CLAS. Utility Functions Handout

Similar documents
Where are we? To do today: finish the derivation of the demand curve using indifference curves. Go on then to chapter Production and Cost

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Econ 100A: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes on Consumer Theory

Utility. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory Utility 1 / 15

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Problem Set 2 1/20/10

The fundamental question in economics is 2. Consumer Preferences

Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior

A Utility Maximization Example

Preferences. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Preferences 1 / 20

Theory of Demand. ECON 212 Lecture 7. Tianyi Wang. Winter Queen s Univerisity. Tianyi Wang (Queen s Univerisity) Lecture 7 Winter / 46

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Simple Model Economy. Business Economics Theory of Consumer Behavior Thomas & Maurice, Chapter 5. Circular Flow Model. Modeling Household Decisions

Demand. Lecture 3. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 4 1 / 58

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES

Constrained Optimisation

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Economic Principles Solutions to Problem Set 1

Sample Midterm Solutions

4.1 Ordinal versus cardinal utility

Economics 326: Duality and the Slutsky Decomposition. Ethan Kaplan

Prot Maximization and Cost Minimization

Felix Munoz-Garcia 1. School of Economic Sciences. Washington State University

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Economics 100 Exam 2

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Constrained Optimization: The Method of Lagrange Multipliers:

3. George W. Bush is the current U.S. President. This is an example of a: A. Normative statement B. Positive statement

CONSUMER PREFERENCES THE THEORY OF THE CONSUMER

MERSİN UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND ADMINISTRATIVE SCİENCES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MICROECONOMICS MIDTERM EXAM DATE

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

CHAPTER 7: CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Problem Set 2: Solutions ECON 301: Intermediate Microeconomics Prof. Marek Weretka. Problem 1 (Marginal Rate of Substitution)

Different Types of Tastes

Consumers face constraints on their choices because they have limited incomes.

Slutsky Equation. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Slutsky Equation 1 / 15

Indifference Curves: An Example (pp ) 2005 Pearson Education, Inc.

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Advanced Microeconomics

Production Function in the Long-Run. Business Economics Theory of the Firm II Production and Cost in the Long Run. Description of Technology

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior

Deriving MRS from Utility Function, Budget Constraints, and Interior Solution of Optimization

COST THEORY. I What costs matter? A Opportunity Costs

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem

Productioin OVERVIEW. WSG5 7/7/03 4:35 PM Page 63. Copyright 2003 by Academic Press. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Microeconomics Sept. 16, 2010 NOTES ON CALCULUS AND UTILITY FUNCTIONS

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory

Rutgers University Economics 102: Introductory Microeconomics Professor Altshuler Fall 2003

Lecture 9: Keynesian Models

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Chapter 10. Consumer Choice and Behavioral Economics

The formula to measure the rice elastici coefficient is Percentage change in quantity demanded E= Percentage change in price

LIST OF MEMBERS WHO PREPARED QUESTION BANK FOR ECONOMICS FOR CLASS XII TEAM MEMBERS. Sl. No. Name Designation

Week 1: Functions and Equations

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Utility Maximization

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

UTILITY AND DEMAND. Chapter. Household Consumption Choices

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

The Cost of Production

Elasticity. Ratio of Percentage Changes. Elasticity and Its Application. Price Elasticity of Demand. Price Elasticity of Demand. Elasticity...

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

ECN 221 Chapter 5 practice problems This is not due for a grade

Economics 10: Problem Set 3 (With Answers)

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture

Demand and Consumer Behavior emand is a model of consumer behavior. It attempts to identify the factors

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

1 The EOQ and Extensions

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

Microeconomic Theory: Basic Math Concepts

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

INTRODUCTION THE LABOR MARKET LABOR SUPPLY INCOME VS. LEISURE THE SUPPLY OF LABOR

Demand. See the Practical #4A Help Sheet for instructions and examples on graphing a demand schedule.

Natural Resources and International Trade

Profit and Revenue Maximization

Review of Production and Cost Concepts

Choice under Uncertainty

Lecture 3 : The Natural Exponential Function: f(x) = exp(x) = e x. y = exp(x) if and only if x = ln(y)

Chapter 4 NAME. Utility

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Tastes and Indifference Curves

Overview. Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Baye Chapters 4-5 Edited by DF 10/12. Consumer Behavior

Transcription:

Utility Functions Handout A big chunk of this class revolves around utility functions (AKA preferences). Bottom line, utility functions tell us how we prefer to consume goods so that we maximize our utility (benefit). Some goods, such as left and right shoes, need to be consumed together in a fixed ratio. Some goods have negative utility, meaning we want none of these goods (spoiled milk). There are many ways to describe preferences, and that is what utility functions do. Most of the time, our consumption will be limited by some type of budget constraint. Using our utility functions (how we want to consume) and our budget constraint (the restriction on how much we can consume) we can find our demand for each good. We are going to spend a lot of time finding demand. Our utility functions include perfect substitutes, perfect complements, Cobb-Douglas, quasilinear concave/convex, and max functions. Throughout this class, we will look at the SAME utility functions from DIFFERENT angles. First, we look at the utility functions through a basic budget constraint. Later we will look at the utility functions from a different angle by using a budget constraint that includes the effects of interest and inflation over time (the intertemporal budget constraint). When we look at utility functions from different angles, their underlying characteristics STA THE SAME, but solving the problems will be somewhat different. When we are looking at substitutes, regardless of whether we are using the budget constraint or the intertemporal budget constraint, we will want all of the good that gives the most bang for our buck. However, the variables we use to get to the solution are slightly different. When we go over a new angle at which to view the utility functions, lecture will only cover this new angle for some of the functions. This is no reason to get upset at the professors, since it would be impossible to cover every possibility in lecture. ou are expected to know how to solve for demand with ALL of the applicable functions from the new angle. This is a critical thinking class. ou should always be thinking about why a problem works the way it does, how it would change if you used a different utility function, and what would happen if you changed the variables. If you start thinking about problems as puzzles, the material is actually quite intuitive, and even fun! This handout introduces the utility functions using the normal budget constraint (Px + Py =m), but the general rules learned here apply to preferences no matter what angle we are using. Learning how to identify, characterize, and solve all of the utility functions now will make a significant portion of this class a lot easier. This guide is not exhaustive, nor does it replace lecture, section, hard work, ect. Take your time looking over this, and revisit it while you do the problems provided on the last page. Best of luck! 1

Perfect Substitutes U(,)= a +b In real life: Pepsi and coke OR Ice-cream and frozen yogurt OR apples and bananas Mathematical form: U(,) = + OR 4 + 5 OR 10 + Any monotonic transformation of +, such as ( + ) 3 OR + +100 Since the marginal utility of x and the marginal utility of y (Mux and Muy) are constant, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is constant (E MRS= -2 OR MRS = 5) Since the slope of the Indifference curves (IDCs) is the MRS, the IDCs are represented by a constant slope Key characteristic (Conceptual): Buy all of the good that gives the most BANG for your buck (utility per dollar spent) If both goods give the same bang for your buck, then you are indifferent between the two goods. ou could consume all of good, all of good, or some combination of the goods. Because the slope of the BC is the same as the slope of the IDC, any bundle on the BC are also on the same IDC (meaning all affordable points have the same utility) o Methods (know all of the different methods!) 1. Sketch a graph: Compare the MRS (Mux/Muy) to the price ratio (Px/Py) 2. Compare Bang for Buck: Compare the utility per dollar for both goods (Mux/Px and Muy/Py) 3. Compare utility levels: find utility if all good 1 is purchased versus all good 2 CHECK: AM I GETTING THE MOST UTILIT POSSIBLE? DO I SPEND ALL OF M INCOME? 2

Perfect Complements (Leontief) U(,)= Min(a,b) In real life: Left and right shoes OR tea and sugar Mathematical form: U(,)= Min (, /2) OR 5Min (, ) OR Min (5, 5) Any Monotonic transformation of Min (a, b) such as Min (a, b) + 100 OR 3Min (a, b) (Note: monotonic transformations do NOT change the ratio at which you want to consume perfect complements. They do change the total and marginal utility). Key Characteristic (Conceptual): Consume in a fixed ratio, where the two variables inside the Min function are equal. AKA, set the interior equal I want to make the MOST bundles I can, while paying as little as possible. This means that, if possible, I will not buy excess of one good that does not contribute to a bundle The Min function outputs the lower of 2 numbers. If our utility function is U(, )= Min (, ) and we consume at (10, 50), our function is Min (10, 50), which outputs 10. If we consume at (10, 10), our utility is once again 10, the lowest number The excess of at (10, 50) increases the amount we must pay, but not our utility If U(, ) = Min (, ) and is fixed at 15, how much is optimal? Do large values help? o Example: Peanut (B)utter and (J)elly U(B,J)= Min(4B, 2J) I want to make the most sandwiches I can. 1. Set the interior equal to find the fixed ratio at which to consume a. Consume at a fixed ratio 4B = 2J B = J/2. This means that for every unit of peanut butter, we want 2 units of jelly. This is the ratio needed to make a sandwich 2. Plug B=J/2 into the budget constraint 3. Once one variable is solved, plug it into the ratio (from setting the interior of the Min function equal) to get the other variable CHECK: DO I HAVE AN ECESS OF EITHER GOOD? DO I SPEND ALL OF M INCOME? 3

Cobb-Douglas U(,)= a α b β Mathematical form: U(,)= OR 1/2 5 1/3 OR 2 2 3 + 100 Any monotonic transformation of a α b β Key Characteristic (Mathematical): Use Tangency, which is the marginal rate of substitution set equal to the price ratio (MRS = Px/Py) MRS is always diminishing (our graph is convex), allowing us to use the tangency condition. The Tangency condition is only possible with DMRS. The slope of the budget line is Px/Py and the slope of the IDC is the MRS, so tangency is where MRS=Px/Py Tangency tells us where are budget line (what we can afford) intersects our IDC (what we want). Tangency finds the highest IDC that our budget constraint intersects, AKA the best point we can afford. Cobb-Douglas exponent trick: The fraction of the exponents tells us the proportion of income we spend on each good (Ex if U(,)= 1/2 1/2 spend half of your income on each) o Steps 1. Find MRS and test for diminishing MRS (DMRS). 1 Set MRS=Px/Py 2. Plug answer from 2 (solved for either or ) into the budget constraint 3. Plug in solved variable into the budget constraint or MRS=Px/Py to find the other variable CHECK: IS M MATH RIGHT? UNDERSTANDING PARTIAL DERIVATIVES IS CRUCIAL FOR COBB-DOUGLAS Test for DMRS If MRS decreases as increases and decreases, the function has DMRS. If MRS is constant for an increase in, but is decreasing for a decrease in, it is still has DMRS. When one is constant, the other dominates. MRS? 1 Cobb-Douglas always has DMRS. We test for to ensure we have a Cobb-Douglas function, and because it is a good step to show on tests. 4

Quasi-Linear For Quasi-linear Convex/Decreasing U(,)= V() + b For Quasi-linear Concave/Increasing Examples: + ln() OR 2 + 1/2 OR 2 + Any monotonic transformation of V() + b Quasi-linear Convex/Decreasing In Real life: cooking pans and ingredients OR pencils and all other goods In mathematical form: U(,)= ln() + OR + 2 1/2 Diminishing MRS, the function is convex o Example: cooking (P)ans and (I)ngredients 5 U(P,I) = 2P 1/2 + I Notice that Mu of ingredients is constant, while the Mu of pans is diminishing. This means that at some point buying an extra unit of ingredients will increase your utility by more than an extra pan. This is because, at some point, having more pans does not help you very much. The demand for the diminishing Mu good does not include income (M) in the equation (Ex P*=Pp 2 /PI 2 ). We call this a zero income-effect good, since the level of income does not change the amount demanded. In this case, pans are a zero income-effect good. For example, you want 1 pan regardless of how much money you have, and you will not buy any ingredients until you have one pan. Key Characteristic (Mathematical): Use Tangency. Do not consume any of the good with constant Mu until you have consumed the demanded amount of the good with diminishing Mu (the zero-income effect good). 1. Find MRS and test for IMRS or DMRS. Decreasing quasi-linear has DMRS, so use tangency 2. MRS=Px/Py (you will solve for the variable with diminishing Mu in this step) 3. Plug the solved variable into the budget constraint CHECK: IF I DON T HAVE ENOUGH INCOME, DID I MAKE SURE TO GET AS MUCH OF THE DIMINISHING GOOD AS POSSIBLE?

Max Quasi-Linear Concave/Increasing In Real Life: $10 dollar bills and cocaine Mathematical form: U(,) = 2 + 2y OR + 2 3 The function does not have DMRS and is therefore not convex. ou cannot use tangency. The function has increasing MRS, meaning the graph is concave. o Example $10 (B)ills and and (C)ocaine U(C,O)= 2C +O 2 $10 has constant Mu, while Cocaine has increasing Mu. Eventually the good with the increasing Mu will be better than the good with constant Mu. The first few $10 bills have higher Mu than small amounts of cocaine, but since cocaine is addictive, larger amounts of cocaine will have higher MU the $10 dollars. If you could only consume 1 unit total, would you want cocaine or $10? What If you could consume 100 units total? This is just an example, don t do drugs! Key Characteristic (conceptual): consume all of the good that gives the most utility 1. Find MRS, test to find DMRS or IMRS. Quasi-Linear Concave has IMRS 2. IMRS, can t use tangency, so consume all of one or the other 3. Compare all vs all and consume all of the good that gives the most utility U(,)= Max(,) Examples Max (3, ) OR 6Max(, 3) OR Max(2, 2) +100 Any monotonic transformation of Max(,) Max outputs the largest of 2 numbers: U(,)=Max(100,0) = 100 AND Max(100,50)=100 Our utility in both cases is 100, but the first is cheaper, so consume all of one good. Notice how the cheapest points on each IDC are the corners (all or all ) and Methods Key Characteristic (conceptual): consume all of the good that gives the most utility 1. Compare utility levels: compare all vs all and get the good with the most utility 6

Demand Problems Perfect Substitutes 1. U(, ) = 5 + 2 Px=6 Py=2 M=24 What is * and *? 2. U(, ) = 2 + 3 Px=2 Py=3 M=12 What is * and *? 3. U(, ) = 3 + No prices/income given 2 What is * and *? Perfect Complements 1. U(, ) = Min(2, ) Px=10 Py=2 M=28 What is * and *? a. What is Mux at (1,2)? At (3,2)? At (1,4)? 2. U(, ) = 5Min(, /5) Px=5 Py=1 M=30 =20 3 What is *? a. What would * and * be if was not fixed at 20? Cobb-Douglas 1. U(, ) = 2 No prices/income given What is * and *? a. What portion of income do you spend on and if U(, ) = x 2 y? If utility = x 1/2 y? Quasi-Linear Convex (Decreasing) 1. U(,) = 2 1/2 + No prices/income given What is * and *? a. What would * and * be if M=30 Py=5 Px=1 b. What would * and * be if M=3 Py=5 Px=1 2. U(, ) = + ln() No prices/income given What is * and *? Quasi-Linear Concave (Increasing) 1. U(, ) = 2 + 5 Px=5 Py=3 M=30 What is * and *? Max 1. U(, ) = 2Max(3, ) Px=4 Py=1 M=20 What is * and *? 2 When you are not given prices with a substitutes problem, you will need to find conditional demand. Conditional demand is an if then statement, which tells you what the demand will be if the prices are a certain amount. 3 Assume you are forced to purchase 20 units of 7