The Black Scholes World

Similar documents
The Black-Scholes Formula

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Mathematical Finance

How To Price A Call Option

Lecture. S t = S t δ[s t ].

Option Pricing. Chapter 9 - Barrier Options - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 9th December 2013

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Binomial lattice model for stock prices

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

More Exotic Options. 1 Barrier Options. 2 Compound Options. 3 Gap Options

One Period Binomial Model

Diusion processes. Olivier Scaillet. University of Geneva and Swiss Finance Institute

Option Pricing. Chapter 11 Options on Futures. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13/01/2014 at 14:25

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Notes on Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

LECTURE 9: A MODEL FOR FOREIGN EXCHANGE

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

Black-Scholes Equation for Option Pricing

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS

where N is the standard normal distribution function,

Lecture 6 Black-Scholes PDE

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Lectures. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Merton-Black-Scholes model for option pricing. Peter Denteneer. 22 oktober 2009

Lecture 5: Put - Call Parity

Finite Differences Schemes for Pricing of European and American Options

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

7: The CRR Market Model

Bond Options, Caps and the Black Model

A Vega-Gamma Relationship for European-Style or Barrier Options in the Black-Scholes Model

Computational Finance Options

Black-Scholes and the Volatility Surface

Schonbucher Chapter 9: Firm Value and Share Priced-Based Models Updated

Forward Price. The payoff of a forward contract at maturity is S T X. Forward contracts do not involve any initial cash flow.

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Option Pricing. Stefan Ankirchner. January 20, Brownian motion and Stochastic Calculus

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Hedging Variable Annuity Guarantees

Additional questions for chapter 4

Convenient Conventions

Private Equity Fund Valuation and Systematic Risk

Lecture 3: Put Options and Distribution-Free Results

The Constant Elasticity of Variance Option Pricing Model

Betting on Volatility: A Delta Hedging Approach. Liang Zhong

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Financial Options: Pricing and Hedging

Caps and Floors. John Crosby

LECTURE 10.1 Default risk in Merton s model

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

Option Values. Option Valuation. Call Option Value before Expiration. Determinants of Call Option Values

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory

Sensitivity analysis of European options in jump-diffusion models via the Malliavin calculus on the Wiener space

The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber

A SNOWBALL CURRENCY OPTION

LOGNORMAL MODEL FOR STOCK PRICES

Chapter 13 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

TULLIE, TRACEY ANDREW. Variance Reduction for Monte Carlo Simulation of. for the evolution of an asset price under constant volatility.

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

Notes for Lecture 2 (February 7)

Barrier Options. Peter Carr

Pricing Barrier Option Using Finite Difference Method and MonteCarlo Simulation

Buy a number of shares,, and invest B in bonds. Outlay for portfolio today is S + B. Tree shows possible values one period later.

CHAPTER 3 Pricing Models for One-Asset European Options

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

EXP Capital Markets Option Pricing. Options: Definitions. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices 1) C > 0

Options Markets: Introduction

Numerical methods for American options

4. Option pricing models under the Black- Scholes framework

2. Exercising the option - buying or selling asset by using option. 3. Strike (or exercise) price - price at which asset may be bought or sold

Transcription:

Chapter 2 The Black Scholes World 2.1 The Model To start with we consider a world with just one risky asset with price process S t and a risk-free savings account paying constant interest rate r with continuous compounding. Everything takes place in a finite time interval [, T ]. Let Ω, F, F t ) t [,T ], w t ) t [,T ] ) be Wiener space, i.e. w t is Brownian motion, F t is the natural filtration of w t and F = F t. The price process S t is supposed to be geometric Brownian motion: S t satisfies the SDE ds t = µs t dt + σs t dw t 2.1) for given drift µ and volatility σ. 2.1) has a unique solution: if S t satifies 2.1) then by the Ito formula d log S t = µ 1 2 σ2 )dt + σdw t, so that S t satisfies 2.1) if and only if S t = S expµ 1 2 σ2 )t + σw t ). 2.2) Note that this makes S t very easy to simulate: for any increasing sequence of times = t < t 1..., S ti = S ti 1 exp µ 1 2 σ2 )t i t i 1 ) + σ ) t i t i 1 X i, where X 1, X 2,... is a sequence of independent N[, 1] random variables. This representation is exact. Another thing that follows from 2.2) is that ES t = S e µt. In the interests of symmetry we want the savings account also to be expressed as a traded asset, i.e. we should invest in it by buying a certain number of units of something. A convenient something is a zero-coupon bond This grows, as required, at rate r: B t = exp rt t)). db t = rb t dt 2.3) Note that 2.3) does not depend on the final maturity T the same growth rate is obtained from any ZC bond) and the choice of T is a matter of convenience as we will see below. 13

2.2 Portfolios and Trading Strategies If we hold φ and ψ units of S and B respectively at time t then we have a portfolio whose time-t value is φs t + ψb t. The assumptions of Black-Scholes are that we have a frictionless market, meaning that S and B can be traded in arbitrary amounts with no transaction costs, and short positions are allowed. In particular this means we can invest in, or borrow from, the riskless account at the same rate r of interest. A trading strategy is then a triple φ t, ψ t, x ), where x is the initial endowment and φ t, ψ t ) is a pair of adapted processes satisfying T The gain from trade in [s, t] is then φ 2 t dt < t s a.s., T t φ u ds u + ψ u db u. s ψ t dt <. Note how this matches up with the definition of the Ito integral!) A portfolio is self-financing if t t φ t S t + ψ t B t φ s S s ψ s B s = φ u ds u + ψ u db u. s s The increase in portfolio value is entirely due to gains from trade. 2.3 Arbitrage and Valuation Denote by V t the portfolio value at time t, i.e. V t = φ t S t + ψ t B t. An arbitrage opportunity is the existence of a self-financing trading strategy and a time t such that V =, V t a.s. and P [V t > ] > or, equivalently, EV t >.) It is axiomatic that arbitrage cannot exist in the market, so no mathematical model should permit arbitrage opportunities. 2.3.1 Forwards Consider a forward contract in which we fix a price K now to be paid at time T for delivery of 1 unit of S T. The unique no-arbitrage value of K is F = e rt S. Indeed, suppose someone offers us a forward contract at K < F. We sell one share and invest the proceeds S in the bank. At time T we get the share back for a payment of K but the value of our bank account is F > K. We make a riskless profit of F K. If we are able to offer a forward at K > F then we should borrow S and buy the share. Again, there is a riskless profit at time T. This argument is independent of the pricing model for S t.) 2.3.2 Put-Call Parity A call option with strike K and exercise time T has exercise value [S T K] +, and a put has exercise value [K S T ] +. Clearly [S T K] + [K S T ] + = S T K, so that buying a call and selling a put at time zero is equivalent to buying a forward and agreeing to pay K at time T. Thus whatever the prices C and P at time, they must satisfy C P = F K)B. 14

Note again that this is completely model-independent. 2.3.3 Replication Suppose there is a contingent claim with exercise value hs T ) at time T for example a put or call option) and there exists a self-financing trading strategy φ, ψ, x ) such that V T = hs T ) a.s. Then x is the unique no-arbitrage price of the contingent claim. The arbitrage, if available, is realized by selling the contingent claim and going long the replicating portfolio, or vice versa. This argument is sometimes known as the law of one price: if two assets have identical cash flows in the future then they must have the same value now. 2.4 Black-Scholes: the Original Proof Black s and Scholes original proof of the famous formula [1] was a very direct argument showing that a replicating portfolio exists for the European call option. Here is a version of that argument. The idea is to assume a whole lot of things and then show they are all true. The first assumption is that there is a smooth function Ct, S) such that the call option has a value Ct, S t ) at time t < T, with lim t T Ct, S) = [S K] +. Suppose we form a portfolio in which we are long one unit of the call option and short a self-financing portfolio φ, ψ, C, S )). The value of this portfolio at time t is then X t = Ct, S t ) φ t S t ψ t B t, with, in particular, X =. By the Ito formula and the self-financing property, dx t = S ds + t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 t 2 ) C S 2 dt φ t ds t ψ t db t. If we choose φ t = / S and use the fact that db = rbdt we see that Let us now choose dx t = t + 1 2 σ2 St 2 2 ) C S 2 dt ψ trb t dt. ψ t = t + 1 2 σ2 St 2 2 C S 2, rb t heroically assuming that in doing so we have not destroyed that self-financing property. Then X t, so that C = φs + ψb = S S + t + 1 2 σ2 St 2 2 C S 2, r showing that C must satisfy the Black-Scholes PDE with boundary condition t + rs S + +1 2 σ2 S 2 t 2 C rc = 2.4) S2 CT, S) = [S K] +. 2.5) 15

Equations 2.4),2.5) are enough to determine the function C, as we will show below. Is φ, ψ, x ) in fact self-financing? By definition φs + ψb = C since X t ) and t t φds + ψdb = = t t S ds + t dc = Ct, S t ) C, S ). t + 1 2 σ2 S 2 t 2 ) C S 2 du This confirms the self-financing property. We have now shown that the call option can be replicated by a self-financing portfolio with initial endowment C, S ), so by the argument in section 2.3.3 this is the unique arbitrage-free price. In the above argument, no special role is played by the call option exercise function [S T K] +. It simply provides the boundary condition for the Black-Scholes PDE 2.4). If we used another boundary condition CT, S) = hs) then the corresponding solution of 2.4) would give us the no-arbitrage value and hedging strategy for a contingent claim with exercise value hs T ). Example: the Forward Price. It is easy to check that Ct, S) = S satisfies 2.4) with boundary condition CT, S) = S. For a constant K, Ct, S) = e rt t) K satisfies 2.4) with boundary condition CT, S) = K. Since 2.4) is a linear equation, the value at time of receiving S T K at time T is therefore S Ke rt, which is equal to zero when K = e rt S, the forward price. You can check please do!) that the hedging strategy φ = / S implied by Black-Scholes coincides with the strategy given in section 2.3.1. 2.4.1 Probabilistic solution of the Black-Scholes PDE Suppose we have an SDE dx t = mx t )dt + gx t )dw t where m, g are Lipschitz continuous functions so that a solution exists. The differential generator of x t is the operator A defined by so the Ito formula can be written Afx) = mx) f x + 1 2 g2 x) 2 f x 2 dfx t ) = Afx t )dt + f x gx t)dw t. Now consider the following PDE for a function vt, x) v t + Avt, x) rvt, x) =, t < T, 2.6) vt, x) = Ξx), 2.7) 16

where r is a given constant and Ξ a given function. If v satisfies this then applying the Ito formula we find that v de rt vt, x t )) = re rt vt, x t )dt + e rt t + Avt, x t)dt + v ) x gt, x t)dw t rt v = e x gt, x t)dw t. 2.8) Thus exp rt)vt, x t ) is a local martingale. If it is a martingale then integrating from t to T and using 2.7) we see that ] vt, x t ) = E t,x [e rt t) Ξx T ) This is the probabilistic representation of the solution of the PDE 2.6),2.7). Comparing 2.4),2.5) with 2.6),2.7) we see that these equations match up when mx) = rx and gx) = σx, i.e. x t satisfies dx t = rx t dt + σx t dw t. 2.9) Now return to the price model 2.1) and introduce a measure change dq dp = exp αw T 1 ) 2 α2 T, where α is a constant. By Girsanov, d ˇw = dw αdt is a Q-Brownian motion, in terms of which 2.1) becomes ds t = µs t dt + σs t d ˇw t + α dt). Choosing α = r µ)/σ we get ds t = rs t dt + σs t d ˇw t, 2.1) the same equation as 2.9). Equation 2.1) is the price process expressed in the risk-neutral measure Q, and the above argument shows that the probabilistic solution of the Black-Scholes PDE 2.4),2.5) is Ct, S) = E Q t,s e rt t) [S T K] +). This is however easily computed since S T is given explicitly in terms of w T by 2.2) with r replacing µ). We get Ct, S) = e rt t) 2π [S expr σ 2 /2)T t) σx T t) K] + e x2 /2 dx. A short calculation gives the final expression Ct, S) = SNd 1 ) e rt t) KNd 2 ) 2.11) where N ) denotes the cumulative standard normal distribution function and d 1 = logs/k) + r + σ2 /2)T t) σ T t d 2 = d 1 σ T t 17

We can now tie up the loose ends of the argument. It can be checked directly that C defined by 2.11) does satisfy the Black-Scholes PDE 2.4),2.5), and another short calculation see Problems II!) shows that / S = Nd 1 ), so that in particular < / S < 1. Hence the integrand in 2.8) is square-integrable and the stochastic integral is a martingale, as required. Another version of the formula, often more useful, is this. Recall that the forward price at t for delivery at T is F = Se rt t). We can therefore express 2.11) as Ct, S) = e rt t) F Nd 1 ) KNd 2 )), 2.12) and d 1 can be expressed as d 1 = logf/k) + 1 2 σ2 T t) σ. T t 2.5 Proof by Martingale Representation Let φ be an adapted process with and let X t be a process defined by T φ 2 t S 2 t dt < a.s. 2.13) dx t = φ t ds t + X t φ t S t )r dt, X = x. 2.14) The interpretation is that X t is the portfolio value corresponding to the trading strategy φ, ψ, x ) where ψ t = X t φ t S t, 2.15) Bt) i.e. φ t units of the risky asset are held and the remaining value X t φ t S t is held in the savings account. This strategy is always self-financing since X t is by definition the gains from trade process, while the value is φs + ψb = X. Applying the Ito formula we find that, with X t = e rt X t, d X t = φe rt Sµ r) dt + σ dw) 2.16) = φ Sσd ˇw, 2.17) where S t = e rt S t. The first line 2.16) shows incidentally that 2.14) has a unique solution.) Thus e rt X t is a local martingale in the risk-neutral measure Q. Suppose we have an option whose exercise value at time T is H, where H is an F T -measurable random variable with EH 2 <. By the martingale representation theorem there is an integrand g such that T e rt H = E Q [e rt H] + g t d ˇw t. Define φ t = e rt g t /σs t ) and then ψ by 2.15) and x = E Q [e rt H]. Then φ Sσ = g and the trading strategy φ, ψ, x ) generates a portfolio value process such that X T = H a.s., i.e. φ, ψ, x ) is a replicating portfolio for H. It follows that the option value is x = E Q [e rt H]. 18

Note this is a much more general result than that obtained by the previous argument, in that the option payoff can be an arbitrary, possibly path-dependent, random variable, whereas before we assumed it took a value of the form H = hs T ). On the other hand the above argument only asserts that a replicating portfolio exists: it does not give an explicit formula for φ. Theorem 6 Let Φ be the class of investment strategies φ t such that a) the integrability condition 2.13) is satisfied, and b) there exists a positive constant A φ such that X t A φ for all t [, T ], where X t is the process defined by 2.14). In the Black-Scholes model, no strategy φ Φ is an arbitrage opportunity. Proof: Suppose X t is given by 2.14) for some strategy φ Φ and X =. Then, from 2.17), the discounted process X t is a Q-local martingale which is bounded below by the constant A φ. Thus X t + A φ is a non-negative local martingale, and hence a supermartingale. Therefore X t is a supermartingale and has decreasing expectation: for any t > = E Q [ X ] E Q [ X t ]. 2.18) On the other hand, if X t a.s.p ) and P [X t > ] > then, since P and Q are equivalent measures, E Q [ X t ] >, which is incompatible with 2.18). Hence there cannot be an arbitrage opportunity as defined in Section 2.3. 2.6 Robustness of Black-Scholes Hedging If we assume the Black-Scholes price model 2.1) then the price at time t of an option with exercise value hs T ) is C h S t, r, σ, t) = Ct, S t ) where Ct, S) satisfies the Black-Scholes PDE 2.4) with boundary condition CT, S) = hs). Suppose we sell an option at implied volatility ˆσ, i.e. we receive at time the premium C h S, r, ˆσ, ), and we hedge under the assumption that the model 2.1) is correct with σ = ˆσ. The hedging strategy is then delta hedging : the number of units of the risky asset held at time t is the so-called option delta / S: φ t = S t, S t). 2.19) Suppose now that the model 2.1) is not correct, but the true price model is ds t = αt, ω)s t dt + βt, ω)s t dw t, 2.2) where w t is an F t -Brownian motion for some filtration F t not necessarily the natural filtration of w t ) and α t, β t are F t -adapted, say bounded, processes. It is no loss of generality to write the drift and diffusion in 2.2) as αs, βs: since S t > a.s. we could always write a general diffusion coefficient γ as γ t = γ t /S t )S t α t S t. In fact the model 2.2) is saying little more than that S t is a positive process with continuous sample paths. Using strategy 2.19) the value X t of the hedging portfolio is given by X = C, S ) and dx t = S ds t + X t ) S S t r dt 19

where S t satisfies 2.2). By the Ito formula, Y t Ct, S t ) satisfies dy t = S ds + t + 1 2 β2 St 2 2 ) C S 2 dt. Thus the hedging error Z t X t Y t satisfies d dt Z t = rx t rs t S t 1 2 β2 St 2 2 C S 2. Using 2.4) and denoting Γ t = Γt, S t ) = 2 Ct, S t )/ s 2, we find that Since Z =, the final hedging error is Comments: d dt Z t = rz t + 1 2 S2 t Γ 2 t ˆσ 2 β 2 t ). Z T = X T hs T ) = T e rt s) 1 2 S2 t Γ 2 t ˆσ 2 β 2 t )dt. This is a key formula, as it shows that successful hedging is quite possible even under significant model error. It is hard to imagine that the derivatives industry could exist at all without some result of this kind. Notice that: Successful hedging depends entirely on the relationship between the Black-Scholes implied volatility ˆσ and the true local volatility β t. For example, if we are lucky and ˆσ 2 β 2 t a.s. for all t then the hedging strategy 2.19) makes a profit with probability one even though the true price model is substantially different from the assumed model 2.1), as long as Γ t, which holds for standard puts and calls. The hedging error also depends on the option convexity Γ. If Γ is small then hedging error is small even if the volatility has been underestimated. 2.7 Options on Dividend-paying Assets Holders of ordinary shares receive dividends, which are cash payments normally quoted as x pence per share, paid on specific dates with the value x being announced some time in advance. For a stock index, where the constituent stocks are all paying different dividends at different times, it makes sense to think in terms of a dividend yield, the dividend per unit time expressed as a fraction of the index value. In mathematical terms, we assume that a dividend is a continuoustime payment stream, the dividend paid in a time interval dt being qs t dt. Thus q is the dividend yield. In this section we analyse the case where q is a fixed constant. Equation 2.14), describing the evolution of a self-financing portfolio, must be modified to dx t = φ t ds t + qφ t S t dt + X t φ t S t )r dt, X = x. 2.21) = φ t S t µ + q r)dt + X t r dt + φ t S t σdw t, 2.22) so that ) d e rt X t = φ Sµ + q r)dt + φ Sσ dw. 2.23) 2

Now change to a martingale measure Q q such that dw q = dw + µ + q r dt σ is a Q q -Brownian motion. Then 2.23) becomes simply ) d e rt X t = φ Sσ dw q. Thus by the argument of the previous section, the price at time of a contingent claim H is [ ] p = E Q q e rt H. 2.24) In particular, take H = S T. Then p is the no-arbitrage price now for delivery of 1 unit of the asset at time T, or, equivalently, e rt p is the forward price. In 2.21), take X φs =, so that all receipts are re-invested in the risky asset S, nothing being held in the bank account. Then φ = X/S, so that dx = X S ds + q X S S dt = Xµ dt + σ dw) + qx dt = Xµ + q)dt + σ dw). 2.25) On the other hand, if we define Ŝt = e qt S t and use 2.1) and the Ito formula, we find that dŝt = Ŝtµ + q)dt + σ dw). 2.26) From 2.25) and 2.26) we see that X t = Ŝt = e qt S t for all t > if X = S. Now the solution of 2.25) is linear in the initial condition, so if X = e qt S then X T = S T a.s. We have shown the following. Proposition 1 i) For an asset with a constant dividend yield q, the forward price at time T is F T = e r q)t S. The replicating strategy that delivers one unit of the asset at time T consists of buying e qt units of the asset at time and reinvesting all dividends in the asset. ii) The value of a call option on the asset with exercise time T and strike K is CS, K, r, q, σ, T ) = e rt F T Nd 1 ) KNd 2 )), 2.27) where Proof: d 1 = logf T /K) + σ 2 T/2 σ, d 2 = d 1 σ T. T Only part ii) remains to be proved. Under measure Q q, S t satisfies ds t = r q)s t dt + σs t dw q t, 2.28) and the option value is given by 2.24) with H = [S T K] +. This is exactly the same calculation as standard Black-Scholes, but with r q) replacing r in the price equation 2.28) but not in the discount factor e rt in 2.24)). Formula 2.27) follows from 2.12). 21

2.8 Barrier Options Let S t be a price process and let M t = max u t S u be the maximum price to date. An up-andout call option has exercise value [S T K] + 1 MT <B. It pays the standard call payoff if S t < B for all t [, T ] and zero otherwise. B is the barrier, and to make sense, we must have S < B, K < B. An up-and-in call option pays [S T K] + 1 MT B. The sum of these two payoffs is an ordinary call, so we only need to value one of the above. There are analogous definitions for down-and-out and down-and-in options. Remarkably, there are analytic formulas for the values of these options in the Black-Scholes world. These formulas but not the proofs can be found on pages 462-464 of Hull s book [5] The starting point is the so-called reflection principle for Brownian motion. Let x t be standard Brownian motion starting at zero and m t = max s t x s. The reflection principle states that for y > and x y, ) x 2y P [m t y, x t < x] = N. 2.29) t The idea is that those paths that do hit level y before time t restart from level y with symmetric distribution see figure 2.1), so there is equal probability that they will be below x = y y x) or above y + y x) = 2y x at time t. But P [m t y, x t 2y x] = P [x t 2y x] ) 2y x = 1 N t ) x 2y = N t Now [x t < x] = [m t < y, x t < x] [m t y, x t < x], so 3 25 2 15 1 5-5 1 21 41 61 81 11 121 141 161 181-1 -15 Figure 2.1: Reflection principle 22

We have shown the following. ) x N = P [x t < x] = P [m t < y, x t < x] + P [m t y, x t < x]. 2.3) t Proposition 2 The joint distribution of x t, the Brownian motion at time t, and its maximumto-date m t is given by ) ) x x 2y F y, x) = P [m t < y, x t < x] = N N 2.31) t t This argument depends on symmetry and doesn t work if x t has drift. We can use the Girsanov theorem to get the answer in this case. If P ν denotes the probability measure of BM with drift ν i.e. x t = νt + w t where w t is ordinary BM) then we know that on the interval [, T ] dp ν dp = expνx T 1 2 ν2 T ). Thus if f is any integrable function then, using 2.31), [ E ν [1 mt <yfx T )] = E 1 mt <yfx T ) dp ] ν dp = E [1 mt <yfx T ) exp νx T 1 )] 2 ν2 T = y fx)e νx ν2 T/2) 1 φx/ T ) φx 2y)/ ) T ) dx, T where φx) = e x2 /2 / 2π is the standard normal density function. Now clearly 1 exp 1 2πT 2T x2 + νx 1 ) 2 ν2 T = 1 ) x νt φ T T while after some calculation we find that 1 2πT exp 1 2T x 2y)2 + νx 1 2 ν2 T ) ) = e2yν x 2y νt φ. T T This gives us the final result: the joint distribution function with drift ν is ) )) x νt x 2y νt F ν y, x) = P ν [m T < y, x T < x] = N e 2yν N. 2.32) T T This does coincide with F when ν =. A good reference for the above argument is Harrison [3]. Let us now return to barrier option pricing. The price process in the risk-neutral measure is S T = S expr σ 2 /2)T + σw T ) which we can write as where x T = w T + νt with ν = 1 σ S T = S e σx T r 1 2 σ2 ). 23

The price S T is in the money but below the barrier level when x T a 1, a 2 ) where a 1 = 1 σ log K S ), a 2 = 1 σ log B S ). Denoting gy, x) = F ν y, x)/ x, the option value can now be expressed as ] a2 E ν [e rt [S T K] + 1 MT <B = e rt S e σx K)gy, x)dx. Doing the calculations we obtain the option value given in [5] as a sum of four terms of the form c 1 Nc 2 ), as in the Black-Scholes formula. The up-and-out option price is ) B 2λ S Nd 1 ) Nx 1 ) + N y) N y 1 ))) S +Ke Nd rt 2 ) + Nx 1 σ ) B 2λ 2 T ) N y + σ T ) N y 1 + σ T )) S where d 1, d 2 are the usual coefficients and a 1 x 1 = logs /B) σ + λσ T T y 1 = logb/s ) σ + λσ T T y = logb2 /S K)) σ + λσ T T λ = r + σ2 /2 σ 2 Figures 2.2,2.3,2.4 show the value, delta and gamma of an up-and-out call option with strike K = 1, barrier level B = 12 and volatility 25%. The option matures at time T = 1. One can clearly see the black hole of barrier options: the region where the time-to-go is short and the priced is close to the barrier. In this region there is high negative delta, and there comes a point where hedging is essentially impossible because of the large gamma i.e. unrealistically frequent rehedging is called for by the theory.) 24

Up-and-Out Barrier Option 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 6 8 9 4 1 2 1 7 1 1 1 1 1 5 1 1 9. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 9 9 9 4 2-2 Figure 2.2: Barrier option value Delta 1.. -1. -2. -3. -4. -5.. 8 9. 9 2. 9 5. 9 8 1 1 8 1 1 5 1 1 2 1 9 1 6 1 2 9 6 9 7 5 6 Figure 2.3: Barrier option delta 25

Barrier Gamma.2. -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8-1. -1.2. 8 9. 9 1. 9 3. 9 5. 9 7 1. 1 9 8 9 1 1 5 1 1 2 1 9 1 6 1 2 9 6 9 7 5 6 Figure 2.4: Barrier option gamma 26