A Simple Reduced-Form Macroeconomic Model of CO 2 Emissions Dynamics

Similar documents
Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Optimal Health Insurance for Multiple Goods and Time Periods

A Comparison of Service Quality between Private and Public Hospitals in Thailand

Price-based versus quantity-based approaches for stimulating the development of renewable electricity: new insights in an old debate

From the Invisible Handshake to the Invisible Hand? How Import Competition Changes the Employment Relationship

Classical Electromagnetic Doppler Effect Redefined. Copyright 2014 Joseph A. Rybczyk

Suggested Answers, Problem Set 5 Health Economics

Supply chain coordination; A Game Theory approach

A Holistic Method for Selecting Web Services in Design of Composite Applications

AUDITING COST OVERRUN CLAIMS *

VOLUME 13, ARTICLE 5, PAGES PUBLISHED 05 OCTOBER DOI: /DemRes

Lemon Signaling in Cross-Listings Michal Barzuza*

Customer Efficiency, Channel Usage and Firm Performance in Retail Banking

On the Characteristics of Spectrum-Agile Communication Networks

The Optimal Deterrence of Tax Evasion: The Trade-off Between Information Reporting and Audits

Sebastián Bravo López

Static Fairness Criteria in Telecommunications

Open and Extensible Business Process Simulator

Electrician'sMathand BasicElectricalFormulas

RESEARCH SEMINAR IN INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS. Discussion Paper No The Evolution and Utilization of the GATT/WTO Dispute Settlement Mechanism

Capacity at Unsignalized Two-Stage Priority Intersections

Effectiveness of a law to reduce alcohol-impaired driving in Japan

A Robust Optimization Approach to Dynamic Pricing and Inventory Control with no Backorders

In order to be able to design beams, we need both moments and shears. 1. Moment a) From direct design method or equivalent frame method

The Basics of International Trade: A Classroom Experiment

1.3 Complex Numbers; Quadratic Equations in the Complex Number System*

An Efficient Network Traffic Classification Based on Unknown and Anomaly Flow Detection Mechanism

Working Paper Deriving the Taylor principle when the central bank supplies money

An integrated optimization model of a Closed- Loop Supply Chain under uncertainty

For example, the International Labour Office (1996) estimates that, worldwide, 120 million children between the ages of 5 and 14 work full-time.

arxiv:astro-ph/ v2 10 Jun 2003 Theory Group, MS 50A-5101 Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory One Cyclotron Road Berkeley, CA USA

5.2 The Master Theorem

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs

Trade Information, Not Spectrum: A Novel TV White Space Information Market Model

Context-Sensitive Adjustments of Cognitive Control: Conflict-Adaptation Effects Are Modulated by Processing Demands of the Ongoing Task

4.15 USING METEOSAT SECOND GENERATION HIGH RESOLUTION VISIBLE DATA FOR THE IMPOVEMENT OF THE RAPID DEVELOPPING THUNDERSTORM PRODUCT

Learning Curves and Stochastic Models for Pricing and Provisioning Cloud Computing Services

) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) (1)

Findings and Recommendations

HOW TO CALCULATE PRESSURE ANYWHERE IN A PUMP SYSTEM? Jacques Chaurette p. eng. April 2003

university of illinois library AT URBANA-CHAMPAIGN BOOKSTACKS

Measurement of Powder Flow Properties that relate to Gravity Flow Behaviour through Industrial Processing Lines

The Reduced van der Waals Equation of State

Paid Placement Strategies for Internet Search Engines

Weighting Methods in Survey Sampling

Performance Analysis of IEEE in Multi-hop Wireless Networks

Chapter 5 Single Phase Systems

Soft-Edge Flip-flops for Improved Timing Yield: Design and Optimization

Henley Business School at Univ of Reading. Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development (CIPD)

Optimal Sales Force Compensation

OPTIMAL TAXATION AND SOCIAL INSURANCE IN A LIFETIME PERSPECTIVE

International Journal of Supply and Operations Management. Mathematical modeling for EOQ inventory system with advance payment and fuzzy Parameters

State of Maryland Participation Agreement for Pre-Tax and Roth Retirement Savings Accounts

THE PERFORMANCE OF TRANSIT TIME FLOWMETERS IN HEATED GAS MIXTURES

Monetary Policy, Leverage, and Bank Risk-Taking

From a strategic view to an engineering view in a digital enterprise

Job Creation and Job Destruction over the Life Cycle: The Older Workers in the Spotlight

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF SCIENTIFIC & TECHNOLOGY RESEARCH VOLUME 3, ISSUE 12, December 2014 ISSN

Table of Contents. Appendix II Application Checklist. Export Finance Program Working Capital Financing...7

Henley Business School at Univ of Reading. Pre-Experience Postgraduate Programmes Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development (CIPD)

In many services, the quality or value provided by the service increases with the time the service provider

DSP-I DSP-I DSP-I DSP-I

Granular Problem Solving and Software Engineering

Dynamic and Competitive Effects of Direct Mailings

Zentrum für Entwicklungsforschung Center for Development Research Universität Bonn. Oded Stark and C. Simon Fan

User s Guide VISFIT: a computer tool for the measurement of intrinsic viscosities

UNIVERSITY AND WORK-STUDY EMPLOYERS WEB SITE USER S GUIDE

Online Energy Generation Scheduling for Microgrids with Intermittent Energy Sources and Co-Generation

Globalization, Jobs, and Welfare: The Roles of Social Protection and Redistribution 1

A novel active mass damper for vibration control of bridges

Computer Networks Framing

Motivations for swap-covered foreign currency borrowing

cos t sin t sin t cos t

Deadline-based Escalation in Process-Aware Information Systems

Fixed-income Securities Lecture 2: Basic Terminology and Concepts. Present value (fixed interest rate) Present value (fixed interest rate): the arb

Can October Surprise? A Natural Experiment Assessing Late Campaign Effects

Market power and banking failures

Impact Simulation of Extreme Wind Generated Missiles on Radioactive Waste Storage Facilities

WORKFLOW CONTROL-FLOW PATTERNS A Revised View

A Three-Hybrid Treatment Method of the Compressor's Characteristic Line in Performance Prediction of Power Systems

THE EFFECT OF WATER VAPOR ON COUNTERFLOW DIFFUSION FLAMES

Deliverability on the Interstate Natural Gas Pipeline System

Channel Assignment Strategies for Cellular Phone Systems

INCOME TAX WITHHOLDING GUIDE FOR EMPLOYERS

HEAT CONDUCTION. q A q T

Procurement auctions are sometimes plagued with a chosen supplier s failing to accomplish a project successfully.

Tax-loss Selling and the Turn-of-the-Year Effect: New Evidence from Norway 1

Relativity in the Global Positioning System

Resources Invested in Education

SLA-based Resource Allocation for Software as a Service Provider (SaaS) in Cloud Computing Environments

INCOME TAX WITHHOLDING GUIDE FOR EMPLOYERS

Computational Analysis of Two Arrangements of a Central Ground-Source Heat Pump System for Residential Buildings

A Theoretical Analysis of Credit Card Reform in Australia *

NOTA DI LAVORO. Cultural Diversity and Economic Performance: Evidence from European Regions

Impedance Method for Leak Detection in Zigzag Pipelines

INVESTIGATION OF STABILITY ON NONLINEAR OSCILATIONS WITH ONE DEGREE OF FREEDOM

A Reputation Management Approach for Resource Constrained Trustee Agents

Cournot Equilibrium in Price-capped Two-Settlement Electricity Markets

Customer Reporting for SaaS Applications. Domain Basics. Managing my Domain

Transcription:

A Simple Redued-Form Maroeonomi Model of CO 2 Emissions Dynamis Gerard H. Kuper July 29 Abstrat The present paper explains CO 2 emissions in a non-linear maroeonomi model. We derive a relationship between CO 2 emissions, investment, and eonomi growth, and indiate under what onditions arbon dioxide emissions may be redued. The theoretial model shows that the effet on CO 2 emissions of investment in green tehnologies may redue CO 2 emissions depending on the initial level of CO 2 emissions and on eonomi growth. We test the model with World Bank data for a wide seletion of ountries for the period 196-25, and for the eight rihest ountries (G-8) as well as for the eight biggest polluters (P-8). High eonomi growth leads to more CO 2 emissions unless green investment inreases. Key words: CO 2 emissions, Non-Linear Models, Stability, Investment JEL lassifiation: O13, Q32, Q53. Department of Eonomis and Eonometris, University of Groningen, the Netherlands. Correspondene onerning this artile should be addressed to Gerard H. Kuper, Department of Eonomis and Eonometris, University of Groningen, P.O. Box 8, 97 AV Groningen, The Netherlands. Phone: +31 5 363 3756, E-mail: g.h.kuper@rug.nl. 1

1 Introdution The relationship between eonomi ativity and pollution is a omplex one. In this study we only fous on atmospheri pollution. More speifially,we onsider emissions of one of the greenhouse gases regulated by Kyoto protool: arbon dioxide (CO 2 ) whih is to a large extent responsible for the inrease of CO 2 (Battle et al., 2). 1 We analyze stability of the relationship between eonomi ativity, measured by real prodution, and CO 2 emissions. We also show the effet of investments in tehnologies that redue CO 2 emissions green investment on this relationship. It is shown that these investments are ompatible with positive rates of eonomi growth (f. Azar and Shneider, 22). It should be noted that we are not onerned with optimal CO 2 emissions poliies (f. Wirl, 26, 27) nor with ostbenefit analysis or other (see Azar (1998) for a ritial disussion of these issues). Figure 1 shows how CO 2 emissions per apita inreases in the period 196 27. 2 The mean aross a seletion of 192 ountries steadily inreases, but the standard deviation is very large espeially before the 198s. More reently, the standard deviation of CO 2 emissions per apita inreases again. The ountries with the highest CO 2 emissions per apita inlude Kuwait (> 3), Qatar (> 6) and the United Arab Emirates (> 3). In the United States of Ameria, CO 2 emissions are about 2 metri tons per apita, while in Canada it is over 16 metri tons per apita. In China, CO 2 emissions 1 The differene between CO 2 emission, whether natural or man made, and arbon inrease in the atmosphere is what is absorbed in oeans or by vegetation eah year. 2 The data are downloaded from the online World Development Indiators database. 2

Figure 1: CO 2 emissions in metri tons per apita (mean and 1% standard deviation of 192 ountries); Soure: World Development Indiators by the World Bank 2 15 Mean +/- 1 S.D. 1 5-5 -1 196 1965 197 1975 198 1985 199 1995 2 25 are about 4 metri tons per apita. However, China and India have a large population, so total CO 2 emissions (kt) are high and rapidly inreasing as inome grows (see Auffhammer and Carson, 28). Reently, China has overtaken the USA as the ountry with the highest total CO 2 emissions. This is illustrated in Figure 2 whih shows eight ountries with the highest emissions of arbon dioxide. In this paper we refer to these biggest polluters as the P-8 ountries. Not surprisingly, six of these P-8 ountries belong to the eight rihest industrialized ountries. Ukraine and India are replaed by Frane and Canada to omplete the G-8. This paper is not diretly related to the widely disussed Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) that relates per apita arbon dioxide emissions and real Gross Domesti Produt (GDP) per apita (surveyed for instane in 3

Figure 2: CO 2 emissions for the eight biggest polluters (kilotons, log-sale); Soure: World Development Indiators by the World Bank 1,, 7,, 5,, 3,, 2,, 1,, 7, 5, Japan USA China Russia Germany United Kingdom 3, 2, India Ukraine 1, 196 1965 197 1975 198 1985 199 1995 2 25 Dinda, 24). The empirial results of this relationship are ambiguous, whih led some authors to question relevane of the EKC and others to study the robustness of the EKC. Examples are Galeotti, Lanza and Pauli (26) and Vollebergh, Melenberg and Dijkgraaf (29). Reently, Lee and Lee (29) disuss the stationarity properties of per apita arbon dioxide emissions and real GDP per apita whih are important the speifiation and impliations of the EKC. The next setion derives the theoretial model, and disusses various senarios. The impliations for arbon dioxide emissions are analyzed in Setion 3. In Setion 4 we present the data we use in the empirial part. The estimation results are shown in Setion 5. These results are interpreted in Setion 6. 4

2 The Model Denote by C(t) the CO 2 emissions in period t. We assume that the hange of C(t) is affeted by investment in tehnologies I(t) that redue CO 2 emissions (denoted as green investment). These green tehnologies may inlude tehnologies that aptures and stores CO 2 (f. Sulzewski and Juanes, 29). I(t) is the balane of ativities that inrease the emission of arbon dioxide, like fossil fuel ombustion, or redue the ability to onsume these gases. A negative value of I(t) indiates that investment ativities on balane redue the emission of arbon dioxide. Furthermore, it is assumed that the level of CO 2 emissions affets the hange in CO 2 emissions at the rate x(t). x(t) may be negative, but an also be positive. More about this later. In mathematial form, this is expressed as: dc(t) dt Ċ(t) = I(t) + x(t)c(t). (1) Defining (t) C(t)/Y (t) and i(t) I(t)/Y (t), we an rewrite Equation (1) as a fration of real output or prodution Y (t) as follows: Ċ(t) Y (t) The dynamis of the C(t)/Y (t) ratio is desribed by: = i(t) + x(t)(t). (2) where y(t) ln Y (t). ċ(t) = Ċ(t) (t)ẏ(t) = i(t) + [x(t) ẏ(t)] (t), (3) Y (t) We assume that the absorption apaity may inrease of derease. This is 5

indiated by funtion x(t). Green investment may redue CO 2 emissions by inreasing the absorption apaity in whih ase x(t) is negative. We, rather ad ho, introdue a damage funtion d(t), that for sake of onveniene, is assumed to be linear in (t). More realistially the damage funtion may be stohasti to reflet unertainties, and my even inlude jumps to inlude atastrophi events (see Dumas and Ha-Duong, 25). In mathematial form: x(t) = αi(t) + d(t) = αi(t) + β(t). (4) Obviously, the results depend on the sign of feedbak parameter β. For positive β, high values for (t) lead to inreasing arbon dioxide emissions for given values of i(t), while negative values for β redue emissions. Substituting this equation in Equation (5) yields: ċ(t) = Ċ(t) Y (t) (t)ẏ(t) = i(t) + [αi(t) + β(t) ẏ(t)] (t) = i(t) + [αi(t) ẏ(t)] (t) + β 2 (t). (5) This equation is a non-linear first-order differential equation in terms of (t). If the model has real roots then the time profile of state variable (t) depends on the initial value () and the ontrol variables i(t) and ẏ(t). Assuming, for instane, that αi(t) < ẏ(t) and i(t) >, the slope of the ċ(t)-urve is negative for (t) = and rosses the vertial axis for positive values of ċ(t). 3 3 If parameter β =, the model is linear model (see Appendix A). 6

2.1 Positive feedbak For positive values for β the ċ-urve is onvex. Two senarios an emerge whih are shown in Figure 3. Figure 3: Equilibrium and stability in the non-linear model i a 1 2 b The dashed urve shows the situation where there are no real roots. The other urve assumes two real roots, one that is loally stable and a higher one that is unstable. There are no real roots if (αi(t) ẏ(t)) 2 4βi(t) <. (6) in whih ase (t) inreases indefinitely as indiated by the arrows on the dashed urve. Starting in point a and reduing the interept, that is dereasing i(t), we may move to point b on the drawn urve, and ultimately we end in the stable equilibrium in point 1. There are four ases depending on the signs of αi(t) ẏ(t) and i(t). Table 4 summarizes the four ases. 7

Table 1: Possible ases with positive feedbak αi(t) ẏ(t) < αi(t) ẏ(t) > i(t) > ase 1 ase 3 real roots if (αi(t) ẏ(t)) 2 4βi(t) > i(t) < ase 2 ase 4 no imaginary roots 2.1.1 Case 1 Case 1 is the situation desribed above with ẏ > αi(t) > and real roots. In this ase the slope of the ċ(t)-urve is negative for (t) = and intersets the positive part of the vertial axis. In point 1 in Figure 3 CO 2 emissions per unit of prodution are stabilized, but CO 2 emissions still rise as is shown in Figure 4(a), in whih we add the urve that desribes the hange in CO 2 emissions per unit of prodution Ċ(t)/Y (t): Ċ(t) Y (t) = i(t) + αi(t)(t) + β2 (t). (7) The ċ(t)-urve and the Ċ(t)/Y (t)-urve ross at the vertial axis. Sine ẏ(t) > αi(t) >, the slope of Ċ(t)/Y (t)-urve is steeper for (t) =, than the ċ(t)-urve. At the loally stable equilibrium ċ(t) =, but Ċ(t)/Y (t) is positive. Sine ẏ(t) >, emissions inrease faster than the growth rate of prodution. 8

Figure 4: Different CO 2 emissions senarios with positive feedbak (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2,, i 1 1 2 2 () Case 3 (d) Case 4,, 2 1 2 1 2.1.2 Case 2 Case 2 whih is illustrated in Figure 4(b) is haraterized by ẏ(t) > αi(t) i(t) <. Sine i(t) is negative, both urves ross the vertial axis below. At the new loally stable equilibrium 1, Ċ(t)/Y (t) is negative. Like in ase 1, αi(t) < ẏ(t), so that, depending on the initial value of (), positive prodution growth is possible and emissions are redued. 2.1.3 Case 3 Two more ases an be distinguished if αi(t) > ẏ(t). Case 3 is haraterized by i(t) > and real roots. In this ase, there are two negative real roots 9

and Ċ(t)/Y (t) inreases at the loally stable equilibrium. This is shown in Figure 4(). In the loally stable equilibrium ċ(t) =, so that CO 2 emissions grow at the same rate as prodution whih may be negative depending on the initial value of (t). 2.1.4 Case 4 The last ase is haraterized by ẏ(t) < αi(t) <, so that prodution growth is negative. Figure 4(d) illustrates that Ċ(t)/Y (t) inreases. So emissions may inrease or derease depending on the initial value of (t). Figure 5: Different CO 2 emissions senarios with negative feedbak (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2,, 1 2 1 2 () Case 3 (d) Case 4,, 1 2 1 2 1

2.2 Negative feedbak For negative values for β the ċ urve is onave as is shown in Figure 5. Here we assume that there are real roots. Only in ase 2 are CO 2 emissions falling if the model is in its stable equilibrium. The major differene with the model in whih β is positive is that for high initial values of (t) the model moves towards its stable equilibrium. Emissions per unit of output stabilize, but total emissions stabilize in three out of four ases. Only in ase 1 will total emissions inrease for ever. This stands in sharp ontrast with the model in whih β is positive. We will illustrate the differenes in the next setion. 3 Impliations 3.1 Positive feedbak In the previous setion we illustrate that it is possible to redue CO 2 emissions, even at positive rates of prodution growth, as long as investment is aimed at ativities that redue the emission of arbon dioxide, so that i(t) <. There are two unambiguous ases, these are ases 1 and 2. Only the seond ase leads to a redution in the emission of arbon dioxide provide the initial value of the state variable is lower than the unstable equilibrium. In ases 3 and 4 the effet on CO 2 emissions is ambiguous. Case 4 obviously is the more favorable one sine investment is green and aimed at reduing CO 2. Obviously the effet depends on the initial onditions. Espeially if CO 2 emission per unit of prodution in the initial period is high, there an 11

only be lower CO 2 emissions if there are large investments aimed at ativities that redue the emission of arbon dioxide. Figure 6: Time paths of CO 2 emissions senarios with positive feedbak and with favorable initial onditions () = 1 (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2 ê ê.35.7.15.1.3.25.2.15.1.5 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 period.6.5.4.3.2.1.1 -.1.5 -.2 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1-.3 -.5 -.4 -.1 -.5 period () Case 3 (d) Case 4.7.6.5.4.3.2.1 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 period ê.35.3.25.2.15.1.5.1.9.8.7.6.5.4.3.2.1 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 period ê.18.16.14.12.1.8.6.4.2 The effets are dependent on the initial value of the state variable and the values of the ontrol variables. Assuming positive roots, Figure 6 simulates the time profiles of Ċ(t)/Y (t) and total emissions Ċ(t)/Y (t) starting at a very favorable initial values () = 1, in whih ase total arbon in the atmosphere is redued. Figure 7 simulates similar paths starting at less favorable initial values () = 1, and assuming real roots. In two of these ases emissions inrease without bounds. 12

Figure 7: Different time paths of CO 2 emissions with positive feedbak and with unfavorable initial onditions () = 1 (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2 ê ê.35.7.1.1.3.25.2.15.1.6.5.4.3.2.5 -.1 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1-.2 -.5 -.3.5 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 period.1 -.1 -.15 period -.4 -.5 () Case 3 (d) Case 4 ê ê 2,25 8 2,5 18 16 14 12 1 8 6 4 2 1 1 19 28 period,2,15,1,5 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 1 1 19 28 period 2 1,5 1,5 13

3.2 Negative feedbak The effets in ase β is negative are shown in Figure 8. In ases 3 and 4 emissions are ultimately stabilized. Only ase 2 shows a redution in CO 2 emissions. Case 1 leads to ever inreasing arbon dioxide emissions. Figure 8: Time paths of CO 2 emissions senarios with negative feedbak and initial onditions () = 1 (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2 ê ê.15.1.5.4 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 -.5 -.1.5.3.2 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 -.5.1 -.1 -.15 -.2 -.25 -.2 -.3 -.4 -.1 -.3 -.5 -.15 period -.1 -.35 period -.6 () Case 3 (d) Case 4 ê -.1 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 -.2 -.2 -.4 -.3 -.6 -.4 -.8 -.5 -.1 -.6 -.7 -.12 -.8 -.14 -.9 -.16 -.1 -.18 period ê 1 1 19 28 37 46 55 64 73 82 91 1 -.1 -.5 -.2 -.1 -.3 -.15 -.4 -.2 -.5 -.25 -.6 -.3 -.7 -.35 period 14

4 Data The model above suggest a relationship between the hange in arbon dioxide per unit of output on the one hand and investment per unit of output, the square of CO 2 emissions per unit of output, and the interation between investment per unit of output and output growth with CO 2 emissions per unit of output on the other hand. The panel data we use to estimate the model are from the World Development Indiators database ompiled by the World Bank. These series are: [ 1 ] CO2 emissions (metri tons per apita); [ 2 ] Total population; [ 3 ] GDP (urrent US$); [ 4 ] GDP growth (annual %); [ 5 ] Inflation, GDP deflator (annual %); [ 6 ] GDP deflator is alulated from [5] with 25=1; [ 7 ] Gross apital formation (% of GDP); [ 8 ] Adjusted net savings (% of Gross National Inome); [ 9 ] CO 2 per unit of GDP is alulated as [1]*[2]/([3]/[6]). Adjusted net savings are equal to net national savings plus eduation expenditure and minus energy depletion, mineral depletion, net forest depletion, and arbon dioxide. This series exludes partiulate emissions damage. Adjusted net saving also known as genuine saving (Hamilton and Clemens, 1999 is a proxy for sustainability. In the empirial model we use gross fixed apital formation (% of GDP) and the adjusted net savings rate (% of GNI) for investment, denoted below 15

as s t and k t, respetively. The latter is more relevant for analyzing sustainable growth, although it is ritized. For example Ferreira and Vinent (25) point at measurement errors and show that adjustments for depreiation of produed apital, depletion of natural apital, and investment in human apital do not add muh preditive power. Critique by Pillarisetti (25) and Valente (28) is more fundamental. Pillarisetti (25) shows that the measure is oneptually and empirially imperfet sine it is based on weak sustainability assuming perfet substitutability between different types of apital inluding physial, natural and human apital. Valente (28) argues that the sign of urrent genuine savings might deliver a false message: Positive genuine savings in the present does not guarantee sustainability in the future. The series are shown in Figure 9. The panel is unbalaned with data for CO 2 emissions per unit of output ( t ) for 177 ountries and 6,213 observations, Annual % GDP growth (ẏ t ) data for 198 ountries and 7,69 observations, data for adjusted net savings (% of GNI) for 15 ountries and 3,87 observations, and data for gross apital formation (% of GDP) for 182 ountries and 6,491 observations. The graph shows a strong inrease in CO 2 emissions per unit of GDP sine 199. The standard deviation also inreases whih indiates that aross the full sample of ountries the variation aross ountries inreases. Adjusted net savings seems to drop towards the end of the sample, whereas gross apital formation remains at a high level. Applying a range of panel unit root tests reveals that for ċ t, ẏ t, s t and k t the null of a unit root is rejeted. 16

Figure 9: Variables used in the model (means and 1% standard deviation bounds); Soure: World Development Indiators by the World Bank.2 Carbon dioxide emissions per unit of GDP 2 Annual GDP growth (%).15.1.5. 15 1 5-5 -.5 196 197 198 199 2-1 196 197 198 199 2 3 2 1-1 Adjusted net savings (% GDP) 36 32 28 24 2 16 12 Gross apital formation (% GDP) -2 196 197 198 199 2 8 196 197 198 199 2 5 Estimation results The empirial ounter part of Equation (5) in disrete time, where the state variable is lagged, is: ċ j,t = γ j + γ t + γ 1 i j,t + γ 2 (i j,t j,t 1 ) + γ 3 (ẏ j,t j,t 1 ) + γ 4 2 j,t 1, (8) where j = 1,..., N with N the number of ountries, and i t is either k t or s t. Parameter γ 4 is the feedbak parameter β from the theoretial model. The 17

marginal effets are: ċ j,t j,t 1 = γ 2 i j,t + γ 3 ẏ j,t + 2γ 4 j,t 1, (9) ċ j,t i j,t = γ 1 + γ 2 j,t 1, (1) ċ j,t ẏ j,t = γ 3 j,t 1. (11) We estimate the model using World Bank data and apply panel least squares inluding ross setion fixed effets and period fixed effets. 4 The results are shown in Table 2. In all estimations we use White ross setion robust standard errors and ovarianes, making the estimator robust to rossequation (ontemporaneous) orrelation. The estimation results lead to some onlusions: 1. Parameter γ 4 is negative, and even signifiant for the G-8 and the P-8. This implies a negative feedbak: high emission levels lowers emissions per unit of GDP (everything else being equal). 2. For the full set of ountries γ 4 does not differ signifiantly from zero, implying a linear ċ-urve. 3. Adjusted net savings have a negative impat on the hange in CO 2 per unit GDP, as expeted. However, the level of signifiane is only 1%. 4. Gross fixed apital formation does not affet the hange in CO 2 per unit GDP diretly. 4 The hoie of ross setion fixed effets and period fixed effets is onfirmed by likelihood ratio tests. 18

Table 2: Estimation results for different seletions of ountries, with t-values between brakets Dependent variable: Change in CO 2 emissions per unit of GDP All ountries G-8 P-8 Variable (a) (b) () (d) (e) (f) onstant 6.3E-5 4.1E-5 1.6E-4 1.4E-4 2.7E-4 2.9E-4 (8.697) (4.942) (1.991) (.888) (2.718) (1.34) k t -4.5E-5-9.E-4 -.1 (-.889) (-1.87) (-1.268) s t -1.2E-4 -.1 -.2 (-1.737) (-1.758) (-1.891) ẏ t t 1-1.37 -.689 1.63 -.12.251 -.1 (-2.557) (-3.48) (2.18) (-.69) (.425) (-.6) k t t 1.63.877.755 (.647) (2.339) (1.769) s t t 1 -.111.628.688 (-.892) (1.561) (1.455) 2 t 1-9.944-1.544-76.442-12.124-43.94-64.396 (-1.51) (-1.587) (-2.711) (-3.79) (-2.178) (-2.46) Countries 151 17 8 8 8 8 Obs. 376 559 233 36 218 289 R 2.19.137.221.192.271.266 These are the diret effets. There are also indiret effets: 1. For the full sample of ountries a high level of CO 2 emissions leads to a drop in emissions for high rates of GDP growth. 2. For the G-8 and the P-8 high adjusted net savings redue CO 2 emissions, but the effet is moderated if the level of emissions initially is high. 19

3. For the G-8 and the P-8 gross apital formation inreases CO 2 emissions if the level of emissions is high. 6 Disussion In this setion we interpret the estimated equation in terms of the theoretial model and fous on the interept and slope of the ċ-urve. The interept is alulated as γ 1 s, where s is the mean of adjusted net savings. Higher adjusted net savings is interpreted as green investment (negative i(t) in the theoretial model). The slope is alulated as γ 2 s + γ 3 ẏ, where ẏ is mean GDP growth. For all ountries, the interept and the slope is negative, whih resembles ase 2 with negative feedbak, whih may lead to falling CO 2 emissions. For the G-8 and also for the P-8 the interept is negative, but the slope is positive. This is ase 4 in terms of the senarios desribed in the theoretial model, whih leads to lower CO 2 emissions. It should be noted that, beause of various issues with the onept of genuine savings, positive adjusted net savings is no guarantee for sustainability and that in terms of our model the interept is positive and we may end up in ase 1 with inreasing CO 2 emissions. High growth requires positive genuine savings (measured in the orret way) in order to redue CO 2 emissions permanently. The sample ends before the start of the urrent worldwide eonomi reession. Taking into aount that GDP growth is estimated to be -4% in 29, this turns the estimated slope positive for the full sample. So, we move to ases 3 or 4 where CO 2 emissions are lower, but stabilize. The preferred 2

ase is ase 2 where CO 2 emissions ontinue to drop whih requires higher net adjusted savings and investments, whih is probably a more diffiult task in a reession. 21

Referenes Auffhammer, M. and R. Carson (28). Foreasting the path of hinas CO 2 emissions using provine-level information. Journal of Environmental Eonomis and Management 55, 229 247. Azar, C. (22). Are optimal CO 2 emissions really optimal? Environmental and Resoure Eonomis 11(3 4), 31 315. Azar, C. and S. Shneider (22). Are the eonomi osts of stabilising the atmosphere prohibitive? Eologial Eonomis 42(1), 73 8. Battle, M., M. L. Bender, P. P. Tans, J. W. White, J. T. Ellis, T. Conway, and R. J. Franey (2). Global arbon sinks and their variability inferred from atmospheri O 2 and δ 13 C. Siene 287 (5462), 2467 247. Dinda, S. (24). Environmental kuznets urve hypothesis: A survey. Eologial Eonomis 49, 431 455. Dumas, P. and M. Ha-Duong (25). An abrupt stohasti damage funtion to analyze limate poliy benefits. In A. Haurie and L. Viguier (Eds.), The Coupling of Climate and Eonomi Dynamis: Essays on Integrated Assessment, Volume 22, Chapter 4, pp. 97 111. Dordreht: Springer Netherlands. Ferreira, S. and J. Vinent (25). Genuine savings: Leading indiator of sustainable development? Eonomi Development and Cultural Change 53 (3), 737 754. Galeotti, M., A. Lanza, and F. Pauli (26). Reassessing the environmental 22

Kuznets urve for CO 2 emissions: A robustness exerise. Eologial Eonomis 57, 152 163. Hamilton, K. and M. Clemens (1999). Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Countries. World Bank Eon Rev 13 (2), 333 356. Lee, C.-C. and J.-D. Lee (29). Inome and CO 2 emissions: Evidene from panel unit root and ointegration tests. Energy Poliy 37, 413 423. Pillarisetti, J. (25). The world bank s genuine savings measure and sustainability. Eologial Eonomis 55 (4), 599 69. Szulzewski, M. and R. Juanes (29). A simple but rigorous model for alulating CO 2 storage apaity in deep saline aquifers at the basin sale. Energy Proedia 1, 337 3314. Valente, S. (28). Optimal growth, genuine savings and long-run dynamis. Sottish Journal of Politial Eonomy 55 (2), 21 226. Vollebergh, H., B. Melenberg, and E.Dijkgraaf (29). Identifying reduedform relations with panel data: The ase of pollution and inome. Journal of Environmental Eonomis and Management 58, 27 42. Wirl, F. (26). Consequenes of irreversibilities on optimal intertemporal CO 2 emission poliies under unertainty. Resoure and Energy Eonomis 28, 15 123. Wirl, F. (27). Corrigendum to Consequenes of irreversibilities on optimal intertemporal CO 2 emission poliies under unertainty. Resoure and Energy Eonomis 29, 325 326. World Bank. World Development Indiators. 23

A Linear model Again, there are four ases whih are shown in Figure A.1. Cases 1 and 2 where αi(t) ẏ(t) < are stable. Figure A.1: Different CO 2 emissions senarios for the linear model (a) Case 1 (b) Case 2,, 1 1 () Case 3 (d) Case 4,, 1 1 24