Chapter 13 : The Arbitrage Pricing Theory



Similar documents
CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

Solution: The optimal position for an investor with a coefficient of risk aversion A = 5 in the risky asset is y*:

Computational Finance Options

Lecture 6: Arbitrage Pricing Theory

Models of Risk and Return

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

Review for Exam 2. Instructions: Please read carefully

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Midterm Exam:Answer Sheet

1 Portfolio mean and variance

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

The Tangent or Efficient Portfolio

MATH10212 Linear Algebra. Systems of Linear Equations. Definition. An n-dimensional vector is a row or a column of n numbers (or letters): a 1.

THE DIMENSION OF A VECTOR SPACE

Chapter 5 Risk and Return ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Chapter 2 Portfolio Management and the Capital Asset Pricing Model

Chapter 5 Financial Forwards and Futures

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

MTH6120 Further Topics in Mathematical Finance Lesson 2

v w is orthogonal to both v and w. the three vectors v, w and v w form a right-handed set of vectors.

Similarity and Diagonalization. Similar Matrices

CFA Examination PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT Page 1 of 6

Chapter 13 Composition of the Market Portfolio 1. Capital markets in Flatland exhibit trade in four securities, the stocks X, Y and Z,

Forward Contracts and Forward Rates

α = u v. In other words, Orthogonal Projection

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

Risk Decomposition of Investment Portfolios. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Webinar January 2014

One Period Binomial Model

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

CML is the tangent line drawn from the risk free point to the feasible region for risky assets. This line shows the relation between r P and

Basic Financial Tools: A Review. 3 n 1 n. PV FV 1 FV 2 FV 3 FV n 1 FV n 1 (1 i)

Equity Market Risk Premium Research Summary. 12 April 2016

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Mean-Variance Framework for Tests of Asset Pricing Models

7: The CRR Market Model

A Short Introduction to Credit Default Swaps

1 Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

Lecture 5: Put - Call Parity

Part IV. Arbitrage Pricing

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

Section 4.4 Inner Product Spaces

Chapter 5. Conditional CAPM. 5.1 Conditional CAPM: Theory Risk According to the CAPM. The CAPM is not a perfect model of expected returns.

Equity Risk Premium Article Michael Annin, CFA and Dominic Falaschetti, CFA

Answers to Concepts in Review

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

Chapter 17. Orthogonal Matrices and Symmetries of Space

AFM 472. Midterm Examination. Monday Oct. 24, A. Huang

Mathematics Course 111: Algebra I Part IV: Vector Spaces

a 11 x 1 + a 12 x a 1n x n = b 1 a 21 x 1 + a 22 x a 2n x n = b 2.

Chapter 5. Risk and Return. Copyright 2009 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

Econ 422 Summer 2006 Final Exam Solutions

Introduction to Matrix Algebra

Five High Order Thinking Skills

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

3. Mathematical Induction

The Matrix Elements of a 3 3 Orthogonal Matrix Revisited

t = Calculate the implied interest rates and graph the term structure of interest rates. t = X t = t = 1 2 3

CHAPTER 7: OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS

8.1 Summary and conclusions 8.2 Implications

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Lectures notes on orthogonal matrices (with exercises) Linear Algebra II - Spring 2004 by D. Klain

Wel Dlp Portfolio And Risk Management

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

1 Present and Future Value

Chapter 11, Risk and Return

Methods for Finding Bases

Linear Algebra Notes for Marsden and Tromba Vector Calculus

NOTES ON LINEAR TRANSFORMATIONS

Chapter 1 Introduction. 1.1 Introduction

Journal of Exclusive Management Science May Vol 4 Issue 5 - ISSN

Numerical Analysis Lecture Notes

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran

Systems of Linear Equations

Rate of Return. Reading: Veronesi, Chapter 7. Investment over a Holding Period

The Cost of Financial Frictions for Life Insurers

Understanding the Impact of Weights Constraints in Portfolio Theory

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

Lecture 1: Asset Allocation

Models of Asset Pricing The implications for asset allocation

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Binomial lattice model for stock prices

Solving Systems of Linear Equations

Risk and Return Models: Equity and Debt. Aswath Damodaran 1

An introduction to Value-at-Risk Learning Curve September 2003

Introduction to Hypothesis Testing OPRE 6301

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

Notes on Orthogonal and Symmetric Matrices MENU, Winter 2013

Inner Product Spaces

Session X: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics. Department of Economics, City University, London

Practice Set #4 and Solutions.

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas Words: 3441

Transcription:

Chapter 13 : The Arbitrage Pricing Theory 13.1 Introduction We have made two first attempts (Chapters 10 to 12) at asset pricing from an arbitrage perspective, that is, without specifying a complete equilibrium structure. Here we try again from a different, more empirically based angle. Let us first collect a few thoughts as to the differences between an arbitrage approach and equilibrium modeling. In the context of general equilibrium theory, we make hypotheses about agents consumers, producers, investors; in particular, we start with some form of rationality hypothesis leading to the specification of maximization problems under constraints. We also make hypotheses about markets: Typically we assume that supply equals demand in all markets under consideration. We have repeatedly used the fact that at general equilibrium with fully informed optimizing agents, there can be no arbitrage opportunities, in other words, no possibilities to make money risklessly at zero cost. An arbitrage opportunity indeed implies that at least one agent can reach a higher level of utility without violating his/her budget constraint (since there is no extra cost). In particular, our assertion that one can price any asset (income stream) from the knowledge of Arrow-Debreu prices relied implicitly on a no-arbitrage hypothesis: with a complete set of Arrow-Debreu securities, it is possible to replicate any given income stream and hence the value of a given income stream, the price paid on the market for the corresponding asset, cannot be different from the value of the replicating portfolio of Arrow-Debreu securities. Otherwise an arbitrageur could make arbitrarily large profits by short selling large quantities of the more expensive of the two and buying the cheaper in equivalent amount. Such an arbitrage would have zero cost and be riskless. While general equilibrium implies the no-arbitrage condition, it is more restrictive in the sense of imposing a heavier structure on modeling. And the reverse implication is not true: No arbitrage opportunities 1 the fact that all arbitrage opportunities have been exploited does not imply that a general equilibrium in all markets has been obtained. Nevertheless, or precisely for that reason, it is interesting to see how far one can go in exploiting the less restrictive hypothesis that no arbitrage opportunities are left unexploited. The underlying logic of the APT to be reviewed in this chapter is, in a sense, very similar to the fundamental logic of the Arrow-Debreu model and it is very much in the spirit of a complete market structure. It distinguishes itself in two major ways: First it replaces the underlying structure based on fundamental securities paying exclusively in a given state of nature with other fundamental securities exclusively remunerating some form of risk taking. More precisely, the APT abandons the analytically powerful, but empirically cumbersome, concept of states of nature as the basis for the definition of its primitive securities. It 1 An arbitrage portfolio is a self-financing (zero net-investment) portfolio. An arbitrage opportunity exists if an arbitrage portfolio exists that yields non-negative cash flows in all states of nature and positive cash flows in some states (Chapter 11). 1

replaces it with the hypothesis that there exists a (stable) set of factors that are essential and exhaustive determinants of all asset returns. The primitive security will then be defined as a security whose risk is exclusively determined by its association with one specific risk factor and totally immune from association with any other risk factor. The other difference with the Arrow-Debreu pricing of Chapter 8 is that the prices of the fundamental securities are not derived from primitives supply and demand, themselves resulting from agents endowments and preferences but will be deduced empirically from observed asset returns without attempting to explain them. Once the price of each fundamental security has been inferred from observed return distributions, the usual arbitrage argument applied to complex securities will be made (in the spirit of Chapter 10). 2 13.2 Factor Models The main building block of the APT is a factor model, also known as a returngenerating process. As discussed previously, this is the structure that is to replace the concept of states of nature. The motivation has been evoked before: States of nature are analytically convincing and powerful objects. In practice, however, they are difficult to work with and, moreover, often not verifiable, implying that contracts cannot necessarily be written contingent on a specific state of nature. We discussed these shortcomings of the Arrow-Debreu pricing theory in Chapter 8. The temptation is thus irresistible to attack the asset pricing problem from the opposite angle and build the concept of primitive securities on an empirically more operational notion, abstracting from its potential theoretical credentials. This structure is what factor models are for. The simplest conceivable factor model is a one-factor market model, usually labeled the Market Model, which asserts that ex-post returns on individual assets can be entirely ascribed either to their own specific stochastic components or to their common association in a single factor, which in the CAPM world would naturally be selected as the return on the market portfolio. This simple factor model can thus be summarized by following the equation (or process): 3 r j = α j + β j r M + ε j, (13.1) with E ε j = 0, cõv ( r M, ε j ) = 0, j, and cov ( ε j, ε k ) = 0, j k. This model states that there are three components in individual returns: (1) an asset-specific constant α j ; (2) a common influence, in this case the unique factor, the return on the market, which affects all assets in varying degrees, with β j measuring the sensitivity of asset j s return to fluctuations in the market return; and (3) an asset-specific stochastic term ε j summarizing all other stochastic components of r j that are unique to asset j. 2 The arbitrage pricing theory was first developed by Ross (1976), and substantially interpreted by Huberman (1982) and Conner (1984) among others. For a presentation emphasizing practical applications, see Burmeister et al. (1994). 3 Factors are frequently measured as deviations from their mean. When this is the case, α j becomes an estimate of the mean return on asset j. 2

Equation (13.1) has no bite (such an equation can always be written) until one adds the hypothesis cov ( ε j, ε k ) = 0, j k, which signifies that all return characteristics common to different assets are subsumed in their link with the market return. If this were empirically verified, the CAPM would be the undisputed end point of asset pricing. At an empirical level, one may say that it is quite unlikely that a single factor model will suffice. 4 But the strength of the APT is that it is agnostic as to the number of underlying factors (and their identity). As we increase the number of factors, hoping that this will not require a number too large to be operational, a generalization of Equation (13.1) becomes more and more plausible. But let us for the moment maintain the hypothesis of one common factor for pedagogical purposes. 5 13.2.1 About the Market Model Besides serving as a potential basis for the APT, the Market Model, despite all its weaknesses, is also of interest on two grounds. First it produces estimates for the β s that play a central role in the CAPM. Note, however, that estimating β s from past data alone is useful only to the extent that some degree of stationarity in the relationship between asset returns and the return on the market is present. Empirical observations suggest a fair amount of stationarity is plausible at the level of portfolios, but not of individual assets. On the other hand, estimating the β s does not require all the assumptions of the Market Model; in particular, a violation of the cov( ε i, ε k ) = 0, i k hypothesis is not damaging. The second source of interest in the Market Model, crucially dependent on the latter hypothesis being approximately valid, is that it permits economizing on the computation of the matrix of variances and covariances of asset returns at the heart of the MPT. Indeed, under the Market Model hypothesis, one can write (you are invited to prove these statements): σ 2 j = β 2 j σ 2 M + σ 2 εj, j σ ij = β i β j σ 2 M This effectively means that the information requirements for the implementation of MPT can be substantially weakened. Suppose there are N risky assets under consideration. In that case the computation of the efficient frontier requires knowledge of N expected returns, N variances, and N 2 N 2 covariance terms (N 2 is the total number of entries in the matrix of variances and covariances, take away the N variance/diagonal terms and divide by 2 since σ ij = σ ji, i, j). 4 Recall the difficulty in constructing the empirical counterpart of M. 5 Fama (1973), however, demonstrates that in its form (13.1) the Market Model is inconsistent in the following sense: the fact that the market is, by definition, the collection of all individual assets implies an exact linear relationship between the disturbances ε j ; in other words, when the single factor is interpreted to be the market the hypothesis cov ( ε j, ε k ) = 0, j k cannot be strictly valid. While we ignore this criticism in view of our purely pedagogical objective, it is a fact that if a single factor model had a chance to be empirically verified (in the sense of all the assumptions in (13.1) being confirmed) the unique factor could not be the market. 3

Working via the Market Model, on the other hand, requires estimating Equation (13.1) for the N risky returns producing estimations for the N β j s and the N σεj 2 and estimating the variance of the market return, that is, 2N + 1 information items. 13.3 The APT: Statement and Proof 13.3.1 A Quasi-Complete Market Hypothesis To a return-generating process such as the Market Model, the APT superposes a second major hypothesis that is akin to assuming that the markets are quasicomplete. What is needed is the existence of a rich market structure with a large number of assets with different characteristics and a minimum number of trading restrictions. This market structure, in particular, makes it possible to form a portfolio P with the following three properties: Property 1: P has zero cost; in other words, it requires no investment. This is the first requirement of an arbitrage portfolio. Let us denote x i as the value of the position in the ith asset in portfolio P. Portfolio P is then fully described by the vector x T = (x 1, x 2,..., x N ) and the zero cost condition becomes N x i = 0 = x T 1, i=1 with 1 the (column) vector of 1 s. (Positive positions in some assets must be financed by short sales of others.) Property 2: P has zero sensitivity (zero beta) to the common factor: 6 N x i β i = 0 = x T β. i Property 3: P is a well-diversified portfolio. The specific risk of P is (almost) totally eliminated: N x 2 i σ 2 ε i = 0. i The APT builds on the assumed existence of such a portfolio, which requires a rich market structure. 6 Remember that the beta of a portfolio is the weighted sum of the betas of the assets in the portfolio. 4

13.3.2 Statement and Proof of the APT The APT relationship is the direct consequence of the factor structure hypothesis, the existence of a portfolio P satisfying these conditions, and the no-arbitrage assumption. Given that returns have the structure of Equation (13.1), Properties 2 and 3 imply that P is riskless. The fact that P has zero cost (Property 1) then entails that an arbitrage opportunity will exist unless: r P = 0 = x T r (13.2) The APT theorem states, as a consequence of this succession of statements, that there must exist scalars λ 0, λ 1, such that: r = λ 0 1 + λ 1 β, or r i = λ 0 + λ 1 β i for all assets i (13.3) This is the main equation of the APT. Equation (13.3) and Properties 1 and 2 are statements about 4 vectors: x, β, 1, and r. Property 1 states that x is orthogonal to 1. Property 2 asserts that x is orthogonal to β. Together these statements imply a geometric configuration that we can easily visualize if we fix the number of risky assets at N = 2, which implies that all vectors have dimension 2. This is illustrated in Figure 13.1. Insert Figure 13.1 Equation (13.3) no arbitrage implies that x and r are orthogonal. But this means that the vector r must lie in the plane formed by 1 and β, or, that r can be written as a linear combination of 1 and β, as Equation (13.3) asserts. More generally, one can deduce from the triplet N N x i = x i β i = i i that there exist scalars λ 0, λ 1, such that: N x i r i =0 i r i = λ 0 + λ 1 β i for all i. This is a consequence of the orthonormal projection of the vector r i into the subspace spanned by the other two. 13.3.3 Meaning of λ 0 and λ 1 Suppose that there exists a risk-free asset or, alternatively, that the sufficiently rich market structure hypothesis permits constructing a fully diversified portfolio with zero-sensitivity to the common factor (but positive investment). Then r f = r f = λ 0. 5

That is, λ 0 is the return on the risk-free asset or the risk-free portfolio. Now let us compose a portfolio Q with unitary sensitivity to the common factor β = 1. Then applying the APT relation, one gets: r Q = r f + λ 1 1 Thus, λ 1 = r Q r f, the excess-return on the pure-factor portfolio Q. It is now possible to rewrite equation (13.3) as: r i = r f + β i ( r Q r f ). (13.4) If, as we have assumed, the unique common factor is the return on the market portfolio, in which case Q = M and r Q r M, then Equation (13.4) is simply the CAPM equation: r i = r f + β i ( r M r f ). 13.4 Multifactor Models and the APT The APT approach is generalizable to any number of factors. It does not, however, provide any clue as to what these factors should be, or any particular indication as to how they should be selected. This is both its strength and its weakness. Suppose we can agree on a two-factor model: r j = a j + b j1 F1 + b j2 F2 + ẽ j (13.5) ( ) ( ) with Eẽ j = 0, cov F1, ε j = cov F2, ε j = 0, j, and cov ( ε j, ε k ) = 0, j k. As was the case for Equation (13.1), Equation (13.5) implies that one cannot reject, empirically, the hypothesis that the ex-post return on an asset j has two stochastic components: one specific, (ẽ j ), and one systematic, (b j1 F1 + b j2 F2 ). What is new is that the systematic component is not viewed as the result of a single common factor influencing all assets. Common or systematic issues may now be traced to two fundamental factors affecting, in varying degrees, the returns on individual assets (and thus on portfolios as well). Without loss of generality we may assume that these factors are uncorrelated. As before, an expression such as Equation (13.5) is useful only to the extent that it describes a relationship that is relatively stable over time. The two factors F 1 and F 2 must really summarize all that is common in individual asset returns. What could these fundamental factors be? In an important article, Chen, Roll, and Ross (1986) propose that the systematic forces influencing returns must be those affecting discount factors and expected cash flows. They then isolate a set of candidates such as industrial production, expected and unexpected inflation, measures of the risk premium and the term structure, and even oil prices. At the end, they conclude that the most significant determinants of asset returns are industrial production (affecting cash flow expectations), changes in the risk premium measured as the spread between the yields on low- and high-risk corporate bonds (witnessing changes in the market risk appetite), and 6

twists in the yield curve, as measured by the spread between short- and longterm interest rates (representing movements in the market rate of impatience). Measures of unanticipated inflation and changes in expected inflation also play a (less important) role. Let us follow, in a simplified way, Chen, Roll, and Ross s lead and decide that our two factors are industrial production (F 1 ) and changes in the risk premium (F 2 ). How would we go about implementing the APT? First we have to measure our two factors. Let IP (t) denote the rate of industrial production in month t; then MP (t) = log IP (t) log IP (t 1) is the monthly growth rate of IP. This is our first explanatory variable. To measure changes in the risk premium, let us define UP R(t) = Baa and under bond portfolio return(t) LGB(t) where LGB(t) is the return on a portfolio of long-term government bonds. With these definitions we can rewrite Equation (13.5) as r jt = a j + b j1 MP (t) + b j2 UP R (t) + ẽ j The b jk, k = 1, 2, are often called factor loadings. They can be estimated directly by multivariate regression. Alternatively, one could construct pure factor portfolios well-diversified portfolios mimicking the underlying factors and compute their correlation with asset j. The pure factor portfolio P 1 would be a portfolio with b P1 = 1 and b P2 = σ ep1 = 0; portfolio P 2 would be defined similarly to track the stochastic behavior of UP R(t). Let us go on hypothesizing (wrongly according to Chen, Roll, and Ross) that this two-factor model satisfies the necessary assumptions (cov(ẽ i, ẽ j ) = 0, i j) and further assume the existence of a risk-free portfolio P f with zero sensitivity to either of our two factors and zero specific risk. Then the APT states that there exist scalars λ 0, λ 1, λ 2 such that: r j = λ 0 + λ 1 b j1 + λ 2 b j2. That is, the expected return on an arbitrary asset j is perfectly and completely described by a linear function of asset j s factor loadings b j1, b j2. This can appropriately be viewed as a (two-factor) generalization of the SML. Furthermore the coefficients of the linear function are: λ 0 = r f λ 1 = r P1 r f λ 2 = r P2 r f where P 1 and P 2 are our pure factor portfolios. The APT agrees with the CAPM that the risk premium on an asset, r j λ 0, is not a function of its specific or diversifiable risk. It potentially disagrees with the CAPM in the identification of the systematic risk. The APT decomposes the systematic risk into elements of risk associated with a particular asset s sensitivity to a few fundamental common factors. 7

Note the parallelism with the Arrow-Debreu pricing approach. In both contexts, every individual asset or portfolio can be viewed as a complex security, or a combination of primitive securities: Arrow-Debreu securities in one case, the pure factor portfolios in the other. Once the prices of the primitive securities are known, it is a simple step to compose replicating portfolios and, by a no-arbitrage argument, price complex securities and arbitrary cash flows. The difference, of course, resides in the identification of the primitive security. While the Arrow-Debreu approach sticks to the conceptually clear notion of states of nature, the APT takes the position that there exist a few common and stable sources of risk and that they can be empirically identified. Once the corresponding risk premia are identified, by observing the market-determined premia on the primitive securities (the portfolios with unit sensitivity to a particular factor and zero sensitivity to all others) the pricing machinery can be put to work. Let us illustrate. In our two-factor examples, a security j with, say, b j1 = 0.8 and b j2 = 0.4 is like a portfolio with proportions of 0.8 of the pure portfolio P 1, 0.4 of pure portfolio P 2, and consequently proportion 0.2 in the riskless asset. By our usual (no-arbitrage) argument, the expected rate of return on that security must be: r j = 0.2r f + 0.8r P1 + 0.4r P2 = 0.2r f + 0.8r f + 0.4r f + 0.8 (r P1 r f ) + 0.4 (r P2 r f ) = r f + 0.8 (r P1 r f ) + 0.4 (r P2 r f ) = λ 0 + b j1 λ 1 + b j2 λ 2 The APT equation can thus be seen as the immediate consequence of the linkage between pure factor portfolios and complex securities in an arbitrage-free context. The reasoning is directly analogous to our derivation of the value additivity theorem in Chapter 10 and leads to a similar result: Diversifiable risk is not priced in a complete (or quasi-complete) market world. While potentially more general, the APT does not necessarily contradict the CAPM. That is, it may simply provide another, more disaggregated, way of writing the expected return premium associated with systematic risk, and thus a decomposition of the latter in terms of its fundamental elements. Clearly the two theories have the same implications if (keeping with our two-factor model, the generalization is trivial): β j (r M r f ) = b j1 (r P1 r f ) + b j2 (r P2 r f ) (13.6) Let β P1 be the (market) beta of the pure portfolio P 1 and similarly for β P2. Then if the CAPM is valid, not only is the LHS of Equation (13.6) the expected risk premium on asset j, but we also have: r P1 r f = β P1 (r M r f ) r P2 r f = β P2 (r M r f ) Thus the APT expected risk premium may be written as: b j1 [β P1 (r M r f )] + b j2 [β P2 (r M r f )] = (b j1 β P1 + b j2 β P2 ) (r M r f ) 8

which is the CAPM equation provided: β j = b j1 β P1 + b j2 β P2 In other words, CAPM and APT have identical implications if the sensitivity of an arbitrary asset j with the market portfolio fully summarizes its relationship with the two underlying common factors. In that case, the CAPM would be another, more synthetic, way of writing the APT. 7 In reality, of course, there are reasons to think that the APT with an arbitrary number of factors will always do at least as well in identifying the sources of systematic risk as the CAPM. And indeed Chen, Roll, and Ross observe that their five factors cover the market return in the sense that adding the return on the market to their preselected five factors does not help in explaining expected returns on individual assets. 13.5 Advantage of the APT for Stock or Portfolio Selection The APT helps to identify the sources of systematic risk, or to split systematic risk into its fundamental components. It can thus serve as a tool for helping the portfolio manager modulate his risk exposure. For example, studies show that, among U.S. stocks, the stocks of chemical companies are much more sensitive to short-term inflation risk than stocks of electrical companies. This would be compatible with both having the same exposure to variations in the market return (same beta). Such information can be useful in at least two ways. When managing the portfolio of an economic agent whose natural position is very sensitive to short-term inflation risk, chemical stocks may be a lot less attractive than electricals, all other things equal (even though they may both have the same market beta). Second, conditional expectations, or accurate predictions, on short-term inflation may be a lot easier to achieve than predictions of the market s return. Such a refining of the information requirements needed to take aggressive positions can, in that context, be of great use. 13.6 Conclusions We have now completed our review of asset pricing theories. At this stage it may be useful to draw a final distinction between the equilibrium theories covered in Chapters 7, 8, and 9 and the theories based on arbitrage such as the Martingale pricing theory and the APT. Equilibrium theories aim at providing a complete theory of value on the basis of primitives: preferences, technology, and market structure. They are inevitably heavier, but their weight is proportional to their ambition. By contrast, arbitrage-based theories can only provide a relative theory of value. With what may be viewed as a minimum of assumptions, they only. 7 The observation in footnote 5, however, suggests this could be true as an approximation 9

offer bounds on option values as a function of the price of the underlying asset, the stochastic behavior of the latter being taken as given (and unexplained); permit estimating the value of arbitrary cash flows or securities using riskneutral measures extracted from the market prices of a set of fundamental securities, or in the same vein, using Arrow-Debreu prices extracted from a complete set of complex securities prices; explain expected returns on any asset or cash flow stream once the price of risk associated with pure factor portfolios has been estimated from market data on the basis of a postulated return-generating process. Arbitrage-based theories currently have the upper hand in practitioners circles where their popularity far outstrips the degree of acceptance of equilibrium theories. This, possibly temporary, state of affairs may be interpreted as a measure of our ignorance and the resulting need to restrain our ambitions. References Burmeister, E., Roll, R., Ross, S.A. (1994), A Practitioner s Guide to Arbitrage Pricing Theory, in A Practitioner s Guide to Factor Models, Research Foundation of the Institute of Chartered Financial Analysts, Charlottesville, VA. Chen, N. F., Roll R., Ross, S.A. (1986), Economic Forces and the Stock Market, Journal of Business 59(3), 383-404. Connor, G. (1984), A Unified Beta Pricing Theory, Journal of Economic Theory 34(1). Fama, E.F. (1973), A Note on the Market Model and the Two-Parameter Model, Journal of Finance 28 (5), 1181-1185 Huberman, G. (1982), A Simple Approach to Arbitrage Pricing, Journal of Economic Theory, 28 (1982): 183 191. Ross, S. A. (1976), The Arbitrage Pricing Theory, Journal of Economic Theory, 1, 341 360. 10