Problem Set 1 Solutions



Similar documents
PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

Health Economics. University of Linz & Demand and supply of health insurance. Gerald J. Pruckner. Lecture Notes, Summer Term 2010

Demand and supply of health insurance. Folland et al Chapter 8

Midterm exam, Health economics, Spring 2007 Answer key

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Why is Insurance Good? An Example Jon Bakija, Williams College (Revised October 2013)

What we ll be discussing

The Health Care Law and You

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Test 1 10 October Assume that tea and lemons are complements and that coffee and tea are substitutes.

Economic Policy Analysis: Lecture 6

Market Supply in the Short Run

Second Hour Exam Public Finance Fall, Answers

Chapter 5 Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior

Economics 335, Spring 1999 Problem Set #7

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Demand for Health Insurance

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

What we ll be discussing

Microeconomics Instructor Miller Practice Problems Labor Market

ECON 3240 Session 3. Instructor: Dr. David K. Lee

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 15 - Health Insurance US is only major industrialized nation that doesn t try to give universal health care

COST THEORY. I What costs matter? A Opportunity Costs

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Exam 2 Tuesday, November 6th, 2007

Costs of Production and Profit Maximizing Production: 3 examples.

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

Chapter 5. Linear Inequalities and Linear Programming. Linear Programming in Two Dimensions: A Geometric Approach

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

Pay for performance. Intrinsic (interested in the job as such) Extrinsic motivation. Pay Work environment, non-pay characteristics, benefits

Chapter 22 The Cost of Production Extra Multiple Choice Questions for Review

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Section 12.1 Social Insurance What is insurance? Individuals pay money to an insurer (private firm or gov).

The Cost of Production

Social Insurance Arises, In Part, Because of Asymmetric Information

Choice Under Uncertainty Insurance Diversification & Risk Sharing AIG. Uncertainty

The Central Idea CHAPTER 1 CHAPTER OVERVIEW CHAPTER REVIEW

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Elasticity. I. What is Elasticity?

3.3 Applications of Linear Functions

Intermediate Micro. Expected Utility

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection. Topic 6

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

EC306 Labour Economics. Chapter 3" Labour Supply and Public Policy

Insurance and Public Pensions : (b) Adverse Selection

1. a. (iv) b. (ii) [6.75/(1.34) = 10.2] c. (i) Writing a call entails unlimited potential losses as the stock price rises.

Notes on indifference curve analysis of the choice between leisure and labor, and the deadweight loss of taxation. Jon Bakija

I. Introduction to Taxation

Learning Objectives. After reading Chapter 11 and working the problems for Chapter 11 in the textbook and in this Workbook, you should be able to:

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton

Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment

6. It lengthened its payables period, thereby shortening its cash cycle.

Pricing I: Linear Demand

2. Information Economics

The Large Business Guide to Health Care Law

Econ 132 C. Health Insurance: U.S., Risk Pooling, Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard, Rand Study 7

Gov t Intervention: Price Floors & Price Ceilings / Taxes & Subsidies

Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 17 - Income distribution and Welfare programs Welfare policy in the United States Motivations - relative

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECN 221 Chapter 5 practice problems This is not due for a grade

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

Chapter 5 The Production Process and Costs

Overview: Transfer Pricing

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Medicare Part D. MMA establishes a standard Part D drug benefit, which consists of four components or phases.

CENTERS FOR MEDICARE & MEDICAID SERVICES. Cost

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Lesson 7 - The Aggregate Expenditure Model

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

How the New Health Care Law Benefits You

DEMAND FORECASTING. Demand. Law of Demand. Definition of Law of Demand

The Marginal Cost of Capital and the Optimal Capital Budget

Chapter 3 Productivity, Output, and Employment

Introduction. Asymmetric Information and Adverse selection. Problem of individual insurance. Health Economics Bill Evans

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Are You Paying for Performance? How to Measure Sales Compensation ROI The Sales Management Association

Sustainable Energy Systems

We never talked directly about the next two questions, but THINK about them they are related to everything we ve talked about during the past week:

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

Economics of Insurance

Consumers face constraints on their choices because they have limited incomes.

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Exam 2 Tuesday, November 6th, 2007

The Stewardship Role of Accounting

I d ( r; MPK f, τ) Y < C d +I d +G

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 13. THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

I. Introduction to Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

The Health Care Law and Medicare

3. a. If all money is held as currency, then the money supply is equal to the monetary base. The money supply will be $1,000.

5.4 Solving Percent Problems Using the Percent Equation

Transcription:

Health Economics Economics 156 Prof. Jay Bhattacharya Problem Set 1 Solutions A. Risk Aversion Consider a risk averse consumer with probability p of becoming sick. Let I s be the consumer s income if he becomes sick, and let I ns be his income if he does not become sick, with I s < I ns. Suppose the consumer cares only about his expected utility of income, which is given by: Expected Utility = pu( I s ) + (1 p) U( Ins ) 1. What does risk aversion imply about the consumer s marginal utility of income, U I? Risk aversion implies declining marginal utility of income (and vice versa). With declining marginal utility of income, the extra income gained in the healthy state over average income, EI = pi s + (1-p)I ns, is not as valuable as the income lost in the sick state relative to EI. Draw the consumer s utility curve, showing how utility changes with income. Utility U ns U s I s I ns Income On this same graph, show the consumer s utility when he is sick and when he is well. U s is the consumer s utility when sick, while U ns is the consumer s utility when not sick.

Finally, show the consumer s expected utility at different levels of p (the probability of becoming sick). The dark line connecting (I s, U s ) and (I ns, U ns ) shows the consumer s utility at different levels of p. If p=1, the consumer will certainly be sick, will earn I s and utility U s. If p=0, the consumer will certainly be well, will earn I ns and utility U ns. For levels of p in between zero and one, the consumer will earn I s with probability p and I ns with probability 1-p, so his expected utility will be a linear combination of U s and U ns, where the weights are p and 1-p (see the equation for expected utility above). Consequently, the consumer s expected utility will fall on the dark line connecting (I s, U s ) and (I ns, U ns ). 2. Since the consumer is risk averse, presumably he could raise his expected utility by buying an insurance plan. Actuarially fair plans are those insurance plans where the insurance company makes no profit. Full insurance in this case means the consumer has the same income whether or not he is sick. Let r be the payment from the insurance company to the consumer in the sick state and let q be the premium paid whether the consumer is sick or well. Since there is full insurance, the insurance plan must fully make up the difference in income between the sick and well states; thus r = I ns I s. What is the premium that the consumer pays for an actuarially fair full insurance plan? The insurance company s profits equal revenues (from the policy premiums) minus costs, which equal payouts to sick people. Since p percent of the population is sick, the company s expected payouts per policy are pr = p(i ns I s ), while revenues equal q. In a competitive situation, profits = q pr will equal zero, so premiums will equal p(i ns I s ). What is the payment by the insurance company when the consumer is sick? What is the payment if he is well? The consumer receives (I ns I s ) when sick and nothing when well.

3. Show the consumer s gain in expected utility from buying an actuarially fair full insurance plan on a copy of your graph from question one. Utility U ns U (with insurance) EU (no insurance) U s I s EI I ns Income With insurance, the consumer receives EI with certainty, and hence will have utility U(with insurance). We have seen in the answer to the previous question that the consumer will receive EU(no insurance) without insurance. The gain in utility from purchasing insurance is the difference U(with insurance) EU(no insurance). What happens to this gain in utility as the probability of illness approaches zero (the consumer is certainly well)? As the probability of illness approaches zero, the EI line shifts to the right toward I ns. The gap between U(with insurance) and EU(no insurance) will disappear as p approaches zero, so the welfare gain from insurance will also approach zero. What happens to this gain in utility as the probability of illness approaches one (the consumer is certainly sick)? As the probability of illness approaches one, the EI line shifts to the left toward I s. Just as before, the gap between U(with insurance) and EU(no insurance) will disappear as p approaches zero, so the welfare gain from insurance will also approach zero. 4. Given your answer to the previous question, would consumer welfare be enhanced by a government requirement that everyone buy insurance against lost income due to the common cold, which everyone gets at some time in their life?

No, since in this model, there is no welfare gain from insurance against certain illness. This counterintuitive result arises because insurance premiums rise to reflect the certainty of illness. 5. Show on your graph the highest premium consumers would be willing to pay for insurance (extra credit if you can show all this using algebra). Utility U ns U (with insurance) EU (no insurance) U s I s I 1 I 2 I 3 EI I ns Income Instead of offering a certain income of EI, suppose the insurance company offered a certain income of I 3 instead. The consumer s utility U(I 3 ) would be less than he would receive from actuarially fair full insurance U(EI) = U(with insurance), but he would still be better off than without insurance since U(I 3 ) > EU(no insurance). On the other hand, if the insurance company offered a certain income of I 1, then the consumer would be better off without insurance, since U(I 1 ) < EU(no insurance). In the insurance company offers I 2, the consumer is indifferent between being insured and not being insured. Hence, the most that consumers would be willing to pay for full insurance is when premiums are set such that the consumer receives I 2 as a certain income. Algebraically, at I 2, we have that U(I 2 ) = EU(without insurance) = pu(i s ) + (1-p) U(I ns ), so I 2 = U -1 [pu(i s ) + (1-p) U(I ns )]. Consumers pay a premium equal to the actuarially fair premium for full insurance p(i ns -I s ) plus the difference between EI and I 2, so the total consumer payments are p(i ns -I s )+(EI-I 2 ). What would the insurance company s profits be if they charged this premium, and consumers bought it? The insurance company pays out full insurance (I ns -I s ) when the consumer is sick, and since this happens with probability p, the company s costs are p(ins-is). Their revenues per policy equal consumer premium payments p(i ns -I s )+(EI-I 2 ). The company s profits equal revenues minus costs which are simply EI-I 2.

What might constrain insurance companies from charging this maximum premium? Competition. Insurance companies that charge such a high premium run the risk of being undercut by other insurance companies charging lower premiums. Any insurance company that charges more than actuarially fair premiums run this risk. B. Positive vs. Normative For each of the following statements, indicate whether the statement is making a positive point or a normative point. For each statement, suggest some government policy that someone who believes in the statement would probably support, if any. Limit your answer to one or two sentences per statement. 1. It is wrong for anyone to be denied health care, even if they cannot pay for it. Normative statement. A person who believes this might support universal government provided health care. 2. Raising the marginal tax rate on the rich will make health insurance cheaper for them. Positive statement. A person who believes this might support removing preferential tax treatment for employer provided health insurance purchases. 3. Sanitation is more important than health care in promoting the average health of the population. Though the statement is vague, it is most likely a positive statement since it is possible in principle that it could be proven false (given suitable definitions for more important and average health ). A person that believes this might support government projects designed to improve the quality of the water supply at the expense of health insurance provision. 4. People should be allowed to see the doctor of their choice. Normative statement. A person who believes this might support restrictions on the ability of health insurance plans to restrict the set of doctors that enrollees can see. 5. Doubling the price of a doctor visit reduces the demand for doctor visits by 10% Positive statement. Someone who believes this might support the introduction of copayments in insurance plans to limit moral hazard.

6. The government should not subsidize health insurance for people who have more than $1 million dollars in savings. Normative statement. Someone who believes this might support denying Bill Gates Medicare when he turns 65. 7. My utility function has the following elements: health, video games, health care. Positive statement. Someone who believes this might support supplying me with a fresh new copy of Warcraft III. C. Labor Market Disincentives of Medicaid Let I = the Medicaid income-eligibility threshold I = non-earnings income p = price of health care C = quantity of health care transferred w = wage L = hours of work per year Consider the following figure, which we used in class to discuss the labor market disincentive effects of the Medicaid program:

When income from earnings plus non-earnings income is above I (that is, I + wl > I ), eligibility for Medicaid (and the transfer of C) is lost. When hours of work are between L 1 and L 2 hours, the worker s total assets is less than when hours of work is less than L 1 or greater than L 2. Thus, workers have no incentive to work between L 1 and L 2 hours. 1. Suppose the state reduces the Medicaid income eligibility threshold, I. a. Would this make it easier or harder for people to qualify for Medicaid? Reducing I would make it harder to qualify for Medicaid. A numerical example might help here. Suppose I make $9,500 per year. If the Medicaid threshold is $10,000, then I would qualify, but if the threshold were reduced to $9,000, I would no longer qualify. b. What would happen to the size of the region where workers have no incentive to work? I 1 I 2 L 1 L 2 L 1 L 2 As the Medicaid threshold is reduced from I 1 to I 2, the size of the region where workers have no incentive to work stays exactly the same, but shift to the left. (Note in this figure, initial income I is set to zero). The dark solid line represents the old budget constraint, while the dark dashed line represent how this constraint changes as the Medicaid threshold is reduced. c. Would L 1 increase, decrease or stay the same? What about L 2? L 1 and L 2 would both shift to the left (decrease) by the same amount.

2. Suppose the state makes Medicaid more generous. That is, it increases C. a. What would happen to the size of the region where workers have no incentive to work? pc 2 pc 1 L 1 L 2 L 2 As Medicaid is made more generous (moves from pc 1 to pc 2 ), the budget constraint shifts upward so that the new portion of the budget constraint is represented by the dark dashed line. The size of the region where workers have no incentive to work increases. b. Would L 1 increase, decrease or stay the same? What about L 2? L 1 would stay the same, while L 2 would increase.