MEAN-VARIANCE HEDGING WITH RANDOM VOLATILITY JUMPS

Similar documents
Risk-minimization for life insurance liabilities

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

Sensitivity analysis of utility based prices and risk-tolerance wealth processes

Hedging of Life Insurance Liabilities

Mathematical Finance

Optimal Investment with Derivative Securities

Sensitivity analysis of European options in jump-diffusion models via the Malliavin calculus on the Wiener space

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS

Introduction to Arbitrage-Free Pricing: Fundamental Theorems

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Non-Arbitrage and the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing: Summary of Main Results

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Fair Valuation and Hedging of Participating Life-Insurance Policies under Management Discretion

Properties of BMO functions whose reciprocals are also BMO

7: The CRR Market Model

Asian Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

The Black-Scholes Formula

A spot price model feasible for electricity forward pricing Part II

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

Invariant Option Pricing & Minimax Duality of American and Bermudan Options

LOGNORMAL MODEL FOR STOCK PRICES

Bubbles and futures contracts in markets with short-selling constraints

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

The Effect of Management Discretion on Hedging and Fair Valuation of Participating Policies with Maturity Guarantees

LOG-TYPE MODELS, HOMOGENEITY OF OPTION PRICES AND CONVEXITY. 1. Introduction

In which Financial Markets do Mutual Fund Theorems hold true?

On the decomposition of risk in life insurance

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

FINANCIAL MARKETS WITH SHORT SALES PROHIBITION

Liquidity costs and market impact for derivatives

Lecture 13: Martingales

Simple Arbitrage. Motivated by and partly based on a joint work with T. Sottinen and E. Valkeila. Christian Bender. Saarland University

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

LECTURE 9: A MODEL FOR FOREIGN EXCHANGE

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS

Decomposition of life insurance liabilities into risk factors theory and application

ON LIMIT LAWS FOR CENTRAL ORDER STATISTICS UNDER POWER NORMALIZATION. E. I. Pancheva, A. Gacovska-Barandovska

Adaptive Online Gradient Descent

How To Find Out How To Calculate A Premeasure On A Set Of Two-Dimensional Algebra

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON OF INTEREST RATE GUARANTEES IN LIFE INSURANCE

Valuation and Hedging of Participating Life-Insurance Policies under Management Discretion

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

How To Price A Call Option

Numeraire-invariant option pricing

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces

Essays in Financial Mathematics

Stephane Crepey. Financial Modeling. A Backward Stochastic Differential Equations Perspective. 4y Springer

From Binomial Trees to the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formulas

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model

The Henstock-Kurzweil-Stieltjes type integral for real functions on a fractal subset of the real line

Math 526: Brownian Motion Notes

2 The Term Structure of Interest Rates in a Hidden Markov Setting

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

FACTORING POLYNOMIALS IN THE RING OF FORMAL POWER SERIES OVER Z

MEAN VARIANCE HEDGING AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN HESTON S MODEL WITH CORRELATION

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

On exponentially ane martingales. Johannes Muhle-Karbe

ON DETERMINANTS AND SENSITIVITIES OF OPTION PRICES IN DELAYED BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Lecture. S t = S t δ[s t ].

On a comparison result for Markov processes

Hedging bounded claims with bounded outcomes

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

Some Research Problems in Uncertainty Theory

Continued Fractions and the Euclidean Algorithm

Shape Optimization Problems over Classes of Convex Domains

Diusion processes. Olivier Scaillet. University of Geneva and Swiss Finance Institute

An axiomatic approach to capital allocation

Option Pricing. Chapter 9 - Barrier Options - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 9th December 2013

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Guaranteed Annuity Options

On Quantile Hedging and Its Applications to the Pricing of Equity-Linked Life Insurance Contracts 1

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 26 Feb 2015

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Option Pricing in ARCH-type Models: with Detailed Proofs. Nr. 10 März 1995

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

Practical and theoretical aspects of market-consistent valuation and hedging of insurance liabilities

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia

FAIR VALUATION OF THE SURRENDER OPTION EMBEDDED IN A GUARANTEED LIFE INSURANCE PARTICIPATING POLICY. Anna Rita Bacinello

Valuation of the Surrender Option Embedded in Equity-Linked Life Insurance. Brennan Schwartz (1976,1979) Brennan Schwartz

A Summary on Pricing American Call Options Under the Assumption of a Lognormal Framework in the Korn-Rogers Model

Barrier Options. Peter Carr

A new Feynman-Kac-formula for option pricing in Lévy models

Option Pricing. Chapter 11 Options on Futures. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13/01/2014 at 14:25

MATHEMATICAL FINANCE and Derivatives (part II, PhD)

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

Online Appendix. Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and. Equilibrium Prices. by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos

LECTURE 10.1 Default risk in Merton s model

HPCFinance: New Thinking in Finance. Calculating Variable Annuity Liability Greeks Using Monte Carlo Simulation

Grey Brownian motion and local times

Transcription:

MEAN-VARIANCE HEDGING WIH RANDOM VOLAILIY JUMPS PAOLO GUASONI AND FRANCESCA BIAGINI Abstract. We introduce a general framework for stochastic volatility models, with the risky asset dynamics given by: dx t ω, η = µ t ηx t ω, ηdt + σ t ηx t ω, ηdw t ω where ω, η Ω H, F Ω F H, P Ω P H. In particular, we allow for random discontinuities in the volatility σ and the drift µ. First we characterize the set of equivalent martingale measures, then compute the mean-variance optimal measure P, using some results of Schweizer on the existence of an adjustment process β. We show examples where the risk premium λ = µ r σ follows a discontinuous process, and make explicit calculations for P. Introduction he introduction of the mean-variance approach for pricing options under incomplete information is due to Föllmer and Sondermann [7], who first proposed the minimization of quadratic risk. heir work, as well as that of Bouleau and Lamberton, focused on the case when the price of the underlying asset is a martingale. he more general semimartingale case was considered by: Duffie and Richardson [6], Schweizer [18, 19, 2, 21], Hipp [1], Monat and Stricker [13], Schäl [17], and a definitive solution was provided by Schweizer and Rheinländer [16], and Gourieroux, Laurent, and Pham [14], with different methods. In the meantime, the random behavior of volatility turned out to be a major issue in applied option pricing, and Hull and White [11], Stein and Stein [22] and Heston [9] proposed different models with stochastic volatility. In fact, such models are special cases of incomplete information, and can be effectively embedded in the theoretical framework developed by mathematicians. A particularly appealing feature of mean-variance hedging is that European options prices are calculated as the expectations of their respective payoff under a possibly signed martingale measure P, introduced by Schweizer [21]. he optimal strategy can also be found in terms of this measure, therefore it is not surprising that considerable effort has been devoted to its explicit calculation. 1

In this paper, we address the problem of calculating P in presence of volatility jumps or, more generally, when the so-called market price of risk λ = µ r follows a possibly discontinuous process. σ We consider the following market model, where each state of nature ω, η belongs to the product space Ω H, endowed with the product measure P Ω P H : 1 { dst ω, η = µ t ηs t ω, ηdt + σ t ηs t ω, ηdw t ω t B t = exp r sds and r is a constant. We assume the existence on H of a set A of martingales with the representation property: this somewhat technical condition is in fact satisfied in most models present in the literature. First we characterize martingale measures in terms of A, then, exploiting some results of Schweizer, we isolate the density of the meanvariance optimal martingale measure. When volatility follows a diffusion process such as in the Heston or Hull and White models, only to mention two of them, this result was already obtained by Laurent and Pham with stochastic control arguments. It turns out that the jump size distribution is a critical issue: in fact, finite distributions are easily handled by n martingales, where n is the cardinality of the jump size support. On the contrary, an infinite distribution for the jump size requires a more general approach involving random measures. Moreover we show calculations for sample models where volatility jumps are random both in size and in time of occurrence. For all of them, we calculate the density of the mean-variance optimal measure, and the law of the jumps under P. In the last section, we calculate the mean-variance hedging strategy for a call option, exploiting the change of numeraire technique of El Karoui, Geman and Rochet [8], as well as the general formula in feedback form of Rheinländer and Schweizer [16]. 1. Preliminaries For all standard definitions on stochastic processes, we refer to Dellacherie and Meyer [4]. 1.1. Stopping imes. We recall here some definitions and properties of stopping times, which will come useful in the sequel. In this subsection, we assume that all random variables are defined on some probability space Ω, F, P. 2

Proposition 1.1. Let τ be a real-valued, Borel random variable, and F τ the smallest filtration under which τ is a stopping time. We have that: 2 F τ t = τ 1 B[, t] τ 1 t, where BA is the family of Borel subsets of A. Proof. By definition, F τ t = σ{τ s}, s t. Since F τ t is a σ-field and contains all sublevels of τ within [, t], it necessarily contains the inverse images of all Borel sets of [, t]. he set τ 1 t, is the complement of τ 1 [, t], and belongs to the σ-field. he reverse inclusion is trivial. Finally, the right-hand side in 2 is easily seen to be a σ-field. Remark 1.2. An immediate consequence of Proposition 1.1 is the rightcontinuity of Ft τ. Moreover, Ft τ = τ 1 B[, t τ 1 [t,. his means that the augmentation of Ft τ is continuous if and only if the law of τ is diffuse. Corollary 1.3. he filtration generated by the random variable τ t coincides with F τ if and only if τ is an optional time, that is, if {τ < t} F t for all t. Definition 1.4. A stopping time τ is totally inaccessible if it is strictly positive and for every increasing sequence of stopping times τ 1,..., τ n, such that τ n < τ for all n, P lim n τ n = τ, τ < =. otally inaccessible stopping times can be characterized as follows: Proposition 1.5. Let τ a strictly positive stopping time. he following properties are equivalent: i τ is totally inaccessible; ii here exists a uniformly integrable martingale M t, continuous outside the graph of τ such that M = and M τ = 1 on {τ < }. Proof. See Dellacherie and Meyer [5], VI.78. Proposition 1.6. If the law of a stopping time is diffuse, then it is totally inaccessible with respect to F τ. Proof. See Dellacherie and Meyer [4], IV.17. Definition 1.7. Let A be an adapted process, with A = and locally integrable variation. he compensator of A is defined as the unique predictable process à such that A à is a local martingale. Remark 1.8. In particular, the compensator of an increasing process is itself an increasing predictable process. Proposition 1.9. Let τ be a stopping time with a diffuse law. hen the compensator of the process 1 {τ t} with respect to F τ is given by where F x = P τ x. à t = log1 F t τ 3

Proof. By assumption, M t = 1 {τ t} Ãt is a local martingale, and by Remark 1.8, Ã t is an increasing process. herefore we have: sup M s 1 s t and M t is in fact a martingale see for instance Protter, page 35, heorem 47. We look for a compensator of the form Ãt = a t τ, with a : R + R +. Hence: It follows that: E [ 1 {τ s} 1 {τ t} Ft ] = E [as τ a t τ F t ] P t < τ s P t < τ s t = E [ 1 {t<τ s} a τ a t + 1 {t<τ} a s a t ] P t < τ his equality can be rewritten as an integral equation: F s F t = s t a x a t df x + s a s a t df x It is easy to check by substitution that the unique solution to this integral equation is given by a x = log1 F x. By the uniqueness, this is the only compensator of 1 {τ t}. 1.2. Martingale Representation. We denote by M 2 the set of squareintegrable martingales on a probability space Ω, F, P endowed with a filtration F t satisfying the usual hypotheses. Definition 1.1. A set A = {X 1,... X n } M 2 is strongly orthogonal if X i X j M 2 for i, j {1... n}. Definition 1.11. A set A of strongly orthogonal martingales X 1,..., X n has the representation property if I = M 2, where { n } t I = X : X t = HsdX i s i for all H predictable such that [ t ] E Hs i 2 d[x i ] s < 1 i n t i=1 In this paper we will need the following result: Proposition 1.12. Let A = X 1,..., X n a set of strongly orthogonal martingales. If there is only a martingale measure for A, then A has the representation property. Proof. See Dellacherie and Meyer [5], VIII.58 or Protter [15], IV.37. 4

1.3. Random measures. For completeness, we provide some basic definitions on random measures: we refer to [12] for a complete treatment of the subject. Let H, F, P be a probability space. Definition 1.13. A random measure on R + R is a family ν = νη; dt, dx : η H of nonnegative measures on R + R, BR + BR, satisfying νη; {} R = identically. We set H = H R + R, with σ-fields Õ = O BR and P = P BR, where O and P are respectively the optional and predictable σ-field on H R +. Definition 1.14. For any Õ-measurable function hη; t, x we define the integral process h ν as hη, s, xνη; ds, dx if hη, s, x νη; ds, dx < h ν t η = [,t] H [,t] H + otherwise Analogously, a random measure ν is optional resp. predictable if the process h ν is optional resp. predictable for every optional resp. predictable function h. Definition 1.15. An integer-valued random measure is a random measure that satisfies: i νη; {t} R 1 identically; ii for each A BR + BR, ν, A take its values in N; iii ν is optional; iv P-σ-finite, i.e. there exists a P-measurable partition A n of H such that 1 An ν is integrable. By proposition 1.14 of [12] we obtain the following characterization of integer-valued random measures. Proposition 1.16. If ν is an integer-valued random measure, there exists a random set D = [ n ], where [ n ] n N is the sequence of graphs of stopping times n, and a real optional process β such that νη; dt, du = Σ s 1 D η, sɛ s,βs ηdt, du If n n N satisfies [ n ] [ m ] = for n m, it is called an exhausting sequence for D. Proposition 1.17. Let X be an adapted càdlàg R d -valued process. hen: ν X η; dt, dx = s 1 { Xs }ɛ {s, Xs η}dt, dx defines an integer-valued random measure on R + R d. 5

Proof. See [12], Chapter II, Proposition 1.16. Definition 1.18. A multivariate point process is an integer-valued random measure ν on R + R such that νη; [, t] R < for all η, t R +. Proposition 1.19. Let ν be an optional P-σ-finite random measure. here exists a random measure ν p, called compensator of ν, and unique up to a P -null set, such that: i ν p is a predictable random measure; ii E [h ν p ] = E [h ν ] for every nonnegative P -measurable function h on Ω. Also, if h ν is increasing and locally integrable, then h ν ν p is a local martingale. Proof. See heorem [12], Chapter II, heorem 1.8. Let ν = Σ s 1 D η, sɛ s,βsηdt, du be an integer random measure and ν p its compensator. Definition 1.2. 1. We denote by G loc ν the set of all P-measurable real-valued function h such that the process h t η = hη, t, βη1 D η, t hη, s, xνη; s dx has the property that [Σ s. h s 2 ] 1 2 is locally integrable and increasing. 2. If h G loc ν we call stochastic integral with respect to ν ν p and denote by h ν ν p any purely discontinuous local martingale X such that h and X are indistinguishable. Definition 1.21. A compensated random measure ν ν p has the representation property on H iff every square integrable martingale M t on H, F H, P H can be written as for some P-measurable process k. H M t = M + k ν ν p t We recall that from proposition 1.28, first chapter of [12] follows that h ν ν p t = h ν t h ν p t for every P-measurable process h such that h ν t is a locally integrable increasing process. Consequently, we obtain in theorem 1.21 that the integral h ν ν p, which is a-priori stochastic, coincides with the Stieltjes integral h ν h ν p. It follows that every local martingale on H has finite variation. heorem 1.22. Assume that ν is a multivariate point process. hen, ν ν p has the representation property with respect to the smallest filtration under which ν is optional. Proof. See theorem 4.37 of [12]. 6

2. he Market Model We introduce here a simple model for a market with incomplete information. We have two complete filtered probability spaces: Ω, F Ω, Ft Ω, P Ω and H, F H, Ft H, P H. We denote by W t a standard Brownian Motion on Ω, and assume that Ft Ω is the P Ω H -augmentation of the filtration generated by W. Our set of states of nature is given by the product space Ω H, F Ω F H, P Ω P H. We have a risk-free asset B t and a discounted risky asset X t = S t B t, with the following dynamics: { 3 dx t ω, η = µ t η r t X t ω, ηdt + σ t ηx t ω, ηdw t ω B t = exp t r sds where r is a deterministic function of time. We assume that the equation for X admits P H -a.e. a unique strong solution with respect to the filtration F W or, equivalently, that there exists a unique strong solution with respect to the filtration F t = Ft W F H. his is satisfied under fairly weak assumptions: for example, it is sufficient that µ and σ are P H -a.e. bounded. Denoting by F X the filtration generated by X, we also assume that Ft X = Ft W Ft H. In particular, at time all information is revealed through the observation of the process X. he following proposition helps checking whether this condition is satisfied: Proposition 2.1. Let X t be defined as in 3. hen, if i µ t is F X t -measurable, ii F H t F X t. then F X t = F W t F H t. Proof. By definition of X t, we immediately have that Ft X Ft Ω Ft H. o see that the reverse inclusion holds, observe first that by 3: 4 W t = t µ s σ s ds + t dx s σ s X s By i, the first term above is Ft X -measurable. For the second, note that t n σs, η 2 Xs 2 ds = X ti+1 X ti 2 lim sup i t i+1 t i where the limit holds in probability, uniformly in t. his proves that F Ω t F X t, and by ii the proof is complete. A simpler version of this model was introduced by Delbaen and Schachermayer [3], while it can be found in the above form in Pham, Rheinländer, and Schweizer [14]. 7 i=1

In this framework, we study the problem of an agent wishing to hedge a certain European option HX expiring at a fixed time. Hedging performance is defined as the L 2 -norm of the difference, at expiration, between the liability and the hedging portfolio. More precisely, we look for a solution to the minimization problem: 5 min E [ HX c R c G θ 2] θ Θ where G t θ = t θ s dx s and Θ = { θ LX, G t θ S 2 P } Here LX denotes the space of X-integrable predictable processes, and S 2 the space of semimartingales Y decomposable as Y = Y + M + A, where M is a square-integrable martingale, and A is a process of squareintegrable variation. his problem is generally nontrivial, since the agent has not access to the filtration F, but only to F X. Indeed, Reihnländer and Schweizer [16] and, independently, Gourieroux, Laurent and Pham [14], proved that problem 5 admits a unique solution for all H L 2 P, under the standing hypothesis: CL G Θ is closed Moreover, in [21] it is shown that the option price, i.e. the optimal value for c, and the optimal hedging strategy θ can be computed in terms of P, the variance-optimal martingale measure. In fact, the option price is given by c = Ẽ [H]. Definition 2.2. We define the sets of signed martingale measures M 2 s, and of equivalent martingale measures M 2 e: { M 2 s = Q P : dq } dp L2 P, X t is a Q-local martingale M 2 e = { Q M 2 s : Q P : } Definition 2.3. he variance optimal martingale measure is the unique solution P if it exists to the minimum problem: [ dq ] 2 6 min E Q M 2 s dp If M 2 s is nonempty, then P always exists, as it is the minimizer of the norm in a convex set: the problem is that it may not be positive definite, thereby leading to possibly negative option prices. However, if X t has continuous paths, and under the standard assumption NA M 2 e 8

Delbaen and Schachermayer [3] have shown that P M 2 e. Since we are dealing with continuous processes, and we will always assume NA, we need not worry about this issue. In this paper, using a representation formula from [1], we compute explicitly P for some sample models. 3. Representation of Martingale Measures Here we summarize some of the main results of [1] in order to show that the set M 2 e of equivalent martingale measures admits a convenient representation. We denote by λ t = µ t r t of risk. σ t the so-called market price heorem 3.1. If there exists a n-dimensional martingale M on H such that: i [M i, M j ] for all i j; ii M has the representation property for Ft H ; then we have for every Q M 2 e: dq dp = E λ t ηdw t E k t ω, ηdm t where k t is such that E λ tηdw t E k t tω, ηdm t is a square t integrable martingale and k t M t > 1. By heorem 3.1, a martingale measure is uniquely determined by the process k which appears in its representation. In particular, k = corresponds to the minimal martingale measure ˆP introduced by Föllmer and Schweizer [7]. he next proposition identifies P. Proposition 3.2. In the same assumptions as heorem 3.1, we have: d P dp = E λ t dw t E k t ηdm t where k t is a solution of the following equation exp E k λ2 t ηdt t ηdm t = [ E exp ] λ2 t ηdt such that E λ tdw t E k t t ηdm t is a square integrable martingale. t Remark 3.3. Proposition 3.2 shows how the change of measure works on Ω and H. In fact, provided that ˆP exists, we can write: d P dp = d P d ˆP d ˆP dp 9

where d ˆP dp = E λ t dw t and d P d ˆP = E exp [ exp λ2 t ηdt ] λ2 t ηdt Since in our model d P does not depend on ω, we have: d ˆP d P H dp H = E [ d P dp ] [ F d H = E P ] d ˆP d ˆP dp F H = d P [ d ˆP E d ˆP dp ] F H = d P d ˆP his provides a rule of thumb for changing measure from P to P via ˆP. First change P to ˆP by a direct use of Girsanov theorem: this amounts to replacing µ with r in 3, and is the key of risk-neutral valuation. P H is not affected by this step. In principle, one could repeat the same argument from ˆP to P, but this involves calculating the k t η. As we show with an example in the last section, this task may prove hard even in simple cases. A more viable alternative is calculating P H with the above formula. his avoids dealing with k directly, although its existence is still needed through Proposition 3.2. A sufficient condition for the existence of ˆP is the Novikov condition, namely: [ 1 ] E exp λ 2 t dt < 2 and is satisfied by all the examples in the last section. 4. Volatility jumps and Random Measures Although most markets models considered in the literature can be embedded in a framework consistent with heorem 3.1, there are some remarkable exceptions. For example, continuously distributed jumps in volatility can generate filtrations where no finite set of martingales has the representation property see the examples in the next section. In these cases, we can still represent martingales in terms of integrals with respect to a compensated random measure ν ν p, thereby obtaining an analogous of heorem 3.1 and Proposition 3.2. Note that the following results are complementary to those in the previous section, but do not directly generalize them: in fact any model with volatility following a diffusion process is covered in the previous section, and not in the present one. 1

heorem 4.1. If there exists a compensated, integer-valued, random measure ν ν p on E R + R such that: i F H coincides with the smallest filtration under which ν is optional; ii ν ν p has the representation property on H, F H, P H. hen we have for every Q M 2 e: dq dp = E λ t dw t E k ν ν p where k t is such that k ν t > 1 and E λ tdw t t E k ν νp t is a square integrable martingale. As in the previous section, we need these lemmas: Lemma 4.2. In the same assumptions as heorem 4.1, every square integrable martingale M t on the space Ω E, F Ω F H, P Ω P H with respect to F t can be written as M t = M + t h s dw s + k ν ν p t Proof. Let us denote the set of martingales for which the thesis hold by M. We want to show that M = M 2 Ω H. By representation property, every square integrable martingale M t ω on Ω H depending only on ω belongs to M, since it can be written as M t = M + t h sdw s. Analogously, every N t η belongs to M, since it is of the form N t = N + k ν ν p t, where k is a P-measurable process and k ν t is locally integrable. Denoting P t ω, η = N t ηm t ω, we have that P t is a square integrable martingale on Ω H. Setting P t = Pt d + Pt c, where Pt c and Pt d are the continuous and purely discontinuous parts of P, we have that P t = Pt d = M t N t. By 1.2, it follows that Pt d = P d + Mk ν ν p t. Also, by Itô s formula, Pt c = P c + t N sh s dw s. his shows that any linear combination i M iωn i η belongs to M and, by a monotone class argument, it is easy to see that M is dense in M 2. Hence, for every Z t M 2 there exist a sequence Xt n of squareintegrable martingales such that Xt n = X + t hn s dw s + k n ν ν p t. By the identity: [ ] E [X n ] = E h n s 2 ds + E [ ] ks n 2 νs p it follows that h n and k n are Cauchy sequences respectively in [ ] {h t η predictable: E h 2 sds < } and {k t η, x predictable: E [ k 2 s ν p s ] < } Since these spaces are complete, the proof is finished. 11

Lemma 4.3. Let Z be a strictly positive, square-integrable random variable and denote Z t = E [Z F t ]. hen, if Z t = Z + H ν ν p t, we have: H Z t = Z E ν ν p t. Z Proof. If there exists a martingale M t = M + K ν ν P t such that Z t = Z E M t, then it is unique. In fact, if N t = N + H ν ν P t and Z t = Z E N t, we immediately have M t = N t. Since M t and N t are purely discontinuous martingales by definition 1.2, they must coincide up to evanescent sets. In particular, we have that M t = Z t Z t. For all t >, Z t Z t coincides with the jumps of the purely discontinuous martingale H Z ν νp t, therefore M t exists and is given by M t = logz + H Z ν νp t. Proposition 4.4. In the same assumptions as heorem 4.1, we have: d P dp = E λ t dw t E k ν ν p where k t is a solution of the following equation exp E k ν ν p λ2 t ηdt = [ E exp ] λ2 t ηdt such that E λ tdw t k t E ν ν p is a square integrable martingale. t Proof. he proof is formally analogous to that of heorem 1.16 of [1], by the previous results and the representation property of the compensated random measure ν ν p. 5. Examples We now show how the results in the previous sections provide convenient tools for calculating P and thus pricing options in models where volatility jumps. We start with a simple model where jumps occur at fixed times, and can take only two values. We then discuss the more general cases of jumps occurring at stopping times, and with arbitrary distributions. 5.1. Deterministic volatility jumps. In discrete-time fashion, the following model was introduced in RiskMetrics Monitor [23] as an improvement of the standard lognormal model for calculating Value at Risk. We set H = {, 1} n and denote η = {a 1,..., a n }. a 1...., a n are Bernoulli IID random variable, so that H is endowed with the product 12

measure from {, 1}. Ft H contains all information on jumps up to time t, therefore it is equal to the parts of {a i } ti t. Setting t i = i, the n+1 dynamics of µ and σ is given by: { µ t = 1 { t<t1 }µ + n i=1 1 {t i t<t i+1 }µ ai σ t = 1 { t<t1 }σ + n i=1 1 {t i t<t i+1 }σ ai In fact, all we need for mean-variance hedging is the dynamics for λ: n λ 2 t = λ 2 + 1 {ti t<t i+1 }λ 2 a i i=1 It is easy to check that a martingale with the representation property on H is given by: M t = t i t 1 {a i =} p, where p = P a 1 =. We are now ready to see how the change of measure works: in fact, by heorem 3.1, we have that: d P d ˆP = d P H dp H = exp λ2 1 a1 + +a n n exp λ2 n p exp + 1 p exp λ2 n Since the density above can be written as: d P H n λ exp a 2 1 i = 1 a n i λ2 dp H p exp + 1 p exp i=1 λ2 n n a1 + +a n n λ2 1 n λ2 1 n n n it follows that under P the variables a 1,..., a n are still independent, and p is replaced by: p = p p exp λ2 n exp λ2 1 n + 1 p exp λ2 1 n 5.2. Random volatility jumps. Consider the following model, where µ and σ are constant, until some unexpected event occurs. In other words: { µ t = µ 1 1 {t<τ} + µ 2 1 {t τ} σ t = σ 1 1 {t<τ} + σ 2 1 {t τ} In fact, all we need is the dynamics for λ: λ 2 t = λ 2 1 + α1 {t τ} where α = λ 2 2 λ 2 1. he event τ which triggers the jump is a totally inaccessible stopping time. hat is to say, any attempt to predict it by means of previous information is deemed to failure. α represents the jump size, and it may be deterministic or random. We now solve the problem in three cases: α deterministic, α Bernoulli, and α continuously distributed. 13

5.2.1. α deterministic. Since our goal is to find the variance-optimal martingale measure, we start exhibiting a martingale with the representation property for F H, which in this case is the filtration generated by τ. Proposition 5.1. Let τ be a stopping time with a diffuse law, and à the compensator of 1 {τ t}. hen the martingale M t = 1 {τ t} Ãt has the representation property. Proof. Let Q be a martingale measure for M, and ÃQ the compensator of 1 {τ t} in Q. Both M t and 1 {τ t} ÃQ are Q-martingales, therefore their difference ÃQ à is also a martingale. However, it is also a finite variation process, therefore it must be identically zero. Since ÃQ = Ã, by Proposition 1.9, the c.d.f. s of τ under P and Q are equal. his implies that Q = P, F τ -a.e. heorem 1.12 concludes the proof. We now compute P H, that is the law of τ under P. For simplicity, assume that τ has a density, and denote it by f t. We have: f t = d P d ˆP f t = exp { λ2 sηds 1 = f t = exp λ c 1 + αt f t if t < 1 c exp λ c 1 f if t [ where c = E exp ] λ2 sηds. In this simple example we also calculate k t explicitly, although the computational effort required suggests that in more complex situations it may not be a good idea to do so. First, we see how stochastic integrals with respect to M look like. Recall that, by proposition 1.9 Ãt = at τ, where a : R + R +. Lemma 5.2. Let k t be a F τ -measurable process. hen we have: k t dm t = k τ τ1 {τ } τ k t tda t Proof. By Corollary 1.3, we have that any F τ -measurable process can be written as k t t τ. Hence: k t t τdm t =k τ τ1 {τ } =k τ τ1 {τ } =k τ τ1 {τ } τ τ k t t τda t τ = k t t τda t = k t tda t 14

he above lemma shows that k t s needs only be defined for s = t, so from now on we shall unambiguously write k t instead of k t t. Now we can compute k t : Proposition 5.3. k t is the unique solution of the following ODE: { k t = α + a t + αk t + a tkt 2 7 k = exp λ 2 2 1 c where c = exp λ 2 2 exp αt df t + exp λ 2 1 1 F and F t = P τ t. Proof. By lemma 5.2, and the generalization of Itô s formula for processes with jumps, we have: τ E k t ηdm t = E k τ 1 {τ } k t da t = Hence, by 3.2, we have: = 1 + k τ 1 {τ } exp τ k t da t τ 1 + kτ 1 {τ } exp k t da t = exp λ2 1 τ α [ E exp ] λ2 t dt [ aking logarithms of both sides, and setting c = E exp ] λ2 t dt, we get: ln τ 1 + k τ 1 {τ } k t da t = λ 2 1 τ α ln c Differentiating with respect to τ, for τ we obtain equation 7. Remark 5.4. Equation 7 is a Riccati ODE, and can be solved in terms of the function a t. Depending on the form of a t, explicit solutions may or may not be available. 5.2.2. α Bernoulli. In this case, α is a Bernoulli random variable, independent of τ, with values {α, α 1 }. We also set A = {α = α }, B = {α = α 1 }, and p = P B. Since the support of α is no longer a single point, a martingale will not be sufficient for representation purposes. In fact, two martingales do the job, as we prove in the following: Proposition 5.5. Let N t = 1 {τ t} 1 B p. hen the set of two martingales {M, N} has the representation property. 15

Proof. First we check that M and N are orthogonal. his is easily seen, since MN = Na τ. We now prove that the martingale measure is unique. Let Q be a martingale measure for {M, N}. As shown in the proof of Proposition 5.1, the distribution of τ under Q must be the same as under P. However, we also need that QB = P B, otherwise N would not be a martingale. he change from P to P is a change in the joint law of τ, α. Under P this is a product measure, since τ and α are independent. However, we cannot expect that the same holds under P. For t we have: d P H = 1 A exp λ 2 1 tα + 1 B exp λ 2 1 tα 1 dp H c herefore the law of τ under P is given by: f t = 1 c p exp λ 2 1 tα 1 + 1 p exp λ 2 1 tα ft And the conditional law of α with respect to τ is given by: P B τ dt = = p exp λ 2 1 tα 1 p exp λ 2 1 tα 1 + 1 p exp λ 2 1 tα In particular, it is immediately seen that α is independent of τ if and only if it degenerates in the previous case. When α is Bernoullian, calculating k involves solving a system of two Riccati ODEs, which is somewhat cumbersome. More generally, if the support of α is made of n points, it is reasonable that n martingales are required for representation purposes. As a result, the values of k would be the solutions of a system of n ODEs. 5.2.3. α continuously distributed. In this case the support of α is an infinite set, therefore heorem 3.1 is no longer applicable. In fact we need its random measure analogous, given by heorem 4.1. If the filtration F λ generated by λ t coincides with the one generated by µ t and σ t, we can assume F H = F λ. By Proposition 1.17, there exists a random measure ν associated to λ, and given by: νη; dt, dx = ɛ {τ,αη} dt, dx Since this is a multivariate point process, and F H coincides with the smallest filtration under which ν is optional, by heorem 1.22 the compensated measure ν ν p has the representation property on H. Also, k ν ν p is a purely discontinuous martingale for all P-measurable processes k, therefore [W, k ν ν p ] =. his means that the assumptions of heorem 4.1 are satisfied, and P is given by Proposition 4.4. 16

Suppose that α has a density, say gx. We have: d P H = ht, x = exp λ2 1 x t dp H c Denoting by jt, x and jt, x the joint densities of τ, α under P and P respectively, we have: jt, x = ht, xjt, x = ht, xftgx ft = ft ht, xgxdx gx t = jt, x ft = ht, xgx ht, xgxdx If α N δ, v, the density of τ under P is given by: + 1 f t = f t c exp λ 2 1 α t α δ n dα = v = 1 λ c exp 2 1 δ t + 1 2 t2 v where nx is the standard normal density function. It is easy to check that the conditional density of α given τ is of the form: gx t = 1 exp 1 x α + tv 2 2πv 2 v herefore α is conditionally normal under P, with distribution N δ + tv, v. Remark 5.6. In the specific case of λ t being normally distributed, it can be shown that G Θ is not closed, therefore Proposition 3.2 does not hold. However, in [1] the above formula is proved relaxing this assumption. It is also shown that in this example G Θ is closed if and only if the support of α is bounded from above. 5.2.4. Multiple random jumps. Leaving α deterministic for simplicity, we now study the following model: n λ 2 t = λ 2 + 1 {t τi }α i i=1 We assume that τ i+1 τ i are IID random variables, with common density fx. Denote by H the space [, ] n, endowed with the image measure of the mapping τ 1,..., τ n τ 1,..., τ n, and with the natural filtration F t generated by {τ 1 t,..., τ n t}. A martingale with the predictable representation property is given by M t = n i=1 1 {t τ i }. In this case, the density of P is given by: d P H = exp λ2 dp H 17 n i=1 α i τ i c f t