Stock Price Dynamics, Dividends and Option Prices with Volatility Feedback



Similar documents
Private Equity Fund Valuation and Systematic Risk

The Heston Model. Hui Gong, UCL ucahgon/ May 6, 2014

Lecture 1: Asset pricing and the equity premium puzzle

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

Options 1 OPTIONS. Introduction

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

Online Appendix. Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and. Equilibrium Prices. by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix

The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Online Appendix for Demand for Crash Insurance, Intermediary Constraints, and Risk Premia in Financial Markets

Valuation, Pricing of Options / Use of MATLAB

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

International Stock Market Integration: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

Likewise, the payoff of the better-of-two note may be decomposed as follows: Price of gold (US$/oz) Oil price

Quanto Adjustments in the Presence of Stochastic Volatility

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

Implied Volatility of Leveraged ETF Options

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

Lecture 6 Black-Scholes PDE


Optimal Insurance Coverage of a Durable Consumption Good with a Premium Loading in a Continuous Time Economy

Equity forward contract

Modeling the Implied Volatility Surface. Jim Gatheral Stanford Financial Mathematics Seminar February 28, 2003

Tutorial: Structural Models of the Firm

Article from: Risk Management. June 2009 Issue 16

Investment Statistics: Definitions & Formulas

Binomial lattice model for stock prices

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Valuing double barrier options with time-dependent parameters by Fourier series expansion

Pricing American Options without Expiry Date

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Machine Learning in Statistical Arbitrage

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Arbitrage-Free Pricing Models

On the Existence of a Unique Optimal Threshold Value for the Early Exercise of Call Options

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

Generating Random Numbers Variance Reduction Quasi-Monte Carlo. Simulation Methods. Leonid Kogan. MIT, Sloan , Fall 2010

The CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) NPV Dependent on Discount Rate Schedule

EXP Capital Markets Option Pricing. Options: Definitions. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices 1) C > 0

Option Values. Determinants of Call Option Values. CHAPTER 16 Option Valuation. Figure 16.1 Call Option Value Before Expiration

Lecture 1: Stochastic Volatility and Local Volatility

Expected default frequency

Option Values. Option Valuation. Call Option Value before Expiration. Determinants of Call Option Values

When to Refinance Mortgage Loans in a Stochastic Interest Rate Environment

Estimating Volatility

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 9. Binomial Trees : Hull, Ch. 12.

Mathematical Finance

Holding Period Return. Return, Risk, and Risk Aversion. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? An Example. Percentage Return or Dollar Return? 10% or 10?

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

How To Price A Call Option

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

Exam MFE Spring 2007 FINAL ANSWER KEY 1 B 2 A 3 C 4 E 5 D 6 C 7 E 8 C 9 A 10 B 11 D 12 A 13 E 14 E 15 C 16 D 17 B 18 A 19 D

The Black-Scholes Formula

Pricing and Risk Management of Variable Annuity Guaranteed Benefits by Analytical Methods Longevity 10, September 3, 2014

Markovian projection for volatility calibration

Pricing Options with Discrete Dividends by High Order Finite Differences and Grid Stretching

Key Concepts and Skills

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Interpreting Market Responses to Economic Data

Back to the past: option pricing using realized volatility

Capital Market Theory: An Overview. Return Measures

An Introduction to Modeling Stock Price Returns With a View Towards Option Pricing

IMPLIED VOLATILITY SKEWS AND STOCK INDEX SKEWNESS AND KURTOSIS IMPLIED BY S&P 500 INDEX OPTION PRICES

Risk Aversion, Investor Information, and Stock Market Volatility

OPTION PRICING FOR WEIGHTED AVERAGE OF ASSET PRICES

Numerical Methods for Option Pricing

Chapter 9. The Valuation of Common Stock. 1.The Expected Return (Copied from Unit02, slide 36)

More Exotic Options. 1 Barrier Options. 2 Compound Options. 3 Gap Options

Finite Differences Schemes for Pricing of European and American Options

Introduction to Options. Derivatives

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion

Caps and Floors. John Crosby

IMPLIED VOLATILITY SKEWS AND STOCK INDEX SKEWNESS AND KURTOSIS IMPLIED BY S&P 500 INDEX OPTION PRICES

Introduction Pricing Effects Greeks Summary. Vol Target Options. Rob Coles. February 7, 2014

High-frequency trading in a limit order book

Numerical PDE methods for exotic options

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

Models of Risk and Return

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia

Lectures. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Lisa Borland. A multi-timescale statistical feedback model of volatility: Stylized facts and implications for option pricing

Numerical methods for American options

Barrier Options. Peter Carr

Financial Options: Pricing and Hedging

Long Run Risks, Credit Markets, and Financial Structure

Implied Volatility of Leveraged ETF Options: Consistency and Scaling

Calculating VaR. Capital Market Risk Advisors CMRA

Transcription:

Stock Price Dynamics, Dividends and Option Prices with Volatility Feedback Juho Kanniainen Tampere University of Technology New Thinking in Finance 12 Feb. 2014, London Based on J. Kanniainen and R. Piche, Stock price dynamics and option valuations under volatility feedback effect, Physica A, 392, 722 740.

Intuition: What is Volatility Feedback? 1 An unexpected increase in squared volatility 2 Investors require more return to compensate higher risk 3 An increase in an instantaneous (stochastic) discount rate 4 Dividends are discounted at a higher rate 5 The expectation of future discounted dividends decreases 6 The stock price decreases, price-dividend ratio decreases and instantaneous dividend yield increases 7 An increase in squared volatility can decrease the value of an in-the-money call option with a convex payoff function through stock price and dividend yield It can be important to model how volatility drives dividend yield making it time-varying

Assumption 1: Returns, Volatility, and Risk-Return Tradeoff The cumulative return from dividends and changes in prices satisfies dr t = dp t +D t dt P t. The joint dynamics with its instantaneous volatility, x t, evolves as dr t = ( r +γx 2 t) dt+xt db r t dx t = βx t dt+σ x db x t, where r,γ,β, and σ x are constant positive real numbers. B r and B x are Brownian motions, db r tdb x t = ρ rx,t dt, and x 0 := x, x R. Consequently, squared volatility, h t = x 2 t, follows the squared root process, dh t = κ(θ h t )dt+σ h ht db x t with κ = 2β, θ = σ 2 x/(2β), and σ h = 2σ x.

Assumption 2: Dividends (i) The stochastic differential of dividends is given by dd t = αd t dt+y t D t db d t with db d tdb x t = ρ dx dt and D 0 := D, D > 0. The correlation coefficient of dividend growth and return volatility (leverage effect), ρ dx [ 1,1], and the expected rate of dividend growth, α R, are constant. Dividend growth volatility, y t, is stochastic. (ii) ( ) d sign dτ Cov ( t Dt,(x 2 ) t ) τ=t = sign(ρ dx ).

Assumption 3: Transversality Condition The stock price, p(d t,x t ), can be expressed as the expected value of discounted dividends, conditional upon the present information: [ s ] ( ) p(d t,x t ) = E D,x exp r +γx 2 u du D s ds t t [ s ( = D t E x exp α r γx 2 u 1 ) t t 2 y2 u du s ] + y u dbu d ds <. Here r +γx 2 u represents the instantaneous stochastic cost of capital at time u. t

Price-Dividend Ratio The price-dividend ratio, f : R R +, satisfies p(d t,x t ) = D t f(x t ). Hence, [ s ( f(x t ) = E x exp α r γx 2 u 1 ) s ] 2 y2 u du+ y u dbu d ds. t t t For all x > 0, f(x) = f( x) and so p(d,x) = p(d, x) (the sign of volatility does not matter) f is an even function, i.e., f(x) = f( x),f x (x) = f x ( x), and f xx (x) = f xx ( x) for all x > 0, where f x and f xx denote first and second order derivatives. For the stock price to be a continuously differentiable function, we can impose that f x (0) = 0.

Stock Price Dynamics with Time-Varying Dividend Yield Consequently, the stock price process, P t = p(d t,x t ), {P t ;t 0}, satisfies dp t = ( r +γx 2 t) Pt dt D t dt+x t P t dbt r ( = r +γx 2 t 1 ) P t dt+x t P t dbt r f(x t ) ( = r +γx 2 t 1 ) P t dt+y(x t )P t db d f x (x t ) t +σ x f(x t ) f(x t ) P tdbt x, where 1/f(x t ) is the instantaneous dividend yield and y(x t ) dividend growth volatility.

Solutions for Price-Dividend Ratio and Dividend Growth Volatility The price-dividend, f(x) ratio satisfies the following relation: (y(x)σ x ρ dx βx)f x (x)+ 1 2 σ2 xf xx (x) (r +γx 2 α)f(x) = 1, where dividend growth volatility, y(x), is given by ( ) f x (x) y(x) = ρ dx σ x f(x) +sign(x) x 2 (1 ρ 2 dx ) f x (x) 2 σ x. f(x) For the interval x 0, the boundary conditions are f(x) = 0 as x and f x (x) = 0 at x = 0. Note that y(x) = 0 if and only if return volatility x = 0. Moreover, the paper shows that sign(y(x)) = sign(x) and y( x) = y(x) for any x > 0. We used the bvp4c solver in the Matlab.

Numerical Illustration of Price-Dividend Ratio w.r.t. Volatility Price dividend ratio, f(x) 40 30 20 10 γ = 1; α = 0.02 γ = 2; α = 0.05 γ = 3; α = 0.08 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 Return volatility, x Figure: The price-dividend ratio, f(x), with respect to return volatility, x. The parameters r = 0.02, β = 0.5, σ x = 0.2, and ρ dx = 0.5.

Return Volatility vs Dividend Growth Volatility Return volatility is higher than dividend growth volatility, x 2 > y(x) 2, if and only if ρ dx < σ x f x (x) 2x f(x). Because the right hand side is always positive, returns fluctuate more than dividends if the correlation between dividends and return volatility is negative, ρ dx < 0, which indicates the financial leverage effect. Therefore, the excess volatility can be explained by implementing volatility feedback and leverage effects in the same model. This is in contrast to Shiller s argument that volatility is too high. If γ is relatively high, volatility feedback can amplify a very small but nonzero dividend growth volatility to a relatively high return volatility (the next slide).

Return Volatility vs Dividend Growth Volatility (cont.) Dividend growth volatility, y(x) 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 (a) 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Return volatility, x Ratio of return volatility to dividend growth volatility, x / y(x) 800 600 400 200 (b) 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Return volatility, x Figure: The parameters are γ = 3.115, α = 0.08, σ x = 0.2, β = 0.5, r = 0.02, and ρ dx = 0.5. In (a), dividend growth volatility is plotted against return volatility, and in (b) the ratio of return volatility to dividend growth volatility is plotted.

Alternatively, the dividend stream and return volatility can also be simulated together and the stock price is then given by P t = D t f(x t ). Simulation In discrete time with ǫ d,ǫ x N(0,1), Corr(ǫ d,ǫ x ) = ρ dx : [( P t+ t = P t exp r +γx 2 t 1 f(x t ) 1 ) 2 x2 t t x t+ t = x t exp( β t)+σ x +y(x t ) tǫ d t +σ x f x (x t ) f(x t ) tǫ x t ], 1 exp( 2β t) ǫ x 2β t. In each step, f(x), f x (x), and y(x) can be solved for a given x with the given PDE Note that the dividend process can be determined from D t = P t /f(x t ) or, alternatively, simulated directly: D t+ t = D t exp [(α 12 y(x t) 2 ) t+y(x t ) tǫ d t ].

Sample Paths 0.1 Squared return volatility, x 2 t 0.05 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.6 3.4 3.2 1.6 1.4 1.2 5 4.8 4.6 Log-price-dividend ratio, log(f(x t )) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Log-dividends, log(d t ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 Log-price, log(p t ) 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3

Sample Paths 0.1 Squared return volatility, x 2 t 0.05 1.92 1.915 Return volatility / Dividend growth volatility, x t /y(x t ) 1.91 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 0.8915 0.892 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 The correlation between returns and return volatility, ρ rx (x t ) 0.8925 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3

Risk-Neutral Dynamics Under the risk-neutral probability measure Q, dr t = rdt+x t d B r t, dx t = β(x t )x t dt+σ x d B x t, where B r t and B x t are under the probability measure Q, and β is the speed of the mean reversion under Q. The above is satisfied if with d B r t = db r t +γx t dt, d B x t = db x t + λ x(x t ) σ x x t dt x t d B r t = y(x t )d B d t +σ x f x (x t ) f(x t ) d B x t, where λ x (x t ) = β(x t ) β represents the volatility risk premium. For simplicity, λ x = β β is constant.

Option Valuation The price of a European call option can be computed as c(t,p t,x t,t,k,r,α;θ) = exp( r(t t))e Q t [ (PT K) +], where T is the time of maturity, K the exercise price, and θ = {σ x,β, β,γ,ρ dx } the set of structural parameters. To price options, we need to know not only parameters from volatility process, {σ x, β}, but also the price of diffusion return risk and volatility risk, {γ,λ x }. If γ = 0, then f = 1/(r α) an dividend yield equals r α. This corresponds an option pricing model with a constant dividend yield.

Option Valuation Specifically, even if {γ,λ x } do not directly appear in [( P t+ t = P t exp r 1 f(x t ) 1 ) 2 x2 t t ( ) x t+ t = x t exp β t +y(x t ) ] t ǫ d f x (x t ) t +σ x t ǫ x f(x t ) t, ) ( 2 β t 1 exp +σ x ǫ x t, 2 β they are need to compute f(x t ;γ,β,σ x,ρ dx ) every step (with β = β +λ x ). The price of diffusion return risk, γ, determines the sensitivity of dividend yield to return volatility and thereby affects option prices (vrt B-S).

Effect of Diffusion Return Risk on Call Prices Option Price ($), c(p 0, x 0 ) Initial Dividend Yield (%), 100% 1/f(x ) 0 12 10 8 6 4 2 T = 30 days T = 90 days T = 180 days Dividend Yield (%) 0 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 The price of risk, γ Figure: Parameters are r = 0.02, β = β = 0.5, α = 0.015, and ρ dx = 0.5. Moreover, x 0 = 0.2, P 0 = $100, K = $100, and t = 1/252 year.

Effect of Volatility Risk on Call Prices Option Price ($), c(p 0, x 0 ) Initial Dividend Yield (%), 100% 1/f(x 0 ) 7 6 5 4 3 2 (a) β = 0.5 1 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 The Price of Volatility Risk, λ x Option Price ($), c(p 0, x 0 ) Initial Dividend Yield (%), 100% 1/f(x 0 ) 6 5 4 3 (b) β = 0.5 2 0.2 0.1 0 0.1 0.2 The Price of Volatility Risk, λ x T = 30 days T = 60 days T = 180 days Dividend Yield (%) Figure: Parameters are γ = 2,r = 0.02, α = 0.05, σ x = 0.2, and ρ dx = 0.5. In plot(a) β = 0.5 and in (b) β = 0.5. Moreover, x 0 = 0.2, P 0 = $100, K = $100, and t = 1/252 year.

Effect of return volatility on the price of a European call option 25 (a) Fixed P 0, β = β = 0.5,σ x = 0.2 3 (b) Fixed D 0, β = β = 0.5,σ x = 0.2 Option Price, c(p0,x0) 20 15 10 5 Option Price, c(p0,x0) 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 Initial return volatility, x0 T = 30 days, ρ dx = 0.5 T = 90 days, ρ dx = 0.5 T = 180 days, ρ dx = 0.5 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 Initial return volatility, x0 T = 30 days, ρ dx = 0.5 T = 90 days, ρ dx = 0.5 T = 180 days, ρ dx = 0.5 Figure: γ = 2,r = 0.02, α = 0.05, β = β = 0.5, σ x = 0.2. Moreover, ρ dx = 0.5 (thicker lines) or ρ dx = 0.5 (thinner lines).

Calibration on Option Prices Option mid-prices on S&P500 inedx call options used to calibrate the model. In-sample data: 11,267 observations (150 trading days) Out-of-sample data: 7,320 observations (100 trading days) The loss function we use is the square root dollar mean-squared error, 1 n (ĉ(ti,p ti,t i,k i ) c(t i,p ti,x ti,t i,k i,ri T-bill,ᾱ;θ) ) 2, n i n denotes the number of contracts and ri T-bill the observed T-Bill rate. ĉ( ) is the price of the i-th option, c( ;θ) the corresponding model price, x ti VIX ti 1 denotes the volatility proxy used at time t i. ᾱ 6.13%, from monthly data on S&P 500 dividends

Empirical Results (i) γ free (ii) γ = 0 (iii) γ = 0 with r i = 2r T-bill i, α = ᾱ/2 β 1.2476 32.8570 1.3282 (0.0420) (2.5897) (0.0474) σ x 0.2713 0.6659 0.2666 (0.0032) (0.0271) (0.0035) ρ dx -0.6410 0.4241-0.8002 (0.0069) (0.0180) (0.0033) λ x -0.3376 (0.0128) γ 1.7929 (0.0099) $RMSEs Sample A 0.8111 1.1327 0.9114 Sample B 0.9355 1.6429 0.9859 Parameters of the variance process can be obtained by applying the relations: κ = 2β = 2.4952, σ h = 2σ x = 0.5426, and θ = σ 2 x/(2β) = 0.0288 (spesification i).

Specification (i) ρ dx is negative, indicating the existence of a leverage effect γ is about 1.8 and statistically significant the expected returns are related to squared return volatility the price-dividend ratio is sensitive to return volatility λ x is negative, -0.338, and that it has been estimated accurately Theoretical link between volatility risk premium and the price of diffusion return risk (see e.g. Bakshi and Kapadia RFS 2003): λ x (x t ) = γσ x d dτ Corr t(x t,r t ) τ=t = γσ x ρ rx (x t ), With our estimates, ρ rx 0.7879, σ x = 0.27 and γ = 1.79 yields the right hand side of to be about 0.38.

Specification (ii) γ = 0 excludes volatility feedback and implying that the price-dividend ratio, and then also the dividend yield, do not depend on return volatility. Both the in-sample (sample A) and out-of-the-sample (sample B) RMSEs are substantially higher than in specification (i). The estimate of β is not reasonable, for it implies that κ is greater than 60 Moreover, the ρ dx is substantially positive and contradicts the leverage effect. On the other hand, γ = 0 is not consistent with the observed interest rates and the dividend growth rate. In particular, the average dividend growth rate, ᾱ 0.0613, exceeds the T-bill rates that range from 0.054 to 0.0596 and imply that the dividend yield, 1/f = r α, takes negative values. Therefore, we constructed a third specification, by which we ensured that the dividend yield is always a positive constant.

Specification (iii) To have strictly positive dividend yields with γ = 0, we use r i = 2ri T-bill with α = ᾱ/2, where ri T-bill is the T-bill rate at date i. Makes parameter estimates with γ = 0 more realistic and both the in-sample and out-of-the-sample RMSEs decrease yet remain greater than in specification (i). These adjusted interest rate and dividend growth rate values are ad-hoc and do not represent the true economic situation. Rather, this specification shows that the poor performance and unrealistic estimates of specification (ii) can be partly explained by the fact that the assumption of γ = 0 contradicts the empirical observations of dividend growth and risk-free interest rates.

Conclusions Under volatility feedback effect dividend yield becomes time-varying and endogenously determined by total return volatility This implies that the stock price and dividend stream do not always move in the same direction the ratio of total return volatility to dividend growth volatility can be relatively high the market price of diffusion return risk (or equity risk-premium) affects option prices the market price of diffusion return risk can be estimated from option data the price of a call option can be decreasing in squared total return volatility Approximations or computational solutions needed to ease our progress Hedging under volatility feedback?

Thank you!