Monetary Economics Note 3

Similar documents
Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lectures 2 and 3: The Solow Growth Model

Chapter 7: Economic Growth part 1

MASTER IN ENGINEERING AND TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT

INTRODUCTION TO ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS Preliminary Exam with answers September 2014

19 : Theory of Production

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I

Chapters 7 and 8 Solow Growth Model Basics

Economic Growth: Lectures 6 and 7, Neoclassical Growth

Sample Midterm Solutions

To give it a definition, an implicit function of x and y is simply any relationship that takes the form:

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Economic Growth: Theory and Empirics (2012) Problem set I

Advanced Microeconomics

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

2. With an MPS of.4, the MPC will be: A) 1.0 minus.4. B).4 minus 1.0. C) the reciprocal of the MPS. D).4. Answer: A

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

John Kennan University of Wisconsin-Madison October, 1998

Long Run Growth Solow s Neoclassical Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 11, Technology Diffusion, Trade and World Growth

3. Reaction Diffusion Equations Consider the following ODE model for population growth

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

The previous chapter introduced a number of basic facts and posed the main questions

Agenda. Long-Run Economic Growth, Part 1. The Sources of Economic Growth. Long-Run Economic Growth. The Sources of Economic Growth

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

2x + y = 3. Since the second equation is precisely the same as the first equation, it is enough to find x and y satisfying the system

The Solow Model. Savings and Leakages from Per Capita Capital. (n+d)k. sk^alpha. k*: steady state Per Capita Capital, k

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

WEB APPENDIX. Calculating Beta Coefficients. b Beta Rise Run Y X

Piecewise Cubic Splines

MATRIX ALGEBRA AND SYSTEMS OF EQUATIONS

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Investment

Calibration of Normalised CES Production Functions in Dynamic Models

CHAPTER 9 Building the Aggregate Expenditures Model

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Revenue Structure, Objectives of a Firm and. Break-Even Analysis.

10.1 Systems of Linear Equations: Substitution and Elimination

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Preparation course MSc Business&Econonomics: Economic Growth

Question 2: How do you solve a matrix equation using the matrix inverse?

This unit will lay the groundwork for later units where the students will extend this knowledge to quadratic and exponential functions.

Hello, my name is Olga Michasova and I present the work The generalized model of economic growth with human capital accumulation.

Chapter 5 Estimating Demand Functions

EC2105, Professor Laury EXAM 2, FORM A (3/13/02)

GDP: The market value of final goods and services, newly produced WITHIN a nation during a fixed period.

A Classical Monetary Model - Money in the Utility Function

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

1 if 1 x 0 1 if 0 x 1

The Effect on Housing Prices of Changes in Mortgage Rates and Taxes

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Economic Growth. Chapter 11

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

More Quadratic Equations

Math 241, Exam 1 Information.

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Pre-Test Chapter 18 ed17

Fixed Point Theorems

Math 120 Final Exam Practice Problems, Form: A

LEARNING OBJECTIVES FOR THIS CHAPTER

Constrained optimization.

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Homework #6 - Answers. Uses of Macro Policy Due April 20

EXPONENTIAL FUNCTIONS

The Basic New Keynesian Model

Technology and Economic Growth

10.2 ITERATIVE METHODS FOR SOLVING LINEAR SYSTEMS. The Jacobi Method

Economic Growth. (c) Copyright 1999 by Douglas H. Joines 1

For additional information, see the Math Notes boxes in Lesson B.1.3 and B.2.3.

Probability and Statistics Prof. Dr. Somesh Kumar Department of Mathematics Indian Institute of Technology, Kharagpur

Chapter 9. Systems of Linear Equations

Efficient Curve Fitting Techniques

QUIZ Principles of Macroeconomics May 19, I. True/False (30 points)

1 Short Introduction to Time Series

1 National Income and Product Accounts

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Productioin OVERVIEW. WSG5 7/7/03 4:35 PM Page 63. Copyright 2003 by Academic Press. All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

Business Cycles, Theory and Empirical Applications

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Basic Properties of Rational Expressions

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Creating, Solving, and Graphing Systems of Linear Equations and Linear Inequalities

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

2.1 Increasing, Decreasing, and Piecewise Functions; Applications

Choice under Uncertainty

Logs Transformation in a Regression Equation

Transcription:

316-466 Monetary Economics Note 3 In this note, I discuss some handy facts about steady states and local approximations to them in the context of the Solow (1956) growth model. Setup Consider the Solow growth model in its most stripped down form. This consists of a resource constraint, a production function, a law of motion for capital accumulation, and the behavioral assumption that a constant fraction 0 <s<1 of output is saved and invested. In standard notation c t + i t = y t = f(k t ) k t+1 = (1 δ)k t + i t c t = (1 s)y t for some constant depreciation rate 0 <δ<1 and given initial condition k 0. The following assumptions are made about the production function: It is strictly increasing, strictly concave, needs some capital to produce anything, and satisfies the Inada conditions f(k) 0, f(0) = 0 f 0 (k) > 0, f 00 (k) < 0 f 0 (0) =, f 0 ( ) =0 Scalar difference equation Putting this together gives a first order non-linear difference equation k t+1 = H(k t ) sf(k t )+(1 δ)k t Given the assumptions about f, the function H is also strictly increasing, strictly concave, etc H(0) = sf(0) + (1 δ)0 = 0 H 0 (k) = sf 0 (k)+(1 δ) > 0 H 00 (k) = sf 00 (k) < 0 H 0 (0) = sf 0 (0) + (1 δ) = H 0 ( ) = sf 0 ( )+(1 δ) =(1 δ) < 1 This model has a single state variable, the capital stock k t. Given the capital stock, it s trivial to find output y t = f(k t ), consumption c t =(1 s)f(k t ),andinvestmenti t = sf(k t ). A solution to a difference equation is a function that expresses the capital stock as a function of time, t an initial condition, k 0 and other parameters of the model. Linear difference equations are trivial to solve. For example, suppose x t+1 = Ax t 1

Then the solution is found by recursive substitution x 1 = Ax 0 x 2 = Ax 1 = AAx 0 = A 2 x 0. x t = A t x 0 Unfortunately, non-linear difference equations are not so easy to solve. It s traditional to analyze their qualitative behavior in terms of steady states and phase diagrams. Steady states A steady state is a fixed point of the mapping k t+1 = H(k t ). Put differently, it is a situation where the state variable is unchanging so that k t+1 = k t = k. The Solow model has two fixed points. A steady state has to satisfy k = H(k) =sf(k)+(1 δ)k One solution is k =0 0=H(0) = sf(0) + (1 δ)0 another is the unique positive solution to δk = sf(k) Thelefthandsideisastraightlinethroughtheoriginwithpositiveslope0 <δ<1. Thisis the steady state level of investment, the amount of investment required to keep the capital stock constant. The right hand side is a strictly increasing strictly concave function that is exactly a scalar multiple of the production function f(k). Given the Inada conditions, there is a unique positive k >0 determined by the intersection of the two curves δ k = sf( k). Local stability Consider the first order Taylor series approximation to the function H at some point k H(k t ) = H( k)+h 0 ( k)(k t k) A natural point around which to approximate H is a fixedpoint.inthiscase, H(k t ) = H( k)+h 0 ( k)(k t k) = k + H 0 ( k)(k t k) where the second line follows because of the definition of k as a point that satisfies k = H( k). If we treat this approximation as exact, we have the linear difference equation k t+1 = k + H 0 ( k)(k t k) An intuitive understanding of whether a fixed point is locally stable can be obtained by considering what would have to be true in order for sequences of k t that satisfy this linear 2

difference equation to converge to k. Writing x t+1 = k t+1 k so that x t+1 = H 0 ( k)x t,itis clear that this linear difference equation has the solution or x t = H 0 ( k) t x 0 k t = k + H 0 ( k) t (k 0 k) Clearly, k t k if and only if H 0 ( k) t 0 andthisinturnrequiresthat H 0 ( k) < 1. Thus in order for a fixed point to be locally stable, we need the absolute value of the slope of H at the fixed point to be less than one. If 0 <H 0 ( k) < 1, the convergence to the fixed point is monotone. If 1 <H 0 ( k) < 0, the convergence to the fixed point takes the form of dampened oscillations. Consider the Solow model. The trivial fixed point k =0is locally unstable it repels capital sequences because the derivative at this point is H 0 (0) =. On the other hand, the interior fixed point is locally stable it attracts capital sequences because the derivative at this point is positive but less than one. Of course, just because a fixed point is locally stable, doesn t mean that it is globally stable (that would require k t k for all initial conditions k 0 in the domain of the original non-linear map H). Log-linearizations Log-linearizing a model has the convenience of providing coefficients that are readily interpretable as elasticities. The log deviation of a variable x t from a steady state level x is just ˆx t log(x t / x). Multiplied by 100, this is approximately the percentage deviation of x t from x. Mechanically, the log linearization of a model proceeds by replacing x t with x exp(ˆx t ) and then linearizing the equations of the model with respect to ˆx t in a neighborhood of zero. To illustrate, consider the fundamental non-linear difference equation of the Solow model k t+1 = H(k t ) sf(k t )+(1 δ)k t Replace k t by k exp(ˆk t ) to get k exp(ˆk t+1 )=H[ k exp(ˆk t )] sf[ k exp(ˆk t )] + (1 δ) k exp(ˆk t ) A first order Taylor series approximation around zero of the term on the far left gives k exp(ˆk t+1 ) = k exp(0) + k exp(0)ˆk t+1 = k + kˆk t+1 (1) Similarly H[ k exp(ˆk t )] = H[ k exp(0)] + H 0 [ k exp(0)] k exp(0)ˆk t = H( k)+h 0 ( k) kˆk t = k +[sf 0 ( k)+(1 δ)] kˆk t (2) Equating (1) and (2) and simplifying gives ˆk t+1 = [sf 0 ( k)+(1 δ)]ˆk t Here are some rules that make taking log-linearization easier (you should derive these results yourself to test your understanding). 3

1. MULTIPLICATION z t = x t y t = ẑ t =ˆx t +ŷ t Application: A consumer s first order condition is often 1=β U 0 (c t+1 ) U 0 (c t ) R t+1 This implies the log linearization ˆ1 =ˆβ + U 0 d (c t+1 ) U d0 (c t )+ ˆR t+1 Butsincethelogdeviationsofconstantsarezero,thisisjust 2. DIVISION 0= d U 0 (c t+1 ) d U 0 (c t )+ ˆR t+1 z t = x t /y t = ẑ t =ˆx t ŷ t Application: The law of motion for money supply is often written M t+1 = µ t M t This implies the law of motion for real balances m t+1 M t+1 P t = µ t M t P t 1 1 π t (where π t = P t /P t 1 ). So we have the log linearization ˆm t+1 =ˆµ t +ˆm t ˆπ t 3. ADDITION/SUBTRACTION z t = x t + y t = zẑ t = xˆx t +ȳŷ t Applications: The resource constraint is often c t + i t = y t This implies the log linearization cĉ t +īî t =ȳŷ t 4

Another example is that gross returns are often written as one plus net returns R t+1 =1+r t+1 This implies or R ˆR t+1 = rˆr t+1 ˆR t+1 = r 1+ r ˆr t+1 4. SMOOTH FUNCTIONS z t = f(x t ) = zẑ t = f 0 ( x) xˆx t Applications: The marginal utility of consumption may be U 0 (c).this implies the log linearization U 0 ( c) d U 0 (c t )=U 00 ( c) cĉ t As a leading example, if we have constant relative risk aversion preferences with coefficient σ>0, this implies Ud 0 (c t )= U 00 ( c) c U 0 ( c) ĉt = σĉ t As a further example, if we have the rental rate of capital equal to its marginal product r t = F 0 (k t ) this implies ˆr t = F 00 ( k) k F 0 ( k) ˆk t 5. MULTIVARIATE SMOOTH FUNCTIONS z t = f(x t,y t ) = zẑ t = f x ( x, ȳ) xˆx t + f y ( x, ȳ)ȳŷ t Applications: The production function might be y = F (k, n). This implies the log linearization ȳŷ t = F k ( k, n) kˆk t + F n ( k, n) nˆn t 5

or ŷ t = F k( k, n) k F ( k, n) ˆk t + F n( k, n) n F ( k, n) ˆn t As a leading example, if we have a Cobb-Douglas production function F (k, n) =k α n 1 α for 0 <α<1, thisis ŷ t = αˆk t +(1 α)ˆn t As a further example, if we have the marginal utility of consumption U c (c, ), the associated log linearization is U c (c d t, t )= U cc( c, ) c U c ( c, ) ĉt + U c ( c, ) U c ( c, ) ˆ t And if we use the approximation implied by Rule 3 to write nˆn t + ˆ t =0with =1 n, we can also write U c (c d t, t )= U cc( c, 1 n) c U c ( c, 1 n) ĉt U c ( c, 1 n) n U c ( c, 1 n) ˆn t Chris Edmond, 9 September 2003 6