Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract



Similar documents
The Black-Scholes pricing formulas

Lecture 6 Black-Scholes PDE

Moreover, under the risk neutral measure, it must be the case that (5) r t = µ t.

The Black-Scholes Formula

Martingale Pricing Applied to Options, Forwards and Futures

where N is the standard normal distribution function,

How To Price A Call Option

1 The Black-Scholes model: extensions and hedging

Lecture 15. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Valuation of the Surrender Option Embedded in Equity-Linked Life Insurance. Brennan Schwartz (1976,1979) Brennan Schwartz

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Two-State Option Pricing

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

7: The CRR Market Model

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

Mathematical Finance

Finite Differences Schemes for Pricing of European and American Options

Lectures. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Chapter 1: Financial Markets and Financial Derivatives

Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model

Computational Finance Options

Bond Options, Caps and the Black Model

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Understanding Options and Their Role in Hedging via the Greeks

Monte Carlo Methods in Finance

Hedging Options In The Incomplete Market With Stochastic Volatility. Rituparna Sen Sunday, Nov 15

A SNOWBALL CURRENCY OPTION

Arbitrage-Free Pricing Models

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Option Pricing. Chapter 11 Options on Futures. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13/01/2014 at 14:25

Options 1 OPTIONS. Introduction

1.1 Some General Relations (for the no dividend case)

Session X: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics. Department of Economics, City University, London

The British Put Option - A Unique Protection Against Unfavourable Stock Move

The interest volatility surface

QUANTIZED INTEREST RATE AT THE MONEY FOR AMERICAN OPTIONS

The Effect of Management Discretion on Hedging and Fair Valuation of Participating Policies with Maturity Guarantees

LECTURE 9: A MODEL FOR FOREIGN EXCHANGE

Black-Scholes Equation for Option Pricing

Additional questions for chapter 4

On Quantile Hedging and Its Applications to the Pricing of Equity-Linked Life Insurance Contracts 1

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

Numerical methods for American options

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 9. Binomial Trees : Hull, Ch. 12.

More Exotic Options. 1 Barrier Options. 2 Compound Options. 3 Gap Options

Hedging. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Hedging

American Options. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan American Options

OPTION PRICING FOR WEIGHTED AVERAGE OF ASSET PRICES

Option Pricing. Chapter 4 Including dividends in the BS model. Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 6th November 2013

FORWARDS AND EUROPEAN OPTIONS ON CDO TRANCHES. John Hull and Alan White. First Draft: December, 2006 This Draft: March 2007

LECTURE 15: AMERICAN OPTIONS

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

Option Pricing. Chapter 12 - Local volatility models - Stefan Ankirchner. University of Bonn. last update: 13th January 2014

THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

Barrier Options. Peter Carr

COMPLETE MARKETS DO NOT ALLOW FREE CASH FLOW STREAMS

Convenient Conventions

Manual for SOA Exam FM/CAS Exam 2.

The Black-Scholes-Merton Approach to Pricing Options

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi. Option Pricing

Foreign Exchange Symmetries

Simulating Stochastic Differential Equations

ASimpleMarketModel. 2.1 Model Assumptions. Assumption 2.1 (Two trading dates)

Other variables as arguments besides S. Want those other variables to be observables.

Introduction to Stochastic Differential Equations (SDEs) for Finance

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Introduction to Mathematical Finance

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

Notes on Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula

Caps and Floors. John Crosby

LECTURE 10.1 Default risk in Merton s model

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach

Lecture 11. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 7

ENGINEERING AND HEDGING OF CORRIDOR PRODUCTS - with focus on FX linked instruments -

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Pricing Barrier Option Using Finite Difference Method and MonteCarlo Simulation

EXP Capital Markets Option Pricing. Options: Definitions. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices 1) C > 0

Pricing Options with Discrete Dividends by High Order Finite Differences and Grid Stretching

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

A Genetic Algorithm to Price an European Put Option Using the Geometric Mean Reverting Model

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

Chapter 13 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Merton-Black-Scholes model for option pricing. Peter Denteneer. 22 oktober 2009

A Martingale System Theorem for Stock Investments

Simple approximations for option pricing under mean reversion and stochastic volatility

MTH6120 Further Topics in Mathematical Finance Lesson 2

Valuation of American Options

Fair Valuation and Hedging of Participating Life-Insurance Policies under Management Discretion

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

Transcription:

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Jirô Akahori, Yuji Hishida and Maho Nishida Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, Ritsumeikan University 1-1-1 Nojihigashi, Kusatsu, Shiga 525-8577, Japan E-mail: {akahori, rp003994, rs028990}@se.ritsumei.ac.jp Abstract In this paper we study a pricing problem of an exotic Forward contract. Unlike the standard Forward, the contract is not fair, and like an option, it is compensated by the premium. Using standard arguments in the Black- Scholes economy, an explicit formula for hedging as well as pricing is obtained. This is possible because of an exotic way of settlement, which is another focus of this paper. Contrary to our intuition, simpler ways of settlement do not necessarily imply a simpler formula. 1 Introduction A Forward contract is an agreement between two parties to buy or sell an asset (which can be of any kind) on a pre-agreed future day at a pre-agreed price which is called Forward price. Usually the Forward price is set to make the contract fair, and so no payment takes place on the agreement day. For details of standard Forward contracts, see e.g. [2]. If an extra agreement that benefits one party only is added to the contract, as is the situation that we will study, then an adjustment is needed to keep the contract fair. There are two possibilities: one is by a change of the Forward price, and the other is by payment at the agreement day. In this paper we will study such a contract which we call exotic Forward. We adopt the latter adjustment and study the premium how much should be paid for the contract. The Exotic Forward we will study is defined by the following

Extra Agreement 1. A buyer has a right to choose the price-date at the delivery day between N 1 days before the delivery day and N 2 days after, with the Extra Agreement 2 (Settlement of Difference). A settlement day is the delivery day in both cases. If a buyer chooses the N 2 days after, the payment is taken by the way of settlement of difference; she/he is paid a pre-agreed price at the delivery day T. and then is paid the difference at T + N 2. We will give an explicit formula for the premium and the corresponding hedging strategy under a Black-Scholes type model. What interests us most is that the formula is very much alike the Black-Scholes formula for the plain European option. The reduction is caused by the exotic way of settlement (Extra Agreement 2). 2 The Setting and Notations We denote the delivery day by T, T 1 := T N 1, and T 2 = T +N 2. We assume the Black-Scholes Economy; i.e., a spot price S = {S t } 0 t T2 and risk-free bond B = {B t } 0 t T2 satisfy the following stochastic differential equations: ds t = σs t dw t + µs t dt db t = rb t dt (1) where σ > 0, r 0, µ R, and W is a standard 1-dimensional Brownian motion. For simplicity, we assume that B 0 = 1. Under these settings, the Exotic Forward contract in question is restated as follows. 1. The agreement day is time 0, when the Forward price K is quoted in the market. 2. The buyer pays the premium π on the agreement day. 3. On the delivery day T, the buyer chooses the price day; T 1 or T 2. 4. If she/he chooses T 1, she/he is paid S T1 K. 5. If she/he chooses T 2, she/he is paid Y T for the moment. 6. And then on T 2, she/he is paid the difference S T2 K Y T. Though studying general Y T is possible, we concentrate on the case Y T = S T K in this paper. 2

Before stating the results, we introduce some notations. Let d ± (t, x) = (r ± 1 2 σ2 )(T t) + log(2 e r(t 2 T) )x/s T1 σ T t (2) for t [T 1, T) and x > 0. We write simply d ± for d ± (T 1, S T1 ). That is, d ± = (r ± 1 2 σ2 )(T T 1 ) + log(2 e r(t 2 T) ) σ T T 1. (3) Let also A := {S T1 (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T }. (4) Finally, we use the following conventions: φ(x) = 1 2π e x2 2 (5) and Φ(x) = x φ(y) dy, (6) the density and the distribution function of the standard Gaussian random variable. 3 The Results The first result which corresponds to the pricing is the following. Theorem 1. Under the hypothesis of No-Arbitrage, the fair premium is given by π = S 0 e r(t T 1) Φ( d ) + S 0 (2 e r(t 2 T) )Φ(d + ) e rt K. (7) From the above result, we notice that the premium of this contract is represented by a mono-integral, even though this contract has several exotic aspects. We stress that when Y T = 0, i.e. no settlement of difference, the premium is no more mono-integral; a little far away from Black-Scholes formula. Further, we can also obtain the explicit hedging strategy for the seller as follows. 3

Theorem 2. The contract is perfectly hedged by holding η t = e r(t T 1) Φ( d ) + (2 { e r(t2 T) )Φ(d + ) =: η 0, η 0 + (2 e r(t2 T) )φ(d + (t, S t )) B } ts T1 φ( d (t, S t )) /σ T t, B T S t (0 t < T 1 ) (T 1 t < T) 1 A (T t < T 2 ) amount of the risky asset at time t [0, T 2 ), and ν t = K/B T =: ν 0, (0 t < T 1 ) ν 0 + (2 e r(t2 T) ) S tφ(d + (t, S t )) B 1 t σ T t { + S T1 B 1 T Φ( d (t, S t )) ν 0 + 1 A S T (B 1 T B 1 φ( d (t, S t )) σ T t T 2 ) + 1 Ω\A S T1 B 1 T }, (T 1 t < T) (T t < T 2 ) (8) (9) amount of the bond. Remark. The hedging strategy is statistical unless t [T 1, T), as is the case with standard Forward contracts; known as cost of carry (see e.g. [2]). The exotic aspect of our contract forces the seller to hedge dynamically, though it is needed only for t [T 1, T). 4 No-Arbitrage Hypothesis Firstly, we review the consequences of the No-Arbitrage hypothesis on the Black-Scholes economy (1). Let (Ω, F, P) be a probability space on which W is defined, and {F t } be the natural filtration of W. Put θ := (µ r)/σ. The P-{F }-martingale Z t := exp(θw t 1 2 θ2 t) defines an equivalent probability measure ˆP by d ˆP dp = Z t, t [0, T 2 ]. (10) Ft The probability measure ˆP is usually called equivalent martingale measure, EMM for short, and plays a central role in the pricing of options and other derivatives. 4

The Black-Scholes economy (1) under the EMM is ds t = σs t dŵ t + rs t dt db t = rb t dt, (11) or equivalently S t = S 0 exp{σŵ t σ2 t 2 }, B t = B 0 exp{rt}. (12) where Ŵ t := W t θt is a standard Brownian motion on ({F t } 0 t T2, ˆP), as the Maruyama-Girsanov theorem says. The fair value at time t of a derivative whose pay-off at time T is H, which is the unique one that excludes arbitrage opportunities, is given by C t = e r(t t) E ˆP [H F t ], (0 t T) (13) the discounted conditional expectation of the pay-off random variable with respect to the EMM. The hedging strategy for the derivative is obtained via the stochastic differential expression of C; dc t = η t ds t + ν t db t (14) which means holding η amounts of the asset and ν amounts of the non-risky asset perfectly hedges the derivative. For details of the arguments in this section, see e.g. [1] or [2] and the references therein. 5 Pricing/A Proof of Theorem 1 In this section, we will give the value of the Exotic Forward following the framework of the previous section. To apply (13), we unify the cash flows as an F T2 measurable random variable. Let us define an F T measurable set A(Y T ) := {S T1 K Y T + e r(t2 T) E ˆP [S T2 K Y T F T ]} = {S T1 K (1 e r(t2 T) )Y T + S T e r(t2 T) K} = {S T1 S T (1 e r(t2 T) )(Y T + K)}. (15) 5

On A(Y T ), the buyer is sure to choose T 2 as the price-date, while on Ω\A(Y T ) she/he will not fail to choose T 1. The cash flow on Ω \ A(Y T ) is S T1 K at T, and will be e r(t 2 T) (S T1 K) (16) at T 2, if all is invested to the bond. While on A(Y T ), applying the same argument as above, the cash flow at T 2 is e r(t2 T) Y T + S T2 K Y T = (e r(t2 T) 1)Y T + S T2 K. Hence, the pay-off at T 2 of the exotic forward can be seen as H(Y T ) = 1 Ω\A(YT )e r(t2 T) (S T1 K) + 1 A(YT ){(e r(t2 T) 1)Y T + S T2 K}. Therefore, applying (13), we have (17) (18) C t (Y T ) = e r(t 2 t) E ˆP [H(Y T ) F t ] (0 t T 2 ) and if t T 1, = e r(t 2 t) e r(t 2 T) E ˆP [1 Ω\A(YT )(S T1 K) F t ] + e r(t 2 t) E ˆP [1 A(YT ){(e r(t 2 T) 1)Y T } F t ] + e r(t 2 t) E ˆP [1 A(YT )(S T2 K) F t ], = e r(t t) E ˆP [1 Ω\A(YT )(S T1 K) F t ] + e r(t t) E ˆP [1 A(YT ){(1 e r(t 2 T) )Y T } F t ] + E ˆP [1 A(YT )(e rt E ˆP [e rt 2 S T2 F T ] e r(t 2 t) K) F t ] = e r(t t)( E ˆP [1 Ω\A(YT )(S T1 K) F t ] + E ˆP [1 A(YT ){(1 e r(t 2 T) )Y T + S T e r(t 2 T) K} F t ] ) (19) (20) = e r(t t) E ˆP [max ( S T1 K, (1 e r(t2 T) )Y T + S T e r(t2 T) K ) F t ]. In particular, we see that C t (S T K) = e r(t t) E ˆP [max ( S T1, (2 e r(t2 T) ) )S T Ft ] e r(t t) K, (21) 6

and π = C 0 (S T K) = e rt E ˆP [max ( S T1, (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T ) ] e rt K. (22) We will calculate the expectation in (22), to complete the proof of Theorem 1. The most remarkable property is that A(S T K) is independent of F t for any t T 1, since A(S T K) ={S T1 K (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T K} ={S T1 (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T } = A ={log S 0 + σŵ T1 + (r 1 2 σ2 )T 1 log S 0 + σŵ T + (r 1 2 σ2 )T + log(2 e r(t 2 T) )} (23) = { Ŵ T Ŵ T1 (r 1 2 σ2 )(T T 1 ) + log(2 e r(t 2 T) ) σ ={Ŵ T Ŵ T1 d T T1 }. Therefore, π = e rt E ˆP [S T1 ; Ω \ A] + (2 e r(t2 T) )e rt E ˆP [S T ; A] Ke rt = e rt E ˆP [S T1 ]{ ˆP(Ω \ A) + (2 e r(t2 T) )E ˆP [S T /S T1 ; A]} = e r(t T1) S 0 {Φ( d ) + (2 e r(t2 T) )E ˆP [S T /S T1 ; A]}. (24) Noting that S T /S T1 = exp{σ(ŵ T Ŵ T1 ) σ2 2 (T T 1)}, (25) 7

we have E ˆP [S T /S T1 ; A] σ2 (r = e 2 )(T T 1) = e r(t T 1) y d = e r(t T 1) Φ(d + ). By (24) and (26), we obtain (7). y d 1 2π e y2 2 e yσ T T 1 dy 1 2π e 1 2 (y σ T T 1 ) 2 dy (26) Remark. For the cases of Y T = 0, the set A(0) defined in (15) is no longer independent of F T1, and therefore the pricing formula is somehow more complicated than (7). On the other hand, if we have Y T = cs T K (27) for any deterministic c, then A(Y T ) is again independent of F T1. Further generalizations of (27) are possible and will be studied elsewhere. 6 Hedging/A Proof of Theorem 2 As was mentioned in section 4, the expression (14) gives the hedging strategy. Let us start with (19), the expression for all t [0, T 2 ]: C t C t (S T K) = e r(t t) E ˆP [1 Ω\A (S T1 K) F t ] + e r(t2 t) E ˆP [1 A {(e r(t2 T) 1)(S T K)} F t ] + e r(t2 t) E ˆP [1 A (S T2 K) F t ] = e r(t t) E ˆP [1 Ω\A S T1 F t ] e r(t t) K + e r(t2 t) E ˆP [1 A {S T2 + (e r(t2 T) 1)S T } F t ]. (28) First, let us consider the case when t [T, T 2 ). Since all terms except 8

S T2 are F t measurable, we have C t = e r(t t) 1 Ω\A S T1 e r(t t) K + (e r(t t) e r(t 2 t) )1 A S T + 1 A e rt E ˆP [e rt 2 S T2 F t ] (29) = e r(t t) 1 Ω\A S T1 e r(t t) K + (e r(t t) e r(t 2 t) )1 A S T + 1 A S t. Therefore, we have dc t = 1 A ds t + {1 A S T (e rt e rt 2 ) + 1 Ω\A S T1 e rt e rt K}dB t. (30) Next, when t [T 1, T), C t = e r(t t) S T1 E ˆP [1 Ω\A F t ] e r(t t) K + e r(t t) (2 e r(t 2 T) )S t E ˆP [1 A S T /S t F t ]. (31) Since we have A = {S T1 (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T } = {S T1 /S t (2 e r(t 2 T) )S T /S t } = { log(s T /S t ) log(2 e r(t 2 T) ) + log(s t /S T1 )} (32) = {Ŵ T Ŵ t (r 1 2 σ2 )(T t) + log(2 e r(t2 T) )S t /S T1 } σ from (23), the conditional expectations in (31) are explicitly calculated as and E ˆP [1 Ω\A F t ] = Φ ( d (t, S t )), (33) E ˆP [1 A S T /S t F t ] = e r(t t) Φ (d + (t, S t )). (34) Noting that Φ(±d ± (t, x)) C 1,2 ([T 1, T) R), we can apply Itô s formula to get dφ(±d ± (t, S t )) = x Φ(±d ± (t, x)) x=s t ds t + ( t + 2 1 σ 2 x 2 xx )Φ(±d ± (t, x)) x=s t dt = ± φ(d ±(t, S t )) σ T t [ S 1 t ds t (r + 2 1 σ 2 ± 2 1 σ 2 ) ] dt. (35) 9

Hence dc t = e rt {S T1 Φ( d (t, S t )) K} db t + e rt B t S T1 dφ( d (t, S t )) + (2 e r(t 2 t) ) [ Φ(d + (t, S t ))ds t + S t dφ(d + (t, S t )) + d Φ(d + ), S t ] = e rt {S T1 Φ( d (t, S t )) K} db t e rt φ(d (t, S t )) B t S T1 σ (S t 1 ds t rdt) T t + (2 e r(t2 t) ) [ Φ(d + (t, S t ))ds t + S t φ(d + (t, S t )) σ {S t 1 ds t (r + σ 2 ) dt} T t φ(d + (t, S t )) + σs t dt ] T t = [ ( (2 e r(t2 t) ) Φ(d + (t, S t )) + φ(d ) +(t, S t )) σ T t B ts T1 φ( d (t, S t )) B T S t σ ] ds t T t [ ( S T1 + Φ( d (t, S t )) + φ(d (t, S t )) B T σ T t (2 e r(t 2 t) ) S tφ(d + (t, S t )) B t σ T t ) K B T ] db t (36) Finally, consider the cases when t [0, T 1 ). Since A is independent of F t, from (28) we have C t = e r(t T1) S t ˆP(Ω \ A) e r(t t) K + e r(t t) (2 e r(t2 T) )E ˆP [S T1 F t ]E ˆP [1 A S T /S T1 ] = e r(t T1) S t Φ( d ) e r(t t) K + (2 e r(t2 T) )Φ(d + )S t. (37) Therefore, dc t = Ke rt db t + {e r(t T 1) Φ( d ) + (2 e r(t 2 T) )Φ(d + )}ds t. By (30), (36) and (38), we get (8) and (9). (38) 10

References [1] J. Akahori: Stochastic Analysis in Mathematical Finance, (in Japanese) Systems, Control and Information, 44, pp.429-433, 2000. [2] J. C. Hull Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, (5th Edition), Prentice Hall, 2002. 11