Notes on Optimal Taxation (Guest Lectures for Macro Analysis II)



Similar documents
Optimal Taxation in a Limited Commitment Economy

Optimal fiscal policy under commitment

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

A Model of Financial Crises

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Noah Williams Economics 312. University of Wisconsin Spring Midterm Examination Solutions

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

Dynamics of Small Open Economies

Money and Public Finance

Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

Business Cycle Accounting

Intertemporal approach to current account: small open economy

Optimal Income Taxation with Multidimensional Types

A Theory of Capital Controls As Dynamic Terms of Trade Manipulation

TRANSITIONAL DYNAMICS OF OPTIMAL CAPITAL TAXATION

Zero Nominal Interest Rates: Why They re Good and How to Get Them

Nonseparable Preferences and Optimal Social Security Systems

3 The Standard Real Business Cycle (RBC) Model. Optimal growth model + Labor decisions

The Real Business Cycle Model

Optimal Money and Debt Management: liquidity provision vs tax smoothing

Pareto Efficient Income Taxation with Stochastic Abilities

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Time Inconsistency and Free-Riding in a Monetary Union

Graduate Macroeconomics 2

SUSTAINABLE PLANS AND DEBT

Taxation, redistribution, and debt in incomplete market economies with aggregate shocks

Human Capital Risk, Contract Enforcement, and the Macroeconomy

New Dynamic Public Finance. Mikhail Golosov (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER) Aleh Tsyvinski (Yale, New Economic School, and NBER)

Lecture Notes 10

TAXATION AND SAVING. B. DOUGLAS BERNHEIM Stanford University, Stanford, CA National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

Towards a Structuralist Interpretation of Saving, Investment and Current Account in Turkey

Reforming the Tax System Lecture II: The Taxation of Savings. December 2015 Richard Blundell University College London

Taxes, debts, and redistributions with aggregate shocks

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

Lecture 1: The intertemporal approach to the current account

ECON4620 Public Economics I Second lecture by DL

Chapter 3: The effect of taxation on behaviour. Alain Trannoy AMSE & EHESS

ECON Elements of Economic Analysis IV. Problem Set 1

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Lumpy Investment and Corporate Tax Policy

Discrete Dynamic Optimization: Six Examples

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

On the irrelevance of government debt when taxes are distortionary

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Monetary Business Cycle Accounting

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Keywords: Overlapping Generations Model, Tax Reform, Turkey

Macroeconomics Lecture 1: The Solow Growth Model

Inflation. Chapter Money Supply and Demand

How To Find Out If A Tax System Is More Efficient

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

IMPLEMENTING ARROW-DEBREU EQUILIBRIA BY TRADING INFINITELY-LIVED SECURITIES

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February Ellen R. McGrattan

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey

The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth

Insurance and Taxation over the Life Cycle

Lecture 1: OLG Models

Teaching modern general equilibrium macroeconomics to undergraduates: using the same t. advanced research. Gillman (Cardi Business School)

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Cash-in-Advance Model

A Model of the Current Account

TAXATION AND SAVINGS. Robin Boadway Queen s University Kingston, Canada. Day Six

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM WITH BANKS AND THE FACTOR-INTENSITY CONDITION

Optimal Social Insurance Design: UI Benefit Levels

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

CHAPTER 7 APPLICATIONS TO MARKETING. Chapter 7 p. 1/54

Class Notes, Econ 8801 Lump Sum Taxes are Awesome

How To Understand The Relationship Between A Country And The Rest Of The World

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Non-exclusive Dynamic Contracts, Competition, and the Limits of Insurance

Sample Midterm Solutions

Prep. Course Macroeconomics

Leveraged purchases of government debt and deflation

EXHAUSTIBLE RESOURCES

Final. 1. (2 pts) What is the expected effect on the real demand for money of an increase in the nominal interest rate? How to explain this effect?

Investigación Operativa. The uniform rule in the division problem

SHARING DEMOGRAPHIC RISK WHO IS AFRAID OF THE BABY BUST?

Debt and the U.S. Economy

Unifying Time-to-Build Theory

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Decentralization and Private Information with Mutual Organizations

Real Business Cycle Models

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Real Business Cycle Theory

Health Insurance and Retirement Incentives

Private International Debt with Risk of Repudiation. Karsten Jeske. Working Paper a July Working Paper Series

Introduction to Money

Optimal Taxation with Incomplete Markets

The Optimal Use of Government Purchases for Macroeconomic Stabilization. Pascal Michaillat (LSE) & Emmanuel Saez (Berkeley) July 2015

Notes on Papers on Public Debt & Dynamic Public Finance

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Wealth vs. Income Taxes in a Model of Credit Constraints and Inequality

Transcription:

Notes on Optimal Taxation (Guest Lectures for Macro Analysis II) Roozbeh Hosseini April 2, 2012 1

Contents 1 Ramsey Taxation - Primal Approach 3 1.1 Ramsey problem................................. 5 1.2 Elasticities and optimal taxes.......................... 6 1.2.1 Additive separable utility functions................... 7 1.2.2 Quasi-linear utility function....................... 7 1.2.3 Complementarity with leisure...................... 8 1.3 Uniform commodity taxation.......................... 8 1.4 Intermediate good taxation........................... 9 2 Optimal Fiscal Policy-Dynamic Ramsey Taxation 12 2.1 Ramsey problem................................. 14 2.2 Chamley-Judd result............................... 15 2.2.1 Heterogeneous consumers........................ 16 2.2.2 Non-Steady State............................. 20 2.2.3 Werning (QJE, 2007)........................... 20 2.3 Taxing Capital in Life Cycle Economies (Erosa and Gervais (2002))..... 26 References 30 2

1 Ramsey Taxation - Primal Approach Consider an economy with n types of consumption good that are produced using labor input: F (c 1 + g 1,..., c n + g n, l) = 0 (1) c i is private and g i is public consumption of good i and l is the labor input. F is a constant return to scale technology. Consumers face the following maximization problem max U(c 1,..., c n, l) c 1,...,c n,l n p i (1 + τ i )c i = l i=1 in which τ i is the taxed levied on consumption of good i (wage is normalized to 1). There is a representative firm that produces goods using technology F : max x 1,...,x n,l n p i x i l i=1 F (x 1,..., x n, l) = 0 Government has to finance its purchase g = (g 1,..., g n ) using linear taxes τ i n n p i g i = p i τ i c i (2) i=1 i=1 Let s take government purchase as given. A Competitive Equilibrium is Consumers and producers allocations: (c, x, l) prices: p = (p 1,..., p n ) policy: π = (τ 1,..., τ n ) such that 1. Given policy π and prices p, (c, l) solve consumers problem. 2. Given prices, p, (x, l) solves producers problem. 3

3. Government budget (equation (2)) holds 4. Allocations are feasible (or market clearing if you like!) c i + g i = x i for i = 1,..., n (3) Proposition 1 Any competitive equilibrium allocations must satisfy the resource feasibility constraint F (c 1 + g 1,..., c n + g n, l) = 0 (4) and an implementability constraint n U i c i + U l l = 0. (5) i=1 Furthermore, any allocations that satisfy (4) and (6) can be supported as a competitive equilibrium for appropriately constructed polices and prices. Proof. Suppose (c, x, l) is a competitive equilibrium allocation. Then the following FOC must hold together with the following budget constraint U i U l = (1 + τ i )p i for i = 1,..., n n p i (1 + τ i )c i = l. i=1 Replacing out for prices (and taxes) from FOC into budget constraint gives the implementability constraint. The feasibility follows by definition of equilibrium. Now consider allocations (c, x, l) that are feasible (given vector of g) and satisfy (5). Construct prices from the FOC of the firm p i = F i F l for i = 1,..., n set policy as 1 + τ i = U i U l F l F i for i = 1,..., n 4

You can verify that the policy and prices (as constructed above) together with the allocation (c, x, l) is a competitive equilibrium. We are interested in the problem of choosing the best policy π to maximize the welfare of consumers. One restriction on such a problem is that the resulting allocation be a competitive equilibrium allocation for each given policy. The timing is the following: First, government chooses a policy, Second, private agents makes decision. We are interested in finding the equilibrium of this game. 1.1 Ramsey problem Suppose the set of feasible policy for government in Π. Definition 1 A Ramsey equilibrium is a policy π = (τ 1, τ n ) Π, allocation rules c( ), x( ) and l( ) and price function p( ) such that π arg max U(c(π ), l(π )) π Π n p i g i = i=1 n p i τ i c i and (c(π ), x(π ), l(π )) together with p(π ) is a competitive equilibrium for every π Π. Suppose π, (c( ), x( ), l( )) and p( ) is a Ramsey equilibrium. Then we call (c(π), x(π), l(π)) a Ramsey allocation. Proposition 2 Suppose c and l are part of a Ramsey allocation. Then i=1 (5) and (4). Proof. (c, l ) arg max U(c, l) c,l Follows from the definition of Ramsey allocation. 5

1.2 Elasticities and optimal taxes Suppose n = 2. Consider the following Ramsey problem max U(c 1, c 2, l) c 1,c 2,l 1. Implementability constraint U 1 c 1 + U 2 c 2 + U l l = 0 (6) 2. Feasibility F (c 1 + g 1, c 2 + g 2, l) = 0 (7) Let λ and γ be multipliers on implementability constraint (equation (6)) and feasibility (equation (7)). First order conditions are U i + λ (U i + U 1i c 1 + U 2i c 2 + U li l) = γf i i = 1, 2 We can write these equations as U l + λ (U l + U 1l c 1 + U 2l c 2 + U ll l) = γf l 1 + λ λh i = γ F i U i i = 1, 2 1 + λ λh l = γ F l U l in which, H i = (U 1ic 1 +U 2i c 2 +U li l) U i and H l = (U 1lc 1 +U 2l c 2 +U ll l) U l. Note that from individual problem we have 1 + τ i = U i U l F l F i in other words the optimal wedge must satisfy 1 + τ i = 1 + λ λh l 1 + λ λh i There you go! If H i > H j, then it is optimal to tax good i more than good j. 6

The problem is that, it is not very helpful. Unfortunately, without imposing assumption on U we cannot say much more. Next we consider some special (yet, interesting) cases. 1.2.1 Additive separable utility functions Suppose U is of the form U(c 1, c 2, l) = u 1 (c 1 ) + u 2 (c 2 ) v(l) then H i = U iic i U i Our goal to relate H i to income elasticity of demand for good i. In order to do that, suppose there is a non-wage income m, such that p 1 c 1 + p 2 c 2 = l + m. Consider FOC of consumer (notice that I have ignored taxes for this part) U i (c i (p, m)) = p i φ(p, m) in which φ(p, m) is the lagrange multiplier on budget constrain. Let s take derivative w.r.t m or Let η i = m c i c i m. Then c i U ii m = p φ i m = U i φ φ m U ii c i U i m c i c i m = m φ H i = m φ φ 1 m φ m. Therefore, H i > H j if and only if η j > η i. Combine this with the above and we get the following: η i Result 1 If preferences are additive separable, necessities should be taxed more than luxuries. 1.2.2 Quasi-linear utility function Consider the utility function in the previous section and assume that v(l) = l. Then there is no income effect and using income elasticities for guiding us about optimal taxes is not 7

useful. However, we use price elasticities. Consider again the FOC of consumer U i (c i ) = p i φ Note that in this case φ = 1 (independent of prices). Take derivative w.r.t p i and U ii c i p i = φ = U i p i H i = 1 ɛ i Result 2 If preferences are additive separable and quasi-linear, price-inelastic goods should be taxed more. 1.2.3 Complementarity with leisure Sandmo (1987) and Corlett and Hauge (1953-54) argue that goods that are more complement with leisure should be taxed more heavily. 1.3 Uniform commodity taxation One of the most useful and interesting result in optimal taxation is the uniform commodity taxation result. Suppose the preferences are weakly separable in consumption and leisure U(c 1,..., c n, l) = W (G(c 1,..., c n ), l) (8) furthermore, G( ) is homothetic. Proposition 3 Suppose preferences satisfy (8), then it is optimal to tax all goods at the same rate, i.e. τ i = τ j for all i and j. Proof. Note that the fact that G( ) is homothetic implies that U i (αc, l) U j (αc, l) = U i(c, l) U j (c, l) 8

or Differentiate w.r.t α and set α = 1 we get U i (αc, l) = U i(c, l) U j (c, l) U j(αc, l). n k=1 U ikc k U i = n k=1 U jkc k Also, note that U l = W l, U li = W lg G i and U i = W g G i. Therefore, U j n k=1 H i = U ikc k U i U ill U i n k=1 = U ikc k U i W lgl W g = H j This can be generalized to utility functions of the form u(c 1,..., c k, G(c k+1,..., c n ), l) in which, G( ) is homothetic. Then the result is that commodities (c k+1,..., c n ) should be taxed at uniform rate. Exercise: Suppose consumer is endowed with y unit of good one that cannot be taxed away. Does the uniform commodity taxation still hold? what if the utility function is additive separable? Exercise: Suppose government is restricted to setting taxed on c 1 to zero. How would modify the Ramsey problem? Does the uniform commodity taxation hold? 1.4 Intermediate good taxation Another powerful and important result in Ramsey taxation is that intermediate good shall not be taxed. Suppose there are two sectors. One sector produces commodity x 1 that is consumed by private agent, c 1 and by government, g. Commodity x 1 is produced using intermediate good z and labor l 1 as input according to the following production function f(x 1, z, l 1 ) = 0. 9

The other sector, uses labor l 2 as input to produce good x 2 that can be used as input in production of good x 1 (that is z) or it can be consumed (c 2 and g 2 ). The technology is the following h(x 2, l 2 ) = 0. Private agents solves max U(c 1, c 2, l 1 + l 2 ) c,l p 1 (1 + τ 1 )c 1 + p 2 (1 + τ 2 )c 2 l 1 + l 2. Producer of good x 1 solves max p 1 x l 1 p 2 (1 + τ z )z x 1,z,l 1 f(x 1, z, l 1 ) = 0. The FOC for this problem implies f z f l = p 2 (1 + τ z ). Producer of good x 2 solves max x 2,l 2 p 2 x 2 l 2 h(x 2, l 2 ) = 0. and FOC implies h x h l = p 2. Combining the FOC condition for two sector we get h x h l (1 + τ z ) = f z f l. Government budget constraint is τ 1 p 1 c 1 + τ 2 p 2 c 2 + τ z p 2 z = p 1 g 1 + p 2 g 2 10

Finally, feasibility and market clearing c 1 + g 1 = x 1 c 2 + g 2 + z = x 2 f(x 1, z, l 1 ) = 0 h(x 2, l 2 ) = 0 The Ramsey problem is max U(c 1, c 2, l 1 + l 2 ) U 1 c 1 + U 2 c 2 + U l (l 1 + l 2 ) = 0 λ f(c 1 + g 1, z, l 1 ) = 0 φ 1 h(c 2 + g 2 + z, l 2 ) = 0 φ 2 FOC w.r.t z φ 1 f z = φ 2 h x FOC w.r.t l 1 and l 2 U l + λ(u ll(l 1 + l 2 ) + U l + U clc) = f l φ 1 U l + λ(u ll (l 1 + l 2 ) + U l + U cl c) = h l φ 2 and therefore, f l φ 1 = h l φ 2. This implies that h x h l = f z f l It means that it is optimal to set τ z = 0 and not distort production efficiency. For more on intermediate good taxation and production efficiency see Diamond and Mirrlees (1971). 11

2 Optimal Fiscal Policy-Dynamic Ramsey Taxation The main focus of this section is the derivation of Chamley-Judd result (Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985)). We are only going to consider deterministic environment. See Chari and Kehoe (1994) and Chari and Kehoe (1998) for stochastic environment and optimal policy over business cycle. The environment is the following. There are infinitely lived identical consumers. Government has to finance expenditure g t every period and levies distortionary taxes (or subsidies) on consumption, investment, labor and capital income. It can also issue debt. Consumer s problem: consumers are endowed with k 0 unit of capital and b 0 unit of government debt max c t,l t,x t,k t+1,b t+1 β t U(c t, l t ) (1 + τ ct )c t + (1 + τ xt )x t + b t+1 (1 τ lt )w t l t + (1 τ kt )r t k t + R bt b t ; λ t k t+1 (1 δ)k t + x t b t+1 M in which M is some large positive number. The FOC s are k 0, b 0 given β t U ct = λ t (1 + τ ct ) (9) β t U lt = λ t w t (1 τ lt ) (10) (1 + τ xt )λ t = λ t+1 [(1 τ xt+1 )(1 δ) + (1 τ kt+1 )r t+1 ] (11) λ t = λ t+1 R bt+1 (12) Government Budget: g t + R bt b t = b t+1 + τ xt x t + τ ct c t + τ lt w t l t + τ kt r t k t (13) Feasibility: c t + g t + k t+1 = F (k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t (14) 12

Competitive pricing implies that r t = F k (k t, l t ) (15) w t = F l (k t, l t ) A competitive equilibrium is: the sequence of allocations x = {c t, l t, b t+1, k t+1, x t }, prices {r t, w t, R bt }, policy π = {τ ct, τ lt, τ xt, τ kt+1 } such that, the allocations solve consumer problem, given prices and policy, prices are competitive, government budget holds and allocations are feasible. A Ramsey Equilibrium is a policy π, an allocation rule x( ) and price rules r( ), w( ) and R b ( ) such that: π arg max β t U(c t, l t ) 12 and x(π) be a competitive equilibrium, and for any policy π, allocation x(π ) and prices (r(π ), w(π ), R b (π )) be a competitive equilibrium. We next derive the implementability condition. Note that if conditions of Ekeland and Scheinkman (1986) and/or Weitzman (1973) are satisfied, then the equilibrium allocations should also satisfy the following Transversality conditions lim tb t+1 t = 0 (16) lim tk t+1 t = 0 (17) Now multiply consumer s budget constraint by λ t and sum over t and use (16)-(17) λ t [(1 + τ ct )c t + (1 + τ xt )(k t+1 (1 δ)k t ) + b t+1 ] = λ t [(1 τ lt )w t l t + (1 τ kt )r t k t + R bt b t ]. Now use (9)-(12) and we get λ t [(1 + τ ct )c t (1 τ lt )w t l t ] = λ 0 {[(1 + τ x0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k 0 + R b0 b 0 }. 13

Now replace (9)-(10) and we arrive at the implementability constraint β t [U ct c t + U lt l t ] = U 0 {[(1 + τ x0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k 0 + R b0 b 0 } (18) Proposition 4 A feasible allocation x = {c t, l t, b t+1, k t+1, x t } is a competitive equilibrium allocation if and only it satisfies the implementability constraint (18) (for some period zero policies). Proof. Suppose x is the competitive equilibrium allocation, then following the steps outlines above we can show that it should satisfy the implementability constraint (18). Now suppose an allocation x is feasible and satisfy (18) for some period zero policies. Note that in any competitive equilibrium, the bond holding must satisfy b t+1 = s=t+1 β t s [U csc s + U ls l s ] U ct k t+1 (19) in other words, any sequence of c t, lt and kt+1 uniquely identifies a sequence of b t that is a part of competitive equilibrium. Candidate wage and rate of return on capital is given by (15). Therefore, from the FOC (9)-(12) we have 1 τ lt = U lt 1 + τ ct Flt U ct Uct (1 + τ xt ) = β U [ ] ct+1 (1 τxt+1 )(1 δ) + (1 τ kt+1 )Fkt+1 1 + τ ct 1 + τ ct+1 Uct = β U ct+1 R bt+1 1 + τ ct 1 + τ ct+1 (20) any two of the four taxes can be chosen such that the above conditions hold. 2.1 Ramsey problem The Ramsey problem is the following max c t,k t+1,l t β t U(c t, l t ) 14

β t [U ct c t + U lt l t ] = U 0 {[(1 + τ x0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k 0 + R b0 b 0 } ; λ c t + g t + k t+1 = F (k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t ; φ t Define function W (,, ) as W (c, l, λ) = U(c, l) + λ [U c c + U l l]. Now we can rewrite the Ramsey problem as max c t,k t+1,l t β t W (c t, l t, λ) c t + g t + k t+1 = F (k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t ; φ t Take first order conditions W lt W ct = F lt (21) W ct W ct+1 = β(1 δ + F kt ) for t 1 (22) 2.2 Chamley-Judd result Proposition 5 If the solution to the Ramsey problem converges to a steady state, then at the steady state, the tax rate on capital income is zero. Proof. In (22) at the steady state we have β(1 δ + F kt+1 ) = 1. This implies that at the steady state there is no inter-temporal distortion. Compare with (20) we have [ (1 + τ xt )(1 + τ ct+1 ) (1 + τ ct )(1 + τ xt+1 ) = β 1 δ + 15 ( ) ] 1 τkt+1 F kt+1 1 + τ xt+1

Note that any feasible allocation that satisfies (18) can be implemented by two of the four taxes (that is we only need two of the τ c, τ l,τ x and τ k to implement the same allocations). This in turn implies that τ kt = 0 1 + τ ct 1 + τ xt = constant 2.2.1 Heterogeneous consumers Suppose there are two type of consumers i = 1, 2 with preferences β t U i (c it, l it ) The resources constraint for the economy is implementability constraint for consumer i is c 1t + c 2t + k t+1 = F (k t, l 1t, l 2t ) + (1 δ)k t (23) β [ ] { } t Uctc i it + Ultl i it = U i 0 [(1 + τx0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k0 i + R b0 b i 0 (24) Suppose government puts welfare weights ω i on consumers of type i. The Ramsey problem is (23) and (24). max ω 1 β t U 1 (c 1t, l 1t ) + ω 2 β t U 2 (c 2t, l 2t ) Attached multiplier λ i to implementability constraint of type i and write W (c 1, c 2, l 1, l 2, λ 1, λ 2 ) = [ ( )] ωi U i (c i, l i ) + λ i U i c c i + Ul i l i i=1,2 16

max β t W (c 1t, c 2t, l 1t, l 2t, λ 1, λ 2 ) c 1t + c 2t + k t+1 = F (k t, l 1t, l 2t ) + (1 δ)k t ; φ t where W i is defined the obvious way. First order conditions imply W cit = βw cit+1 (1 δ + F kt+1 ) and in the steady state 1 = β(1 δ + F kt+1 ) and, therefore, tax on capital should be zero in the steady state. Capitalists vs Workers (Judd 1985) Suppose consumer of type 1 does not hold any asset and cannot save, borrow or invest. We call these Worker. Also, assume that all the capital is held by consumer 2 who do not supply any labor. We call these Capitalists. The implementability constraint for Worker is Uctc 1 1t + Ultl 1 1t = 0 t and for Capitalist β [ ] { } t Uctc 2 2t = U 2 0 [(1 + τx0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k0 2 + R b0 b 2 0 (25) Suppose the welfare weight on Worker utility is 1 and on Capitalist utility is zero. β t Uctc 2 2t = U0 2 max β t U 1 (c 1t, l 1t ) Uctc 1 1t + Ultl 1 1t = 0 t { [(1 + τx0 )(1 δ) + (1 τ k0 )r 0 ] k0 2 + R b0 b0} 2 (26) c 1t + c 2t + k t+1 = F (k t, l 1t, l 2t ) + (1 δ)k t ; φ t 17

Define W (c 1, c 2, l 1, l 2, λ 1, λ 2 ) = U 1 (c 1, l 1 ) + λ i ( U i c c i + U i l l i ) First order conditions λβ t [ U 2 cctc 2t + U 2 ct] + φt = 0 in steady state φ t+1 = βφ t and therefore φ t = φ t+1 (1 δ + F kt+1 ) 1 = β(1 δ + F kt+1 ) and again, tax of capital is zero in the steady state. Exercise: In the above set up we have implicitly assumed that government can levy different taxes on different consumer types. How would you add the following restrictions to the problem 1. Tax on capital income has to be uniform across different types. Does the result hold with this restriction? Under what assumptions? 2. Tax on labor income has to be uniform across different types. Does the result hold? Under what assumptions? 3. Tax on capital income cannot be more than 100 percent. Does the result hold? Under what assumptions? Dividend Taxes?!!! (an interesting example) Suppose we write the environment as in McGrattan and Prescott (2005) with corporate taxes and dividend taxes. Consumers can trade share of corporations, s t, at price v t. Let d t be dividend and τ dt be dividend tax. Consumers solve max c t,s t+1,l t β t U(c t, l t ) p t [c t + v t (s t+1 s t )] p t [(1 τ dt )d t s t + (1 τ lt )w t l t ] s 0 = 1 18

FOC implies U ct U lt = (1 τ lt )w t p t v t = p t+1 v t+1 + p t+1 (1 τ dt+1 )d t+1 And therefore implementability constraint is β t [U ct c t + U lt l t ] = U c0 [v 0 + (1 τ d0 )d 0 ] s 0 (27) There is a corporation that maximizes the present discounted value of owners dividends and pays taxes τ t on corporate income. max p t (1 τ dt )d t d t = f(k t, l t ) x t w t l t τ t (f(k t, l t ) δk t w t l t ) First order conditions for the corporation is k t+1 = (1 δ)k t + x t For this economy the feasibility is f lt = w t p t (1 τ dt ) p t+1 (1 τ dt+1 ) = 1 (1 τ t+1)(f kt+1 δ) c t + k t+1 + g t = f(k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t s t = 1 and there is also a government budget constraint p t g t = p t [τ dt d t s t + τ t (f(k t, l t ) δk t w t l t ) + τ lt w t l t ] Question: What is the appropriate implementability constraint? Is constraint (27) sufficient? In other words, is it true that any feasible allocation that satisfy (27) can be supported in a competitive equilibrium? If not, what other constraints should be added? 19

2.2.2 Non-Steady State Proposition 6 Suppose the utility function is of the form U(c, l) = c1 σ 1 σ v(l), Then Ramsey taxes on capital income is zero for t 2. Proof. Do it as an exercise. Exercise: Can you establish any connection between this result and uniform commodity taxation? 2.2.3 Werning (QJE, 2007) Werning (2007) studies a dynamic environment in which individuals are heterogeneous in their skills. Instead of ruling out lump-sum taxation, he allows them. However, he does not allow government to condition the lump-sum tax on individual skill. Instead he allows for a distortionary labor income (and capital income) tax that government can use to redistribute income across people with different skill. In some sense, it is one step away from traditional Ramsey setup, towards rationalizing distortionary taxes. The environment is the following: let c be consumption and l be the hours worked. Individual with skill θ who works l hours produce y = θl efficiency labor unit. If period utility over hours worked and consumption is U(c, l), then we can write it in terms of consumption and efficiency labor unit as U i (c, y) = U(c, y/θ i ). Suppose there are θ Θ = { θ i,..., θ N}. We call the individual of type θ i, person i or type i. The fraction of type i is π i. Assume i πi θ i = 1. Aggregate state of economy is s t S (finite set) and is publicly observable. Denote the history of aggregate shocks by s t = (s 0,..., s t ). Probability of history s t is Pr(s t ). Consumer problem Individual of type i solves max t,s t β t Pr(s t )U i (c t (s t ), y(s t )) (28) 20

sub. to p(s t ) [ c(s t ) + k(s t ) ] p(s t ) [ wt (s t )(1 τ(s t ))y(s t ) + R(s t )k(s t 1 ) ] T t,s t t,s t k i (s 0 ) = k0 i is given in which R(s t ) = 1 + (1 κ(s t ))(r t (s t ) δ) and T = t,s p(s t )T (s t ) is present value of t lump-sum taxes. Note that there is heterogeneity in skills θ i as well as initial capital holding k i (s 0 ). Feasibility Let L(s t ) = i πi y i (s t ), C(s t ) = i πi c i (s t ), K(s t ) = i πi k i (s t ). Then feasibility is C(s t ) + K(s t ) + g(s t ) = F (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) + (1 δ)k(s t 1 ) (29) Govern met Government has exogenously given sequence of expenditure g(s t ) to finance. It can levy linear tax on capital income κ(s t ). It can also levy the following tax on income τ(s t )w t (s t )y i (s t ) + T (s t ) Government budget constraint is [ p(s t )g(s t ) T + p(s t ) τ(s t )w t (s t )L(s t ) + κ(s t )(r t (s t ) δ)k(s t 1 ) ] (30) t,s t t,s t F irms As usual the firm s problem is static and implies marginal product pricing r t (s t ) = F k (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) (31) w t (s t ) = F L (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) Equilibrium is defined the usual way. Next we derive the implementability constraints. Werning (2007) develops a methodology that incorporates the fact that labor income taxes are uniform across types (so no extra constraint needs to be added to the optimal taxation problem). Also, he shows implementability constraints can be written only in terms of aggregates. 21

First observe that in any equilibrium U i y(s t ) U i c(s t ) U i c(s t ) U i c(s 0 ) = U j y(s t ) U j c (s t ) = w(st )(1 τ(s t )) (32) = U j c (s t ) U j c (s 0 ) = p(s t ) β t Pr(s t )p(s 0 ) i, j Therefore, given the aggregate consumption and labor output (C(s t ), L(s t )), the assignment of allocation of consumption and labor output {c i (s t ), y i (s t )} are efficient. In other words, given any sequence of aggregate output (C(s t ), L(s t )), there are weights ϕ = { ϕ 1,..., ϕ N} such that i πi ϕ i = 1 and {c i (s t ), y i (s t )} is the solution to U m (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) max π i ϕ i U i (c i, y i ) {c i,y i } sub. to π i c i = C(s t ), i π i y i = L(s t ) i Denote the solution by therefore c i = h i c(c, L; ϕ), y i = h i y(c, L; ϕ) (33) (c i (s t ), y i (s t )) = h i (C, L; ϕ) in which h i = (h i c, h i y). Note also that and therefore, in any equilibrium U m C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) = ϕ i U i c(c i, y i ) (34) U m L (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) = ϕ i U i y(c i, y i ) UL m(st ) UC m(st ) Uc m (s t ) Uc m (s 0 ) = w(s t )(1 τ(s t )) (35) = p(s t ) β t Pr(s t )p(s 0 ) i, j Now let s look at individual i s implementability constraint [ ] β t U i c (c i (s t ), y i (s t ))c i (s t ) + Uy(c i i (s t ), y i (s t ))y i (s t ) = U i c (c i (s 0 ), y i (s 0 )) [ R 0 k0 i T ] t,s t 22

Now we can replace individual i s allocations in terms of aggregate allocations using (33) and (34) [ β t U m C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ)h i c(c(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) = (36) t,s t +UL m (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ)h i y(c(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) ] = Uc(C(s i 0 ), L(s 0 ); ϕ) [ R 0 k0 i T ] i(37) Note that (36) is expressed entirely in terms of aggregate allocations, weights ϕ and initial endowments. Proposition 7 Given initial wealth R 0 k0, i an aggregate allocation {C(s t ), L(s t ), K(s t )} can be implemented in a competitive equilibrium if and only if 1. It is feasible 2. There exists weights ϕ and lump-sum T such that implementability constraint (36) holds for all i = 1,..., N Proof. Any equilibrium allocation is feasible and we just showed that it satisfy (36). Suppose there is a feasible aggregate allocation that satisfies (36) for sum weights and lump-sum taxes. Then individual allocations and prices can be constructed using (33) and (35). Then it is immediate that (32) (consumer optimality) holds. The individual allocations constructed as such are also feasible since they satisfy (36). A Panning Problem Suppose λ i is planer s weight on type i. problem i πi λ i = 1. Consider the following planning max t,s t,i λ i π i β t Pr(s t )U i (h i (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ)) sub. to [ β t U m C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ)h i c(c(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) t,s t +UL m (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ)h i y(c(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) ] = Uc(C(s i 0 ), L(s 0 ); ϕ) [ R 0 k0 i T ] i ; µ i π i 23

C(s t ) + K(s t ) + g(s t ) = F (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) + (1 δ)k(s t 1 ) Make our usual change of variable W (C, L; ϕ, µ, λ) π ( i λ i U i (h i (C, L; ϕ)) i +µ [ i UC m (C, L; ϕ)h i c(c, L; ϕ) + UL m (C, L; ϕ)h i y(c, L; ϕ) ] and rewrite the problem as max t,s t,i λ i π i β t Pr(s t )W (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) U i c(c(s 0 ), L(s 0 ); ϕ) i π i µ i [ R 0 k i 0 T ] sub. to First order conditions are C(s t ) + K(s t ) + g(s t ) = F (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) + (1 δ)k(s t 1 ) F L (K(s t 1 ), L(s t ), s t, t) = W C(C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) W L (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) W C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) = β in which R (s t+1 ) = 1 + δ + F K (K(s t ), L(s t+1 ), s t+1, t + 1). FOC with respect to tax on initial capital s t+1 s t W C (C(s t+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ, µ, λ)r (s t+1 )Pr(s t+1 ) µ i π i k0 i = 0 or R 0 = 0 i Optimal Taxes τ (s t ) = 1 U L m (C, L; ϕ) W L (C, L; ϕ, µ, λ) Consumer inter-temporal optimality in equilibrium implies U m C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ) = β W C (C, L; ϕ, µ, λ) UC m (C, L; ϕ) s t+1 s t U m C (C(s t+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ)r(s t+1 )Pr(s t+1 ) 24

One way to get this is to set the capital income taxes such that R(s t+1 ) = R (s t+1 UC m ) (C(st ), L(s t ); ϕ) W C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) Note that FOC with respect to initial capital implies N µ i k0π i i = 0 i=1 Example: Consider the following preferences U i (c, y) = c1 σ 1 σ ) γ α(y/θi γ Note that we have h i c(c, L; ϕ) = ω i cc and h i y(c, L; ϕ) = ω i yl, with and therefore U m = Φ m u ω i c = (ϕ i ) 1/σ i π i (ϕ i ) 1/σ and ωi y = c 1 σ 1 σ Φm v α (y/θi ) γ γ W C (C(s t+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ, µ, λ) U m C (C(st+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ) (θ i ) γ γ 1 (ϕ i ) 1 γ 1 i π i (θ i ) γ γ 1 (ϕi ) 1 γ 1 and W = Φ W u c 1 σ 1 σ ΦW v α (y/θi ) γ γ in which Φ m u, Φ m v, Φ W u and Φ W v are some constant. Note that this implies Note also that τ (C, L) = 1 Φm v Φ m u Φ W u Φ W v UC m(c(st ), L(s t ); ϕ) W C (C(s t+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ, µ, λ) W C (C(s t ), L(s t ); ϕ, µ, λ) UC m(c(st+1 ), L(s t+1 ); ϕ) = 1 and therefore which implies R(s t+1 ) = R (s t+1 ) κ(s t ) = 0 for all t 1 This implies that the result for optimal taxes on capital income holds from date zero (not just for t 1 as it was the case before). When k i 0 = k 0 for all i, taxing initial capital is 25

like a lump-sum tax. But since lump-tax is allowed here, it is not necessary. However, when individuals are heterogeneous in their initial wealth, then taxing wealth for redistribution is desirable. Example: Now consider the following preferences U i (c, y) = α log(c) + (1 α) log(1 y θ i ) then h i c(c, L; ϕ) = ω i C and h i y(c, L; ϕ) = θ i ω i (1 L) and therefore, ω i = ϕ i i πi ϕ i U m (C, L; φ) = α log(c) + (1 α) log(1 L) + i [ α log ( ω i ) + (1 α) log ( ω i /θ i)]. Also we can we can verify that W (C, L) = Φ W U (α log(c) + (1 α) log(1 L)) + Φ W U L (1 α) 1 L and therefore also τ (L) = 1 (1 L)Φ W U /ΦW U L + 1 κ(s t ) = 0 for all t 1 2.3 Taxing Capital in Life Cycle Economies (Erosa and Gervais (2002)) Here, I present a 2 period version of Erosa and Gervais (2002). Individuals live 2 periods (born at age 0, die at age 1). Each generation is indexed by its date of birth. For example in period t, the generations alive are t 1, t. Assume no population growth. Each individual is endowed with one unit of time at each age j and can transform one unit of time into z j unit of efficient labor. Let c t,j be the consumption of generation t at age j. Other variables follow the same notation. 26

Consumer s problem is the following (for generation t > 0) max U(c t,0, l t,0 ) + βu(c t,1, l t,1 ) (1 τ c t,0)c t,0 + a t,1 (1 τ l t,0)w t z 0 l t,0 (1 τ c t,1)c t,1 (1 τ l t,1)w t z 1 l t,1 + (1 + (1 τ k t,1)(r t δ))a t,1 There is a constant return to scale technology and r t = f k (k t, l t ) w t = f l (k t, l t ) and feasibility requires that c t + k t+1 = f(k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t c t = c t,0 + c t 1,1 l t = l t,0 + l t 1,1 k t = a t 1,1 Government budget constrain is [ p t g t = p t τt j,jc c t j,j + ] τt j,jw l t z j l t j,j + τt 1,1(r k t δ)a t 1,1 j=0,1 j=0,1 Let U t = U(c t,0, l t,0 ) + βu(c t,1, l t,1 ) be the lifetime utility of generation t for a given sequence of consumption and leisure and let 0 < γ < 1 be government s discount factor across generations. Government objective is to maximize γ t U t Exercise: Show that, in this environment, implementability constraint for generation t is the following U ct,0 c t,0 + U lt,0 l t,0 + β ( U ct,1 c t,1 + U lt,1 l t,1 ) = 0 (38) 27

Exercise: Show that a feasible allocation is implementable if and only if it satisfy (38). Ramsey problem Ramsey problem is the following max γ t [U(c t,0, l t,0 ) + βu(c t,1, l t,1 )] U ct,0 c t,0 + U lt,0 l t,0 + β ( U ct,1 c t,1 + U lt,1 l t,1 ) = 0 ; γ t λ t c t + k t+1 = f(k t, l t ) + (1 δ)k t ; γ t φ t c t = c t,0 + c t 1,1 l t = l t,0 + l t 1,1 k t = a t 1,1 First order conditions are γ t U ct,0 + γ t λ t ( Uct,0 + U cct,0 c t,0 + U lct,0 l t,0 ) = γ t φ t (39) γ t βu ct,1 + γ t βλ t ( Uct,1 + U cct,1 c t,1 + U lct,1 l t,1 ) = γ t+1 φ t+1 γ t U lt,0 + γ t λ t ( Ult,0 + U llt,0 l t,0 + U lct,0 c t,0 ) = γ t φ t f lt (40) γ t βu lt,0 + γ t βλ t ( Ult,1 + U llt,1 l t,1 + U clt,1 c t,1 ) = γ t+1 φ t+1 f lt+1 γ t φ t = γ t+1 φ t+1 (1 δ + f kt+1 ) (41) Combine (39) and (41) ( ) U ct,0 + λ t Uct,0 + U cct,0 c t,0 + U lct,0 l t,0 ( ) = β (1 δ + f kt+1 ) (42) U ct,1 + λ t Uct,1 + U cct,1 c t,1 + U lct,1 l t,1 Steady State: In the steady state (c t,0, c t,1, l t,0, l t,1, a t,1 ) = (c 0, c 1, l 0, l 1, a 1 ) and λ t = λ. Therefore, 28

U c0 + λ (U c0 + U cc0 c 0 + U lc0 l 0 ) βu c1 + λ (U c1 + U cc1 c 1 + U lc1 l 1 ) = β (1 δ + f kt+1) Note that this in general does not imply zero tax on capital. When profile of labor productivity, z j, is not flat over lifetime, in general consumption and leisure allocations over lifetime is not flat. Question: Intuitively, why is it optimal to distort inter-temporal decision in this environment? We can impose assumptions on preferences (both for government and individuals) to arrive at zero capital taxation result again. Proposition 8 Suppose period utility function is of the following form u(c, l) = c1 σ 1 σ v(l) Then the Ramsey problem prescribes no inter-temporal distortions for periods t 1, provided that labor income taxes can be age-dependent. Proof. Note that equation (42) becomes Individual problems Euler equation is U c0,t U c1,t = β (1 δ + f kt+1 ) U c0,t U c1,t = β (1 + (1 τ t,1 )(f kt+1 δ)) This result should be viewed as a consequence of uniform commodity taxation. Question: Note that we get this result independent of γ. Isn t that surprising? Why is that? 29

References Chamley, C. (1986): Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives, Econometrica, 54, 607 22. 2 Chari, V.V., C. L. and P. Kehoe (1994): Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model, Journal of Political Economy, 102, 617 52. 2 Chari, V. and P. J. Kehoe (1998): Optimal fiscal and monetary policy, Minneapolis Fed Staff Report, SR 251. 2 Corlett, W. and D. Hauge (1953-54): Complementarity and the excess burden of taxation, Review of Economic Studies, 21, 21 30. 1.2.3 Diamond, P. and J. Mirrlees (1971): Optimal taxation and public production I: production efficiency, American Economic Review, 61, 8 27. 1.4 Ekeland, I. and J. A. Scheinkman (1986): Transversality Conditions for some infinite horizon discrete time optimization problems, Mathematics of operation research, 11. 2 Erosa, A. and M. Gervais (2002): Optimal Taxation in Life-Cycle Economies, Journal of Economic Theory, 105, 338 369. 2.3 Judd, K. L. (1985): Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model, Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59 83. 2 McGrattan, E. R. and E. C. Prescott (2005): Taxes, Regulations, and the Value of U.S. and U.K. Corporations, Review of Economic Studies, 72, 767 796. 2.2.1 Sandmo, A. (1987): A Reinterpretation of Elasticity Formulae in Optimum Tax Theory, Economica, 54, 89 96. 1.2.3 Weitzman, M. L. (1973): Duality Theory of Convex Programming for Infinite Horizon Economic Models, Management Science, 19. 2 Werning, I. (2007): Tax Smoothing with Redistribution, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 925 67. 2.2.3, 2.2.3 30