. Petersburg, Russia.

Conditional Tail Expectations for Multivariate Phase Type Distributions

Properties of risk capital allocation methods

Joseph A. Boor, FCAS Florida Office of Insurance Regulation Tallahassee, Florida U.S.A. Florida State University Tallahassee, Florida U.S.A.

Arkansas Tech University MATH 4033: Elementary Modern Algebra Dr. Marcel B. Finan

A liability driven approach to asset allocation

Math 319 Problem Set #3 Solution 21 February 2002

Logical Implications of GASB s Methodology for Valuing Pension Liabilities

arxiv:cond-mat/ v3 [cond-mat.other] 9 Feb 2004

Premium Calculation - continued

Actuarial Pricing for Minimum Death Guarantees in Unit-Linked Life Insurance: A Multi-Period Capital Allocation Problem

160 CHAPTER 4. VECTOR SPACES

Handout #1: Mathematical Reasoning

25 Integers: Addition and Subtraction

From Ruin Theory to Solvency in Non-Life Insurance

Premium calculation. summer semester 2013/2014. Technical University of Ostrava Faculty of Economics department of Finance

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University

Considerations on the Quantification of Variability in P&C Insurance Policy Liabilities

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x a 2n x n = b 2.

Actuarial Teachers and Researchers Conference Investment Risk Management in the Tails of the Distributions. Chris Sutton 3 rd July 2008

COUNTING SUBSETS OF A SET: COMBINATIONS

Math 151. Rumbos Spring Solutions to Assignment #22

NOTES ON LINEAR TRANSFORMATIONS

Risk Minimizing Portfolio Optimization and Hedging with Conditional Value-at-Risk

An Analysis of the Underwriting Risk for DFA Insurance Company. Glenn G. Meyers, FCAS, MAAA

NEW MEASURES FOR PERFORMANCE EVALUATION

Gröbner Bases and their Applications

Risk Measurement in Insurance. A Guide To Risk Measurement, Capital Allocation And Related Decision Support Issues

ERM-2: Introduction to Economic Capital Modeling

Dynamic risk management with Markov decision processes

The last three chapters introduced three major proof techniques: direct,

Premium Calculation. Lecture: Weeks Lecture: Weeks (Math 3630) Annuities Fall Valdez 1 / 32

Some Observations on Variance and Risk

DFA Insurance Company Case Study, PartII: Capital Adequacy and Capital Allocation. Stephen W. Philbrick, FCAS, MAAA and Robert A.

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Decomposing total risk of a portfolio into the contributions of individual assets

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm

Property Casualty Insurer Economic Capital using a VAR Model Thomas Conway and Mark McCluskey

RBC and its Practical Applications to Non-Life Insurance

Copula Simulation in Portfolio Allocation Decisions

Quotient Rings and Field Extensions

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

Large deviations bounds for estimating conditional value-at-risk

On Simulation Method of Small Life Insurance Portfolios By Shamita Dutta Gupta Department of Mathematics Pace University New York, NY 10038

So let us begin our quest to find the holy grail of real analysis.

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

Key functions in the system of governance Responsibilities, interfaces and outsourcing under Solvency II

Class Meeting # 1: Introduction to PDEs

MATH10040 Chapter 2: Prime and relatively prime numbers

Solution. Let us write s for the policy year. Then the mortality rate during year s is q 30+s 1. q 30+s 1

How to model Operational Risk?

Math 4310 Handout - Quotient Vector Spaces

Expected Shortfall: a natural coherent alternative to Value at Risk

BEL best estimate liability, deduced from the mean loss as a present value of mean loss,

Notes on Complexity Theory Last updated: August, Lecture 1

Premium Calculation. Lecture: Weeks Lecture: Weeks (STT 455) Premium Calculation Fall Valdez 1 / 31

Cartesian Products and Relations

Point and Interval Estimates

Approximation of Aggregate Losses Using Simulation

MATH 140 Lab 4: Probability and the Standard Normal Distribution

Department of Applied Mathematics, University of Venice WORKING PAPER SERIES Working Paper n. 203/2010 October 2010

The Steepest Descent Algorithm for Unconstrained Optimization and a Bisection Line-search Method

CHAPTER 3. Methods of Proofs. 1. Logical Arguments and Formal Proofs

LEARNING OBJECTIVES FOR THIS CHAPTER

The Fundamental Theorem of Arithmetic

1. Prove that the empty set is a subset of every set.

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS. + + x 2. x n. a 11 a 12 a 1n b 1 a 21 a 22 a 2n b 2 a 31 a 32 a 3n b 3. a m1 a m2 a mn b m

On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference

Financial Simulation Models in General Insurance

Stochastic Analysis of Long-Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts

Agenda. Session 35. Methodology Modeling Challenges Scenario Generation Aggregation Diversification

WHERE DOES THE 10% CONDITION COME FROM?

Row Echelon Form and Reduced Row Echelon Form

MATH 304 Linear Algebra Lecture 9: Subspaces of vector spaces (continued). Span. Spanning set.

Chapter ML:IV. IV. Statistical Learning. Probability Basics Bayes Classification Maximum a-posteriori Hypotheses

No: Bilkent University. Monotonic Extension. Farhad Husseinov. Discussion Papers. Department of Economics

Subject ST9 Enterprise Risk Management Syllabus

Computing exponents modulo a number: Repeated squaring

Manual for SOA Exam MLC.

THE BANACH CONTRACTION PRINCIPLE. Contents

Guidance Note GGN Insurance Risk

Similarity and Diagonalization. Similar Matrices

Section 1.3 P 1 = 1 2. = P n = 1 P 3 = Continuing in this fashion, it should seem reasonable that, for any n = 1, 2, 3,..., =

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS

Numerical Matrix Analysis

Some Issues in Risk-Based Capital

Math 370/408, Spring 2008 Prof. A.J. Hildebrand. Actuarial Exam Practice Problem Set 5 Solutions

Mathematical Induction

Economic Impact of Capital Level in an Insurance Company

Transcription:

Coherent Measures of Risk An Exposition for the Lay Actuary by Glenn Meyers Insurance Services Office, Inc.

1. Introduction I believe the ideas in the paper Coherent Measures of Risk by Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber and David Heath [2] merit serious consideration by members of the Casualty Actuarial Society (CAS). However, their paper is written for an academic audience with extensive training in probability theory. The majority of CAS members will have some difficulty digesting the paper itself. This paper is my attempt to describe these ideas in language that is familiar to most CAS members. Their paper is motivated by the problem of setting margin requirements on an organized exchange. This problem is similar to that of setting capital requirements for insurance companies. Artzner [3] has written another paper on the subject that casualty actuaries might find more accessible. 2. A Motivation for the Definition of Coherence Consider the following set of ten scenarios, each with associated losses X 1, X 2, X 3 and X 4. Table 1 Scenario X 1 X 2 X 1 +X 2 X 3 = 2*X 1 X 4 = X 1 +1 1 1.00 0.00 1.00 2.00 2.00 2 2.00 0.00 2.00 4.00 3.00 3 3.00 0.00 3.00 6.00 4.00 4 4.00 1.00 5.00 8.00 5.00 5 3.00 2.00 5.00 6.00 4.00 6 2.00 3.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 7 1.00 4.00 5.00 2.00 2.00 8 0.00 3.00 3.00 0.00 1.00 9 0.00 2.00 2.00 0.00 1.00 10 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.00 1.00 Maximum Loss 4.00 4.00 5.00 8.00 5.00 Glenn Meyers Page 1 March 16, 2000

We can think of the X i s as random variables representing the losses of the i th risk. In our examples, we shall assume that each scenario is equally likely. Let a measure of risk for X i be defined as r(x i ) = Maximum(X i ), where the maximum is taken over all ten scenarios. This measure of risk fulfills the needs of an insurance regulator who wishes to require that the insurer have sufficient assets to cover the losses incurred in each of the scenarios. Some of the assets may be supplied by premiums paid by the insureds. The remainder of the assets must be supplied as insurer capital. Using Table 1 as an aid, the reader should be able to verify that the measure of risk, r, satisfies the following axioms. 1. Subadditivity For all random losses X and Y, 2. Monotonicity If X Y ( X + Y ) ( X ) + ( Y ) ρ ρ ρ for each scenario, then, ρ ( X) ρ( Y) 3. Positive Homogeneity For all λ 0 and random losses X, ( X) = λρ ( X ) ρ λ 4. Translation Invariance For all random losses X and constants a. ( X ) ( X) ρ + α = ρ + α A risk measure that satisfies these four axioms is called a coherent measure of risk. Glenn Meyers Page 2 March 16, 2000

These properties of a risk measure appear to be reasonable. Consider the following remarks. Subadditivity reflects the diversification of portfolios, or that, a merger does not create extra risk [4, 4 th page] and [2, 6 th page]. This is a natural requirement consistent with the role of insurance. Positive homogeneity is a limiting case of subadditivity, representing what happens when there is precisely no diversification effect [4, 4 th page]. Glenn Meyers Page 3 March 16, 2000

3. Other Measures of Risk It turns out that many common measures of risk used by actuaries are not coherent. Consider the following examples. Define the Value at Risk or VaR as the smallest loss that is greater than a predetermined percentile of the loss distribution. This measure is similar to Probability of Ruin measures that actuaries have long discussed. If our measure of risk, r(x), is the 85 th percentile of the random loss X, we have for the scenarios listed in Table 2 below: ( X ) ( X ) ( X X ) 0= ρ + ρ < ρ + = 1. 1 2 1 2 As this example shows, the value at risk criterion violates the subadditivity axiom. Table 2 Scenario X 1 X 2 X 1 +X 2 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 2 0.00 0.00 0.00 3 0.00 0.00 0.00 4 0.00 0.00 0.00 5 0.00 0.00 0.00 6 0.00 0.00 0.00 7 0.00 0.00 0.00 8 0.00 0.00 0.00 9 0.00 1.00 1.00 10 1.00 0.00 1.00 VaR@85% 0.00 0.00 1.00 Glenn Meyers Page 4 March 16, 2000

The Standard Deviation criterion sets the measure as the expected value of the loss plus a predetermined multiple of the standard deviation. For the scenarios listed in Table 3 below we have: ρ ρ X X 1 2 ( X1) E[ X1] StDev[ X1] ( X ) E[ X ] StDev[ X ] + 2 = 5.83 + 2 = 5.00 2 2 2 As this example shows, the standard deviation principle violates the monotonicity axiom. Table 3 Scenario X 1 X 2 1 1.00 5.00 2 2.00 5.00 3 3.00 5.00 4 4.00 5.00 5 5.00 5.00 6 5.00 5.00 7 4.00 5.00 8 3.00 5.00 9 2.00 5.00 10 1.00 5.00 E[Loss] 3.00 5.00 StDev[Loss] 1.41 0.00 E[Loss]+2*StDev[Loss] 5.83 5.00 So far, I have demonstrated that two popular statistical measures discussed in the literature (if not used in practice) on solvency standards are not coherent. Let me now turn to a more general description of measures of risk that are coherent. Glenn Meyers Page 5 March 16, 2000

4. The Representation Theorem Let W denote a finite set of scenarios. Let X be the loss incurred by the insurer under a particular business plan. We associate each loss with an element of W. The representation theorem [2, Proposition 4.1 and 3, Proposition 2.1] states that a risk measure, r, is coherent if and only if there exists a family, P, of probability measures defined on W such that ρ ( X) = sup{ EP [ X] P P }. (1) One way to construct a family of probability measures on W is to take a collection m { A i} i = 1 A = of subsets of W with the property that m i= 1 A i =Ω. Let n i be the number of elements in A i. Assume that all elements in W are equally likely. We then define the probability measure, P i, on the elements w Œ W as the conditional probability given that the element is in the set A i, and 0 otherwise. That is 1 if ω Ai i ( ) n P ω = i. 0 if ω A i The authors [2, 16 th page] refer to the collection of probability measures, P, on the set of scenarios as generalized scenarios. Glenn Meyers Page 6 March 16, 2000

Let s look at an example. The following table gives a set of scenarios and associated losses. Table 4 Scenario X 1 0 2 2 3 2 4 6 Let A 1 = {1,2} and A 2 = {3,4}. We then calculate the expected values P [ ] and P [ ] E X = 1 1 E X = 4. 2 The associated coherent measure of risk, r A (X), is then given by { } ( ) P [ ] ρ X = sup E X i = 1,2 = 4. A i We can similarly construct a second coherent measure of risk, r B (X), on the scenarios in Table 4 with the subsets B i = {i}. In this case we have r B (X)= 6. One can impose varying degrees of conservatism on coherent measures of risk by varying the choice of generalized scenarios. Glenn Meyers Page 7 March 16, 2000

5. A Proposal for a Risk Measure Artzner, Delbaen, Eber and Heath s paper finishes with a proposal for a risk measure that casualty actuaries should find easy to implement. Let s start with the formal definition of the Value at Risk (VaR). Let a be a selected probability (e.g. 99%). Then { α } ( ) inf Pr{ } VaR X = x X x > α As demonstrated above, VaR is not a coherent measure of risk. We now define the proposed measure in terms of the VaR. We call this measure the Tail Conditional Expectation (TCE) or Tail Value at Risk (TailVaR). ( ) ( ) ( ) TCEα X TailVaRα X E X X VaRα X The TailVaR is linked to a well-known criterion in recent CAS literature for solvency - the Expected Policyholder Deficit (EPD). See, for example, [1] and [5]. EPD(t) is defined as the expected loss over a predetermined threshold t. We then have that ( α ( X) ) EPD VaR TailVaRα ( X) = VaRα ( X) + 1 α. Glenn Meyers Page 8 March 16, 2000

I will now demonstrate that the TailVaR is coherent under some common conditions. For any subset A of W, let n A be the number of elements in A. Define the probability measure Proposition 1 if ω A A ( ω ) n P = A. 0 if ω A If the probability of each element of W is equally likely, then the TailVaR is a coherent measure of risk. Proof Let n be the number of elements in W. Denote the various values of X by x1 x2... xn. Let k be the integer with 0 k < nsuch that k + 1 k+ 1 Since Pr{ X x } = > α and Pr{ X x } n Let A be the family of subsets of W with exactly n measures P { P A }. By Equation 1, ( ) [ ] P measure of risk. = A A For any scenario w Œ A, Pr{ W ωω A} k k+ 1 α, n n. k < k + 1 α we have that VaR a (X) = x k+1. n k elements. Define the family of ρ X = sup{ E X A A } is a coherent 1 = =. n k Let AMax be the member of A with the n k largest elements, i.e.{ x, x,..., x } We then have ( ) = E ( ) TailVaRα X X X VaRα X xk+ 1+ xk+ 2 +... + xn = n k E. = P AMax For any other set A ŒA, E [ X] E [ X] Thus ( ) sup EP [ ] PA P. AMax { } A [ X] TailVaRα X = X A A and the risk measure is coherent. A k+ 1 k+ 2 n. Glenn Meyers Page 9 March 16, 2000

Note This proposition is slightly more general than [2, Proposition 5.3]. I provided the proof above for completeness. It is a minor modification of the proof that is given in [2]. Many actuaries use a continuous distribution function, with perhaps with a small number of jump discontinuities, to model the aggregate losses of an insurer. Since this distribution can be approximated, to any desired degree of closeness, with a distribution based on a number of equally likely scenarios, it is correct to say that the TailVaR measure applied to such a distribution is coherent. Glenn Meyers Page 10 March 16, 2000

References 1. American Academy of Actuaries Property/Casualty Risk-Based Capital Task Force, Report on Reserve and Underwriting Risk Factors, Casualty Actuarial Society Forum, Summer 1993 Edition. 2. Philippe Artzner, Freddy Delbaen, Jean-Marc Eber and David Heath, Coherent Measures of Risk, Math. Finance 9 (1999), no. 3, 203-228 http://www.math.ethz.ch/~delbaen/ftp/preprints/coherentmf.pdf 3. Philippe Artzner, Application of Coherent Risk Measures to Capital Requirements in Insurance, North American Actuarial Journal, Volume 3, Number 2, April 1999. 4. Michael Denault, Coherent Allocation of Risk Capital, Risklab web site. http://www.risklab.ch/ftp/papers/coherentallocation.pdf 5. Glenn Meyers, Underwriting Risk, 1999 Spring Forum, Casualty Actuarial Society http://www.casact.org/pubs/forum/99spforum/99spftoc.htm Glenn Meyers Page 11 March 16, 2000