Economics 241B Hypothesis Testing: Large Sample Inference

Similar documents
160 CHAPTER 4. VECTOR SPACES

Double Integrals in Polar Coordinates

1 Another method of estimation: least squares

Representation of functions as power series

Web Appendices to Selling to Overcon dent Consumers

Web Appendices of Selling to Overcon dent Consumers

1.2 Solving a System of Linear Equations

Chapter 3: The Multiple Linear Regression Model

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chapter 2. Dynamic panel data models

MSc. Econ: MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS, 1995 MAXIMUM-LIKELIHOOD ESTIMATION

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

6.042/18.062J Mathematics for Computer Science December 12, 2006 Tom Leighton and Ronitt Rubinfeld. Random Walks

Lecture Notes 10

Chapter 4: Statistical Hypothesis Testing

Lecture 1: Systems of Linear Equations

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 14 10/27/2008 MOMENT GENERATING FUNCTIONS

Chapter 5: The Cointegrated VAR model

IDENTIFICATION IN A CLASS OF NONPARAMETRIC SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS. Steven T. Berry and Philip A. Haile. March 2011 Revised April 2011

10.2 Systems of Linear Equations: Matrices

Consumer Referrals. Maria Arbatskaya and Hideo Konishi. October 28, 2014

Out-of-Sample Forecast Tests Robust to the Choice of Window Size

On the predictive content of the PPI on CPI inflation: the case of Mexico

Unit 3. Elasticity Learning objectives Questions for revision: 3.1. Price elasticity of demand

Large Sample Theory. Consider a sequence of random variables Z 1, Z 2,..., Z n. Convergence in probability: Z n

Factor Prices and International Trade: A Unifying Perspective

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

WORKING PAPER NO OUT-OF-SAMPLE FORECAST TESTS ROBUST TO THE CHOICE OF WINDOW SIZE

Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary

Redwood Building, Room T204, Stanford University School of Medicine, Stanford, CA

How To Solve A Minimum Set Covering Problem (Mcp)

Bias in the Estimation of Mean Reversion in Continuous-Time Lévy Processes

Sensitivity Analysis of Non-linear Performance with Probability Distortion

Consistent cotrending rank selection when both stochastic and. nonlinear deterministic trends are present

Text Analytics. Modeling Information Retrieval 2. Ulf Leser

Beyond the F Test: Effect Size Confidence Intervals and Tests of Close Fit in the Analysis of Variance and Contrast Analysis

c 2009 Je rey A. Miron 3. Examples: Linear Demand Curves and Monopoly

A Simple Model of Pricing, Markups and Market. Power Under Demand Fluctuations

Four Derivations of the Black-Scholes Formula by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

1 Gambler s Ruin Problem

PRETRIAL NEGOTIATION, LITIGATION, AND PROCEDURAL RULES

A note on the impact of options on stock return volatility 1

DIAGNOSTIC TESTING FOR COINTEGRATION. P.M. Robinson

Out-of-Sample Forecast Tests Robust to the Window Size Choice

1. Introduction to multivariate data

Trap Coverage: Allowing Coverage Holes of Bounded Diameter in Wireless Sensor Networks

How To Find Out How To Calculate Volume Of A Sphere

Price Elasticity of Demand MATH 104 and MATH 184 Mark Mac Lean (with assistance from Patrick Chan) 2011W

Risk Management for Derivatives

Advanced Microeconomics

Effect Sizes Based on Means

A Generalization of Sauer s Lemma to Classes of Large-Margin Functions

Contingent Fees, Signaling and Settlement Authority

Given three vectors A, B, andc. We list three products with formula (A B) C = B(A C) A(B C); A (B C) =B(A C) C(A B);

Complex Conjugation and Polynomial Factorization

TRANSCENDENTAL NUMBERS

Modifying Gaussian term structure models when interest rates are near the zero lower bound. Leo Krippner. March JEL classi cation: E43, G12, G13

Review of Bivariate Regression

PRIME NUMBERS AND THE RIEMANN HYPOTHESIS

Ch 10. Arithmetic Average Options and Asian Opitons

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

Coordinate Transformation

Monitoring Frequency of Change By Li Qin

Panel Data Econometrics

1 Simulating Brownian motion (BM) and geometric Brownian motion (GBM)

Di usion on Social Networks. Current Version: June 6, 2006 Appeared in: Économie Publique, Numéro 16, pp 3-16, 2005/1.

Measures of distance between samples: Euclidean

The Dynamics of UK and US In ation Expectations

Outsourcing Information Security: Contracting Issues and Security Implications

A statistical test for forecast evaluation under a discrete loss function

Exponential Functions: Differentiation and Integration. The Natural Exponential Function

price elasticity of demand; cross-price elasticity of demand; income elasticity of demand; price elasticity of supply.

Normally Distributed Data. A mean with a normal value Test of Hypothesis Sign Test Paired observations within a single patient group

Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save

Math , Fall 2012: HW 1 Solutions

Cointegration Vector Estimation by DOLS for a Three-Dimensional Panel

The mean-field computation in a supermarket model with server multiple vacations

Herding, Contrarianism and Delay in Financial Market Trading

Factoring Dickson polynomials over finite fields

Identification and inference in a simultaneous equation under alternative information sets and sampling schemes

Discussion Papers Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Lecture L25-3D Rigid Body Kinematics

Panel Unit Root Tests in the Presence of Cross-Sectional Dependency and Heterogeneity 1

An Approach to Optimizations Links Utilization in MPLS Networks

MODELLING OF TWO STRATEGIES IN INVENTORY CONTROL SYSTEM WITH RANDOM LEAD TIME AND DEMAND

The Behavioral Economics of Insurance

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models

Synchronization for a DVB-T Receiver in Presence of Strong Interference

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

Section 2.4: Equations of Lines and Planes

Using Excel for inferential statistics

FREQUENCIES OF SUCCESSIVE PAIRS OF PRIME RESIDUES

Alternative Bootstrap Procedures for Testing Cointegration in Fractionally Integrated Processes

The Impact of Forecasting Methods on Bullwhip Effect in Supply Chain Management

Chapter 1. Linear Panel Models and Heterogeneity

Solving Linear Systems, Continued and The Inverse of a Matrix

ISSN Working Paper Series. An Econometric Contribution to the Intertemporal Approach of the Current Account

Transcription:

Economics 241B Hyothesis Testing: Large Samle Inference Statistical inference in large-samle theory is base on test statistics whose istributions are nown uner the truth of the null hyothesis. Derivation of these istributions is easier than in nite-samle theory because we are only concerne with the large-samle aroximation to the exact istribution. In what follows we assume that a consistent estimator of S exists, which we term ^S. Recall that S = E (g t gt), 0 where g t = X t U t. Testing Linear Hyotheses Consier testing a hyothesis regaring the -th coe cient. Proosition 2.1, which establishe the asymtotic istribution of the OLS estimator, imlies that uner H 0 : =, n B! N (0; Avar (B )) an \ Avar (B )! Avar (B ) : Here B is the -th element of the OLS estimator B an Avar (B ) is the (; ) element of the K K matrix Avar (B). The ey issue here is that we have not assume conitional homoseasticity, hence \ Avar (B ) = S 1 XX ^S S 1 XX ; which is the (heteroseasticity-consistent) robust asymtotic variance. the Slutsy result (Lemma 2.4c), the resultant robust t-ratio n B t q = B Avar \ SE (B ) (B )! N (0; 1) ; Uner q where the robust stanar error is SE 1 = Avar \(B n ). Note this robust t- ratio is istinct from the t-ratio introuce uner the nite-samle assumtions in earlier lectures. To test H 0 : =, simly follow these stes: Ste 1: Calculate the robust t-ratio Ste 2: Obtain the critical value from the N (0; 1) istribution

Ste 3: Reject the null hyothesis if jt j excees the critical value There are several i erences from the nite-samle test that relies on conitional homoseasticity. The stanar error is calculate in a i erent way, to accommoate conitional heteroseasticity. The normal istribution is use to obtain critical values, rather than the t istribution. The actual (or emirical) size of the test is not necessarily equal to the nominal size. The i erence between the actual size an the nominal size is the size istortion. Because the asymtotic istribution of the robust t ratio is stanar normal, the size istortion shrins to zero as the samle size goes to in nity. To summarize these results, together with the behavior of the Wal statistic let us brie y recall the assumtions require for Proosition 2.1: Assumtion 2.1 (linearity): Y t = X 0 t + U t (t = 1; : : : ; n; ) where X t is a K-imensional vector of regressors, is a K-imensional vector of coe cients an U t is the latent error. Assumtion 2.2 (ergoic stationarity): The (K + 1)-imensional vector stochastic rocess fy t ; X t g is jointly stationary an ergoic. Assumtion 2.3 (reetermine regressors): All regressors are reetermine, in the sense that they are orthogonal to the contemoraneous error: E (X t U t ) = 0 for all t an (= 1; 2; : : : ; K). This can be written as E (g t ) = 0 where g t X t U t : Assumtion 2.4 (ran conition): The K K matrix E (X t Xt) 0 is nonsingular (an hence nite). We enote this matrix by XX. Assumtion 2.5 (g t is a martingale i erence sequence with nite secon moments): fg t g is a martingale i erence sequence (so by e nition E (g t ) = 0). The K K matrix of cross moments, E (g t gt), 0 is nonsingular. Let S enote Avar (g) (the variance of the asymtotic istribution of P ng, where g = 1 n t g t).

By Assumtion 2.2 an the Ergoic Stationary Martingale Di erences CLT, S = E (g t g 0 t). Proosition 2.3 (robust t-ratio an Wal statistic): estimator ^S of S, if Assumtions 2.1 to 2.5 hol, then a) Uner the null hyothesis H 0 : = ; t! N (0; 1) Given a consistent b) Uner the null hyothesis H 0 : R = r, where R is a #r K matrix (where #r, the imension of r, is the number of restrictions) of full row ran, W n (Rb r) 0 n R \ Avar(B) R 0 o 1 (Rb r)! 2 (#r) : Proof: We have alreay establishe art a. Part b is a straightforwar alication of Lemma 2.4(). Write W as W = c 0 nq 1 n c n where c n = n (Rb r) an Q n = R \ Avar(B) R 0 : Uner H 0, c n = R n (b ), so Proosition 2.1 imlies Also by Proosition 2.1 c n! c where c N (0; RAvar (B) R 0 ) : Q n! Q where Q RAvar (B) R 0 : Because R is full row ran an Avar (B) is ositive e nite, Q is invertible. Therefore, Lemma 2.4() imlies W! c 0 Q 1 c: Because c is normally istribute with imension #r, an because Q equals the variance of c, c 0 Q 1 c = 2 (#r). QED The statistic W is a Wal statistic because it is constructe from unrestricte estimators (B an Avar \ (B)) that are not constraine by the null hyothesis. To test H 0 :: R = r, simly follow these stes: Ste 1: Construct W:

Ste 2: To n the critical value for a test with size 5%, n the oint of the 2 (#r) istribution that gives 5% to the uer tail. Ste 3: If W excees the critical value, then reject the null hyothesis. Consistent Test The ower of a test is the robability of rejecting a false null hyothesis. The ower of a test (for a given size) eens on the alternative DGP. For examle, consier any DGP fy t ; X t g that satis es Assumtions 2.1-2.5 but for which 6=. The ower of a test base on the t ratio is ower = Pr (jt j > cv ) ; where cv is the critical value associate with a size of. Because the DGP controls the istribution of t, the ower eens uon the DGP. The test is consistent against a set of DGP s (none of which satisfy the null) if the ower against any member of the set of DGP s aroaches unity as n! 1 (for any assume signi cance level). To see that the test base on the t ratio is consistent, note that for n B t = q Avar \(B ) the enominator converges to Avar (B ) esite the fact that DGP oes not satisfy the null (Proosition 2.1 requires only Assumtions 2.1-2.5 an oes not een on the truth of the null hyothesis). In contrast, the numerator tens to either +1 or 1, because B converges to the value of for the DGP, which i ers from. Hence the ower tens to unity as the samle size tens to in nity, imlying that the test is consistent for all members of the set of DGP s. The same is true for the Wal test. Asymtotic Power The ower of the t test aroaches unity as the samle size increases for any xe alternative DGP. If, however, the DGP is not hel xe but allowe to get closer an closer to the null hyothesis as the samle size increases, then the ower may not converge to unity. A sequence of such DGP s is calle a sequence of local alternatives. For the regression moel with the null of H 0 : =, a sequence of n local alternatives is a sequence of DGP s such that (i) the n-th DGP Y (n) t ; X (n) t (t = 1; 2; : : :) satis es Assumtions 2.1-2.5 an converges in a certain sense to a o

xe DGP fy t ; X t g, an (ii) the value of for the n-th DGP, (n), converges to. Suose, further, that (n) satis es (n) = + n for some given 6= 0. Such a sequence of local alternatives, in which (n) aroaches at the rate of 1= n, is calle a Pitman rift or Pitman sequence. Uner this sequence of local alternatives, the t ratio is n B (n) t = q + q : Avar \(B ) Avar \(B ) If a samle of size n is generate by the n-th DGP of a Pitman sequence, oes t converge to a nontrivial istribution? Because the n-th DGP satis es Assumtions 2.1-2.5, the rst term on the right sie converges in istribution to N (0; 1) by Proosition 2.3(a). By art (c) of Proosition 2.1 ( [Avar! Avar) an the n o fact that Y (n) t ; X (n) t "converges" to a xe DGP, the secon term converges in robability to := Avar (B ) where Avar (B ) is evaluate at the xe DGP. Therefore, t! N (; 1) along this sequence of local alternatives. If the signi cance level is, the ower converges to Pr (jxj > cv) ; where cv is the critical value (i.e. 1.96) an x N (; 1). This robability is terme the asymtotic ower. Eviently, the larger is jj the higher is the asymtotic ower for any given size. By a similar argument, the Wal statistic converges to a non-central chi-square istribution along a Pitman sequence. Testing Nonlinear Hyotheses The Wal test can be generalize to a test of nonlinear restrictions on. Consier a null hyothesis of the form H 0 : a () = 0:

Here a is a vector-value function with continuous rst erivatives. Let #a be the imension of a (so the null hyothesis has #a restrictions) an let A () be the #a K matrix of rst erivatives evaluate at : A () = @a () =@ 0. For the hyothesis to be well e ne, we assume that A () is full row ran (this is the generalization of the requirement for linear hyotheses R = r that R is of full row ran). By Lemma 2.5 (the elta metho) we have n (a (B) a ())! c; c N 0; A () Avar (B) A () 0 : Because B!, Lemma 2.3(a) imlies that A (B)! A (). Because (Proosition 2.1(c)) \ Avar (B)! Avar (B), Lemma 2.3(a) imlies A (B) \ Avar (B)A (B) 0! A () Avar (B) A () 0 = V ar (c) : Because A (B) has full row ran an Avar (B) is ositive e nite, V ar (c) is invertible. Uon noting that, uner the null hyothesis a () = 0, Lemma 2.4() imlies na (B) 0 n A (B) \ Avar (B)A (B) 0 o 1 na (B)! c 0 V ar (c) 1 c 2 (#a) : If we combine the two n s into n we have roven Proosition 2.3 (continue - nonlinear hyotheses): c) Uner the null hyothesis H 0 : a () = 0 (which contains #a restrictions) if A () (the #a K matrix of continuous rst erivatives of a ()) is of full row ran, then W n a (B) 0 n A (B) \ Avar (B)A (B) 0 o 1 a (B)! 2 (#a) : Part (c) is a generalization of art (b), if we set a (B) = RB r, then W reuces to the Wal statistic for linear restrictions. For a given set of restrictions, a () may not be unique. For examle, the restriction 1 2 = 1 coul be written as a () = 0 with a () = 1 2 1 or with a () = 1 1= 2. While art c of the Proosition guarantees that the outcome of the Wal test is the same (for either exression of the restriction) in large samles, the numerical value of W oes een on the way the restriction

is written. Hence, the outcome of the test can een on the exression in nite samles. In this examle, the reresentation a () = 1 1= 2 oes not satisfy the requirement of continuous erivatives at 2 = 0. Inee, a 1985 Monte Carlo stuy by Gregory an Veal reorts that, when 2 is close to zero, the Wal test base on the secon reresentation rejects the null too often in small samles. (Actual size excees nominal size.)