Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1"

Transcription

1 Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1 Ching-to Albert Ma Department of Economics Boston University 270 Bay State Road Boston, MA ma@bu.edu Michael H. Riordan Graduate School of Business Columbia University 3022 Broadway, 608 Uris Hall New York, NY mhr21@columbia.edu June 1997; April The authors acknowledge helpful comments from the editor, two referees, David Bradford, David Dranove, Thomas McGuire, and seminar participants at Columbia, Harvard and Yale Universities, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Universitat Pompeu Fabra (Barcelona), Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona, and Universities of New Hampshire, North Carolina and Toulouse.

2 Abstract If an illness is not contractible, then even partially insured consumers demand treatment for it when the bene t is less than the cost, a condition known as moral hazard. Traditional health insurance, which controls moral hazard with copayments (demand-management), can result in either a de - cient or an excessive provision of treatment relative to ideal insurance. In particular, treatment for a low probability illness is de cient if illness per se has little e ect on the consumer s marginal utility of income and if the consumer s price elasticity of expected demand for treatment is large relative to the risk-spreading distortion when these are evaluated at a copayment that brings forth the ideal provision of treatment. Managed care, which controls moral hazard with physician incentives, can either increase or decrease treatment delivery relative to traditional insurance, depending on whether demand management results in de cient or excessive treatment. JEL Classi cation Numbers: I10 B80 Keywords: Insurance, Moral Hazard, Health Care, Managed Care

3 Before the proliferation of managed care, health insurance contracts relied heavily on deductibles, copayments, and other coverage limitations to control the provision of care. These demand management instruments cause consumers to limit their demand for health care, and thereby reduce premiums by restraining health care costs, but may expose consumers to large uninsured risks. In contrast, managed care plans give health care providers explicit nancial incentives, such as prospective payments, capitations, and cost sharing contracts, to limit expensive treatments. Clearly, these supply management instruments have become more important. Economic theory interprets the emergence of institutions as a response to market failures. In the health industry, market failure stems from the di culty of contracting on illness ex ante. 1 Due to this failure, ideal insurance, which shields consumers from the costs of e ciently-provided treatment, is infeasible. Second-best insurance pays only part of treatment expenses or limits coverage in other ways. But patients who do not fully face the cost of medical care may demand treatment ine ciently, in the sense that the cost of treatment sometimes exceeds the bene t. This problem is known as moral hazard. Demand and supply management policies in health care attempt to control moral hazard while partly insuring consumers against the risks of illness. 2 In the 1960 s, the health economics literature adopted the term moral hazard to describe the di culty of contracting over health status (Arrow, 1963, 1968; Pauly, 1968; Zeckhauser,1970), and argued that demand management at best only partly cures the moral hazard problem. The very rst lines of Zeckhauser s 1970 article crystallize what is now the conventional wisdom : Theprimarypurposeofmedicalinsuranceistospreadarisk,theriskofincurringsubstantial medical expenses. With risk-spreading, individuals will not pay the full amounts of such expenses. Insurance provision will thus introduce a perverse incentive toward overexpenditure if, as is usually the case, (1) the insured has substantial in uence over the amount that is spent on their own behalf in any particular medical circumstance, and (2) the level of reimbursement by the insurance plan is a positively associated function of the expenses incurred by its insured. Given that demand management does not solve the moral hazard problem, it is plausible to 1 See Grossman and Hart (1986) on the di culties of contracting on complex events. 2 The health economics literature has recognized that demand and supply management policies are complementary responses to market failure in the health industry. Ellis and McGuire (1993) emphasize the potential importance of nancial incentives on consumers as well as on providers. Ma and McGuire (1997) use this basic premise to investigate the interaction between optimal insurance and provider payment. Newhouse (1996) in a recent survey urges more study of supply side incentives. 1

4 interpret supply management (managed care) as an additional attempt to do so. On this interpretation, Zeckhauser s statement of the conventional wisdom suggests that moral hazard under demand management alone results in an excessive provision of treatment, and that managed care reduces this excess. We demonstrate that this is not necessarily so. Under some conditions, optimal demand management results in de cient treatment and managed care corrects this de ciency, leading to more treatment. We construct a model of insurance for a particular treatment, and characterize conditions under which optimal demand management under moral hazard results in an excessive or de cient provision of treatment. By excessive (de cient), we mean that a higher (lower) fraction of individuals receive the treatment compared to the ideal benchmark in the absence of moral hazard. We extend the model to allow supply management (managed care), and prove that this relaxes the moral hazard constraint and, under certain conditions, achieves ideal insurance. In this case, the introduction of managed care increases (decreases) the provision of treatment if treatment under optimal demand management is de cient (excessive), thus alleviating the market failure due to moral hazard. The provision of treatment can be de cient under optimal demand management if the illness per se has little e ect on the consumer s marginal utility of income. This possibility depends on the income e ect of the copayment: the patient s marginal utility of income is higher if the copayment is higher. 3 The intuition is roughly as follows. There are two important con icting e ects on consumer welfare of limiting treatment by charging a copayment higher than the one that elicits the ideal ( rst-best) provision. First, the consumer su ers directly more income risk, as indicated by a higher marginal utility of income after paying for treatment. Ceteris paribus, the cost to the consumer of this departure from optimal risk-spreading is greater, the greater is the income e ect of the copayment. Second, the consumer enjoys a lower premium because the insurance company has a lower expected cost. This second e ect is more pronounced the greater is the income e ect of the copayment relative to the marginal utility of income when an ill consumer declines treatment, because the consumer s demand response to the increased copayment is greater and translates into a larger premium reduction. Thus the premium reduction e ect is magni ed if illness per se does not very much increase the marginal utility of income. The optimal provision of treatment under 3 The health economics literature has paid little attention to the importance of income e ects on the demand for treatment. In fact, a standard text in health economics only brie y mentions income e ects (Phelps (1992), pp. 32, 301). There are some notable exceptions. De Meza (1983) considers intertemporal income e ects of savings and insurance, but assumes that illness severity is contractible so that optimal insurance involves an indemnity payment when the consumer is sick. Marshall (1976) also allows income e ects, focusing on how the optimal insurance gives the consumer an incentive to exercise care to reduce the likelihood of illness. 2

5 demand management is less than the ideal amount if the price elasticity of demand for treatment (and hence the premium reduction e ect) is large relative to the risk-spreading distortion. While our main results are developed for the case of an infrequent illness, for which these clearly are the most important e ects, we also show that the possibility of de cient treatment does not depend crucially on a small illness probability. The rest of the article is organized as follows. The next section lays out a model of illness, treatment, and insurance. Section 2 studies the rst best, when the treatment decision is fully contractible, and Section 3 characterizes the second best, when the provision of treatment is controlled indirectly by demand management. Section 4 compares the two, and establishes conditions under which the second-best provision of treatment with optimal demand management is more or less than the rst-best with ideal insurance. Section 5 employs these results as benchmarks to study supply management (managed care). Section 6 concludes by summarizing, and describing possible future research. An appendix contains the formal proofs of propositions. 1 The Basic Model We focus on optimal health insurance for a particular discrete treatment. 4 Implicitly, we hold xed other health and disability insurance covering the consumer and study insurance for this particular treatment in isolation. To be concrete and to focus our discussion, we interpret the treatment as being suitable for a speci c diagnosis. 5 For example, the treatment might be a new class of prescription drugs for high cholesterol (statins) described in a recent Wall Street Journal article. 6 We assume that a consumer becomes ill with probability, 0 < <1. For example, is the probability that a consumer is diagnosed as having a high cholesterol condition and is potentially a candidate for statins. Many of our results focus on the case where is small, which of course is often realistic. For example, according to the aforementioned Wall Street Journal article, 13 million 4 This contrasts with a more familiar reduced form approach in the health care literature, which assumes that a consumer s health is a function of undi erentiated health care expenditures. See, for example, Baumgardner (1991). Our discrete choice approach perhaps provides a more useful conceptual basis for empirical analyses of micro data which indicate whether a patient received a particular treatment or not. See, for example, Manning and Phelps (1979). Of course, it will be important in future theoretical work to study the bundled coverage of the panoply of treatments typical of health insurance policies. 5 More generally, the treatment in question might be suitable for a variety of diagnoses. For example, the treatment might be an extra day in the hospital due to complications from a surgical procedure. Our model is consistent with this broader interpretation. 6 See Price Prescription: Powerful Medications for Cholesterol Pose a Paradox for HMO s by Ron Winslow, Wall Street Journal, December 6, 1996, page A1. 3

6 people with serious heart problems are candidates for statins. While this is a lot of people, the probability that one of us will become a candidate for statins in the next year is hopefully quite small. It is easy to think of many other expensive treatments and tests that may be bene cial to an individual consumer with a small probability (organ transplants, neural surgeries, etc.). Our model focuses on health insurance coverage for one of these treatments in isolation. For simplicity, we assume that the cost of diagnosing the illness is zero. 7 Illness varies by its severity, which is described by a random variable ` with a cumulative distribution function F (`), and a density function f(`); with support on the positive real line. 8 As we make clear below, the severity of illness ` indexes the bene ts of treatment, and F (`) describes the distribution of bene ts across the population of patients. The consumer learns the bene ts of treatment (presumably in consultation with a physician) only after becoming ill. We assume that illness is not contractible, 9 and the insurance company can contract neither on the event of illness nor the realization of `. We adopt an eclectic approach to modeling the consequences of an untreated illness. Speci cally, consumers preferences are represented by a utility function of the form U(y a`) b`. Thevariabley represents the consumer s expenditure on other goods. The function U( ) is di erentiable, increasing and strictly concave, re ecting the consumer s risk-aversion to income uctuations, and a and b are non-negative parameters. Nested in this functional form are two special cases of interest. If b =0and a>0, then illness is completely equivalent to a loss of monetary income; we call this the monetary loss model. In this case, we sometimes set a =1as a normalization, measuring the loss of health resulting from illness in monetary units. The second special case is the utility loss model with a =0and b>0. Here, illness a ects an additive utility loss and does not directly e ect the consumer s marginal utility of income; we sometimes also use the normalization b =1, interpreting ` as an expected utility loss from forgoing treatment. This broad interpretation implicitly recognizes the uncertainties surrounding illness and alternative treatments. The general formulation allows for mixtures of monetary losses and (additive) utility losses from illness. The utility loss model seems more plausible than the monetary loss model even though both are special cases. The monetary loss model implies that the demand for treatment does not de- 7 A xed and known diagnostic cost will not change our qualitative results, as long as the outcome of the diagnosis is not contractible. 8 The random probability of illness e ectively puts a mass point at ` =0. It is easy to extend the model to allow for bounded severity, and also for a strictly positive lower bound of the support to be strictly positive, as for a Pareto distribution (Ma and Riordan, 1997). 9 If the event of illness were contractible, the optimal insurance contract could involve a monetary transfer payment to patients who become ill. The case is perhaps better understood as disability insurance. 4

7 pend on income. This seems unrealistic for many discretionary treatments. Manning and Phelps (1979) found signi cant income e ects for speci c dental treatments. The RAND Health Insurance Study generally found small but positive income elasticities, while subsequent studies using di erent methods and data found larger elasticities (Phelps 1992). In contrast, the utility loss model implies a positive income elasticity of the demand for treatment without restricting its magnitude. The utility loss model does imply that a consumer s attitude toward income risk is independent of illness per se. Obviously, this is an empirical question, but seems extremely di cult to answer. We have no apriorireason to think that the e ect of illness on risk aversion goes one way or another. Therefore, it seems reasonable, at least as a rst step, to ignore this e ect. For these reasons, we are partial to the utility loss model. We make several simplifying assumptions about treatment. First, the cost of treatment is xed at C>0. It will be useful to think of C as a large number, creating a signi cant demand for insurance, but not prohibitively large. 10 For example, the Wall Street Journal article says that statin therapy costs $700 a year for life. While this is an expensive therapy, some consumers bene ts obviously are much higher than $700 a year. Second, if the patient receives treatment, then the losses from illness are eliminated completely. 11 Thus, ` indexes the bene ts from receiving treatment. These bene ts vary across patients, implying that some patients are better candidates for treatment than others. 12 Third, we model the treatment decision as a binary choice. Either the patient receives treatment or not. 13 Consequently, for a xed copayment, there is a critical value of ` such that more severely ill patients demand treatment while less severely ill patients do not, as we show later. Finally, the delivery of treatment is contractible, meaning that the insurance company can prevent fraudulent claims for the reimbursement of non-existent treatment costs. 10 Obviously, this treatment cost cannot be too large. Otherwise, there would be little demand for insurance in our model. If C is su ciently small, then there is a demand for insurance to smooth the income uctuation resulting from illness and treatment. Interestingly, in the monetary loss model, the uctuation to be smoothed is the monetary equivalent of illness itself. In the utility loss model, the uctuation to be smoothed is the cost of treatment. 11 As mentioned above, we do not need to assume this in the utility loss model. In this special case, ` is the bene t of possibly imperfect treatment. 12 We emphasize that our interpretation of ` is the treatment s potential bene t to patients. One could interpret alternatively that ` refers to patients losses, although we do not think that this is always true. For some illnesses, it may be more natural to allow for multiple treatments when severity varies. See Chernew, Encinosa and Hirth, (2000). 13 A more general, mechanism design approach to optimal insurance would allow the insurance company to randomize the provision of treatment. We ignore this possibility because it is unrealistic. 5

8 2 Ideal insurance We begin by studying the ideal insurance contract in the absence of moral hazard. In this regime, illness and loss are assumed to be completely contractible; payments and treatment decisions can be contingent on the severity of illness. Under an ideal contract, the consumer pays a xed premium P, and receives treatment whenever the bene ts of treatment ` is above a xed threshold L. Moreover, when treatment is withheld, the consumer can be compensated by an indemnity payment, t(`), that depends on the severity of illness. In principle, the consumer receiving treatment can also receive a transfer payment. This possibility, however, plays no role in our model because treatment eliminates all illness losses. Therefore, under an ideal contract a consumer with income Y enjoys an expected utility given by the formula: ( Z ) L (1 )U(Y P )+ [U(Y P a` + t(`)) b`]f(`)d` +[1 F (L)]U(Y P ) : (1) 0 This expected utility formula is a weighted sum of two components. The rst component is the utility of a healthy consumer who has paid the insurance premium. 14 The second component (in curly brackets) is the conditional expected utility of an ill consumer, who receives treatment when the bene t is su ciently great, but otherwise is compensated only by the indemnity payment. The weights are the respective probabilities of illness and health. The insurance premium must cover the expected costs of treatment and indemnity payments. Thus, the premium constraint for the ideal contract is given by the inequality: " Z # L P t(`)f(`)d` +(1 F (L))C : (2) 0 The ideal contract maximizes expected utility subject to the premium constraint; it is the solution (P ;t (`);L ) to the problem of maximizing (1) subject to (2). The premium constraint is necessarily binding at an optimum. Proposition 1 The ideal insurance contract speci es (a) a treatment threshold that equates the marginal bene ts of treatment to the marginal cost, i.e. U 0 (Y P )al + bl = U 0 (Y P )C; (3) (b) indemnity payments that exactly compensate for the monetary losses from an untreated illness, i.e. t (`) =a`, and (c) a premium that exactly covers the expected costs. Finally, fewer patients receive treatment if the cost of treatment is higher, i.e. L is strictly increasing in C. 14 The variable Y can be interpreted as income net of premiums paid for other health insurance. Thus Y P is net income after the premium insuring for this particular treatment. 6

9 The characterization of the optimal treatment threshold needs a bit more interpretation. The marginal cost of treatment C is in monetary units. To measure the value of the cost of treatment C in utility units, it is multiplied by the marginal utility of income U 0 (Y P ). Equation (3) says that the utility of treatment evaluated at the threshold level of illness, [U 0 (Y P )a + b]l,equals the cost of treatment measured in utility, U 0 (Y P )C. In the monetary loss model (a =1;b=0), equation (3) states that treatment will be provided whenever the monetary loss from an untreated illness exceeds the monetary cost of treatment (` C). In the utility loss model (a =0;b=1), the treatment threshold is set equal to the cost of an untreated illness (L = U 0 (Y P )C), andthere is no indemnity payment for an untreated illness (t (`) =0). 3 Demand Management We now turn to optimal insurance when illness and loss are not contractible. The insurance company contracts with the consumer to reimburse part or all of the cost of treatment, but does not directly observe illness. The treatment decision itself is delegated to the patient, presumably in consultation with a physician. 15 We refer to this scheme of insurance as demand management. Under a demand-managed insurance contract, the patient pays a xed premium P up front, and copays D for treatment. Given this contract, the patient demands treatment when the bene ts exceed the utility cost of the copayment. Thus treatment is provided when the severity of illness exeeds a threshold value L satisfying the treatment constraint : U(Y P al) bl = U(Y P D): (4) This constraint states that a patient with illness severity L is indi erent about receiving treatment, and implicitly de nes L as a function of D and P. This function determines the expected demand for treatment by consumers who fall ill, which is equal to [1 F (L)]. As with ideal insurance, the premium must cover the expected cost of the insurance company. Since treatment is provided only when illness severity exceeds L,theex ante probability of treatment is [1 F (L)], and the insurance company breaks even if the premium covers its expected liability: 16 P = (1 F (L))(C D): (5) 15 Implicitly, we assume that the physician is a perfect agent for consumers. At the end of this section, we brie y discuss competition between self-interested physicians. In Section 5, we examine physician incentives under managed care. 16 The premium constraint, P (1 F (L))(C D), must be binding for an optimal insurance contract, because expected utility, given by (7) below, is decreasing in the premium. 7

10 The breakeven constraint de nes a tradeo between the premium and the copayment: 17 ½ dd = [1 F (L)] + f(l)(c ¾ dp dd The rst term in this expression is the direct e ect of shifting more cost to the patient, while the second is the marginal demand reduction from a higher copayment. Solving for the total e ect reveals that a higher copayment translates into a lower premium: 18 dp dd = [1 F (L)][aU 0 (Y P al)+b]+ f(l)(c D)U 0 (Y P D) [au 0 (Y P al)+b] f(l)(c D)[U 0 (Y P D) U 0 < 0: (6) (Y P al)] Consumer expected utility is a probability weighted average of utility when healthy and ill: ( Z ) L (1 )U(Y P )+ [U(Y P a`) b`]f(`)d` +[1 F (L)]U(Y P D) : (7) 0 The event of illness occasions two possible losses. First, a consumer su ers monetary (a >0) and additive utility (b > 0) losses from an untreated illness (when ` L). Second, the copayment reduces the disposable income of a patient receiving treatment (when ` L). Optimal demand-management sets a premium and copayment to maximize expected utility, given that consumers determine treatment and the insurance company breaks even. Thus, the optimal contract (P d ;D d ;L d ) maximizes (7) subject to (4) and (5). We call this the demand management problem. A rst result, traced to Zeckhauser (1970), is that consumers are only partially insured for the cost of treatment. The consumer faces some risk of untreated illness, and copays less than the full cost of treatment. The solution balances the negative consumer welfare e ect of a higher copayment against the positive e ect of a lower premium. Proposition 2 Optimal demand management partially insures consumers against the cost of treatment (0 <D d <C), and less severely ill patients decline treatment (L d > 0): The optimal copayment balances the expected utility cost of a marginally higher copayment against the corresponding bene ts of a lower premium, i.e. ( Z ) L dp (1 )U 0 (Y P )+ U 0 (Y P a`)f(`)d` + [1 F (L)]U 0 (Y P D) (8) dd where dp=dd is given by (6). 17 >From the = For a small illness probability, the e 0 = [1 F (L)]U 0 (Y P D) U 0 (Y P D) au 0 (Y P al)+b dp > 0 = U0 (Y P D) U 0 (Y P al) au 0 (Y P al)+b > 0. is of second-order importance. 18 dp=dd < 0 follows from the fact that the treatment constraint implies D al. 8

11 The proposition reveals two marginal e ects on consumer welfare of raising the copayment: a direct e ect of more income risk, and a premium reduction e ect. At an optimum, there is no need to weigh the marginal e ects on the demand for treatment, because these are of second-order importance. 19 The optimal copayment depends on the consumer s risk aversion and on the price elasticity of the expected demand for treatment, both of which depend on the curvature of the utility function. The well-known Arrow-Borch condition for optimal risk-spreading requires that marginal utilities of income are equal in all states of illness and health. However, a copayment will create a distortion from optimal risk-spreading across the states in which the consumer is healthy and the states in which the consumer is treated for illness. The magnitude of the Arrow-Borch distortion for a h i given copayment, U 0 (Y P D) U 0 (Y P ) 1, depends only on the curvature of the utility function on the domain between Y D and Y. The consumer s elasticity of expected demand for treatment with respect to the copayment (holding the premium constant), 20 f f(l) DU 0 (Y D) [1 F (L)] [au 0 (Y al)+b] g, also depends on the curvature of the utility function, as well as on the losses from untreated illness and on the severity distribution. These two magnitudes, the Arrow-Borch distortion and the price elasticity of demand, are prominent in determining the optimal cost-sharing ratio ( C D D ) when the probability of illness is small. Corollary 1 If the probability of illness is small, then the optimal ratio of cost shares for the insurance company and the patient is approximately equal to the ratio of the Arrow-Borch distortion and the price elasticity of demand for treatment, i.e. ( f(l d ) D d U 0 (Y D d )" # " ) C D d U 0 (Y D d # ) [1 F (L d )] [au 0 (Y al d )+b] D d = U 0 1 (9) (Y ) in the limit as! Taking the total derivative of (7) with respect to(d; P; L) yields ( Z ) L (1 )U 0 (Y P )+ U 0 (Y P a`)f(`)d` + [1 F (L)]U 0 (Y P D) dp 0 [1 F (L)]U 0 (Y P D)dD + [U(Y P al) bl U(Y P D)]f(L)dL: The treatment constraint (4) implies that the last term vanishes, leaving the two e ects identi ed in the proposition. 20 To derive this elasticity, di erentiate [1 F (L)] with respect to D, using (4) and the chain rule, and apply the de nition of elasticity. 21 The corollary is proved by substituting (6) into the rst-order condition in Proposition 2, dividing through by ; and taking the limit as! 0. In the limit, the premium is zero because the consumer never 9

12 The corollary illustrates neatly the con ict between providing insurance and controlling moral hazard. On the one hand, if the consumer is highly averse to income risk (a large Arrow-Borch distortion), then the insurance company should bear a high fraction of the treatment cost in order to better insure the patient. On the other hand, if the demand for treatment is sensitive to price (a high price elasticity of demand), then the consumer should face a substantial treatment expense in order to curtail an excessive demand. Optimal cost sharing balances these two concerns. We close this section on a technical note. The demand management problem is not in general a concave programming problem. Therefore, the rst-order condition for an optimal contract in Proposition 2 is not necessarily su cient, nor is the solution necessarily well-behaved. The following corollary provides an assumption under which this is not an issue. 22 Corollary 2 Assume that the following function is strictly increasing in D: ½ ¾ 1 D + U 0 (Y ) 1 U 0 [au 0 (Y al)+b] 1 F (L) ; (Y D) f(l) with L determined by the treatment constraint and P =0(the hazard rate assumption ). For su ciently small, the optimal threshold L d and copayment D d are unique, di erentiable and increasing in the treatment cost C. The hazard rate assumption requires that the inverse hazard rate, H(L) [1 F (L)]=f(L); does not decline too quickly. It is satis ed, for example, if H(L) is constant (exponential distribution) or increasing (e.g. Pareto distribution). becomes ill (P d =0). However, the premium is positive in the neighborhood of the limit. In general, the consequences of a change in the premium on expected consumer welfare are multifaceted, partly because the marginal utility of income varies across the di erent states of illness and health. However, some the premium e ects of a small variation of the insurance contract are more important than others, i.e. some are proportional to ( rst-order importance) while others are proportional to 2 (second-order importance). The small approximation focuses on the rst-order e ects. The second-order e ects that the approximation ignores can be described as follows: any change in the premium (P ) a ects consumer welfare di erently across the di erent states of illness and health because of the income e ects of the copayment (D) and untreated illness (al). Because the rst-order e ects are roughly proportional to and the second-order e ects are roughly proportional to 2, there is no particular reason to think that the second-order e ects dominate for plausible values of. 22 See Proposition 4 in Ma and Riordan (2000) for a formal proof. The assumption is not necessary for the result of the corollary. It is su cient that the demand management problem has a unique continuous global maximum. 10

13 4 Does Moral Hazard Increase Treatment? We now turn to our main question. How does moral hazard in uence treatment? Is the delivery of treatment under demand management more or less than that under the ideal contract? We make two points in this section. First, the provision of treatment can be either de cient (L d >L ) or excessive. Second, de cient treatment is a robust possibility, and occurs under various plausible conditions. We focus on the case of a small probability of illness. It is convenient to reformulate the demand management problem slightly. The treatment constraint (4) and the binding premium constraint (5) implicitly de ne the premium P and copayment D as functions of treatment threshold L. Solving for P and D as functions of L, and substituting these into the expression for consumer welfare (7) yields an expression for consumer welfare as a function of L alone, which we denote Z(L). Optimal demand management determines a treatment threshold that maximizes Z(L). Under the hazard rate assumption (of Corollary 2), Z(L) is a quasi-concave function and therefore achieves a unique local maximum at L d. We ask whether the derivative Z 0 (L ) is positive or negative. If Z(L) is quasi-concave and Z 0 (L ) > 0, thentreatment is provided de ciently under demand management (L d >L ), and conversely. Proposition 3 Under the hazard rate assumption, if the probability of illness is small, then treatment under optimal demand management is de cient if the cost-share ratio exceeds the ratio of the Arrow-Borch distortion to the price elasticity of demand, evaluated at the copayment for which the consumer demands treatment if and only if the illness severity (`) exceeds the ideal treatment threshold (L ), i.e. as! 0, L <L d if and only if ½ f(l ) D U 0 (Y D ) ¾ C D U0 (Y D ) [1 F (L )] [au 0 (Y al )+b] D > U 0 1 : (10) (Y ) where D satis es the treatment constraint (4) evaluated at P =0and L = L. The converse also holds. In the monetary loss model (b =0), the demand price for L is equal to the cost of treatment, i.e. D = C. In this case, inequality (10) obviously fails and we conclude that more treatment is provided under demand management than under the ideal contract. In this special case, an uninsured consumer seeks treatment e ciently, (i.e. only when the monetary bene t exceeds the cost a` > C) but this cannot be optimal. A risk averse consumer will always demand some insurance, resulting in an excessive provision of treatment; starting from D = C, the consumer is willing to pay a higher premium to achieve a lower copayment, which increases the demand for 11

14 treatment. 23 Corollary 3 In the monetary loss model (b =0), treatment is excessive under demand management (L d <L ). For the utility loss model (a =0), (3) implies that b = U 0 (Y )C=L as tends to 0, because the premium is proportional to. In this limiting case, inequality (10) is equivalent to C D C U 0 (Y D ) U 0 (Y D ) U 0 (Y ) > 1 F (L ) L f(l ) (11) with D satisfying U(Y ) U(Y D )=CU 0 (Y ). Substituting for C by the de nition of D,we can simplify (11) to U 1 0 (Y ) U(Y ) U(Y D ) D 1 U > 1 F (L ) 0 (Y ) L f(l ) ; U 0 (Y D ) whose left-hand side lies between 0 and 1 because U 0 (Y D )D >U(Y ) U(Y D ). The elasticity of demand with respect to the disutility ` is `f(`)=[1 F (`)]; we refer to this as the loss elasticity of demand. If demand is inelastic with respect to the utility loss, then the right-hand side of (11) is greater than 1, in which case (10) is violated and treatment is excessive. The other side of the coin is that moral hazard causes de cient treatment if the loss elasticity is su ciently large. Corollary 4 In the utility loss model (a =0and b =1), under the hazard rate assumption, if the illness probability is small, and demand is inelastic with respect to the additive utility loss evaluated at the ideal threshold ( L f(l ) 1 F (L ) < 1), then treatment is excessive under demand management (Ld < L ); if the loss elasticity is su ciently large, then treatment is de cient: The corollary can also be interpreted to say that treatment is de cient in the additive loss model if and only if the price elasticity of demand is su ciently high. The ordinary price elasticity of demand in the utility loss model ( L f(l ) [1 F (L )] D U 0 (Y D ) CU 0 (Y ) ) is proportional to the loss elasticity. Therefore, holding the utility function constant, an increase in the loss elasticity (which depends only on F ) translates directly into an increase in the price elasticity of demand. 23 The higher premium has a much smaller e ect on the demand for treatment because of the low probability of illness. Actually though, the following corollary does not require a small illness probability. For the monetary loss model, treatment is always excessive relative to the rst best. That is, the conditions in Proposition 3 are unnecessary. See Ma and Riordan (1997). 12

15 An interesting special case of the utility loss model occurs when the utility of income function exhibits constant absolute risk aversion, i.e. U(y) = exp( ry), where r>0 is the coe cient of absolute risk aversion. In this case, D =ln(1+rc), and (11) is equivalent to µ rc ln(1 + rc) 1+rC > 1 F (L ) rc rc L f( : (12) ) The right-hand side of (12) is the elasticity of demand with respect to the disutility of illness, evaluated at L. The left-hand side is an increasing, concave function of rc, ranging from 0:5 as r! 0 to 1:0 as r!1. Thus, holding the right-hand side constant, 24 we conclude from this special case that treatment is de cient if the consumer is su ciently risk averse and the loss elasticity is su ciently small. The intuitive explanation for this result is subtle. A higher degree of risk aversion clearly increases the magnitude of the Arrow-Borch distortion when D is raised above D to curtail treatment. However, a higher degree of risk aversion also corresponds to a greater income e ect of D on the demand for treatment. Thus, if r is higher, then a given increase in D curtails treatment more, resulting in a greater reduction in the premium. The latter e ect dominates, making the increase in D attractive to the consumer from an ex ante perspective. The above example and corollaries clearly demonstrate that de cient treatment is a robust possibility. This robustness argument can also be made in a more general way. Toward this end, for a given L, normalize the parameters a and b so that a C b = U 0 (Y ) L : (13) Thus the treatment threshold under the ideal contract is held constant as the parameters a and b vary according to this constraint. The inequality (10) can be expressed alternatively as C D n o 1 U 0 (Y ) > 1 F (L ) 1 f(l [au 0 (Y al )+U 0 (Y )f C ag]: (14) ) L U 0 (Y D ) The normalization (13) keeps L constant at the limit as tends to zero. An increase in a increases theright-handsideof(14)becauseu 0 (Y al ) >U 0 (Y ). Moreover, since P tends to zero with, the treatment constraint implies that D increases with a for the same reason. Therefore, the left-hand side of (10) decreases as the value of a increases, and (14) is more likely to hold when a is smaller. Now, xing values for C, U(Y ), U 0 (Y ), andd, we can make the left-hand side of (11) arbitrarily large by choosing a utility function with enough curvature on the interval [Y;Y D ] Note that L can be held constant as rc varies by adjusting Y suitably. 25 Meanwhile, the right-hand side can be held constant by adjusting a appropriately, and is constant if a =0. 13

16 This curvature is greater the more risk averse is the consumer on this interval. Putting together these implications of Proposition 3, we conclude that de cient treatment is a robust possibility over a range of values of a and b. Corollary 5 Under the hazard rate assumption and for a small illness probability, lesstreatment is delivered under demand management than under the ideal contract (L d >L ) if and only if the parameter a is su ciently small and the consumer is su ciently risk averse. The robust possibility of de cient treatment does not hinge on a small illness probability, as mentioned earlier. Let the utility function be logarithmic: U(Y )=ln(y), and assume a standard uniform distribution for losses: f(`) =1, F (`) =` with 0 ` 1 (thus dispensing with the hazard rate assumption as well). Let the cost of treatment be expressed as a fraction of income C = Y. Numerical results are displayed in Figure 1. The graphs describe the treatment thresholds L, as functions of : the lower one corresponds to the treatment threshold under the ideal contract; the higher one, demand management. Figure 1 shows that the threshold under demand management is higher for all values of. The graphs correspond to an expensive treatment: the value of was set at.65. Further numerical comparisons show that the di erence between the two thresholds (the second-best threshold subtracting the rst-best threshold) increases with. For small values of, this di erence is uniformly negative, while for high values of, it is uniformly positive. We have found that there are two local maxima for the numerical example and that the discontinuity in the second-best L represents a jump between them. Thus, the numerical example also illustrates that our de cient treatment possibility is robust even when the objective function is not quasi-concave. 26 In the introduction, we discussed the conventional wisdom that moral hazard causes an excessive provision of treatment. Of course, the conventional wisdom is imprecise, as are most conventional wisdoms. What is the relevant benchmark for determining if treatment is excessive under demand management? We have shown that the conventional wisdom is incorrect if the relevant benchmark is the delivery of treatment under an ideal contract when moral hazard is absent. 27 We have assumed implicitly that physicians act as perfect agents for the patients. In Ma and 26 It also illustrates how moral hazard can result in a rather extreme market failure no treatment or insurance. 27 Other benchmarks for the conventional wisdom are possible: (I) the amount of treatment that would be provided if consumers lacked insurance or (II) the amount of treatment that is e cient ex post, i.e. after consumers have paid the premium. The conventional wisdom according to interpretation (I) is obvious. The conventional wisdom according interpretation (II) is not necessarily correct. Once consumers have paid the insurance premium P d, it is socially e cient to provide treatment to an individual patient whenever the 14

17 Riordan (2000), we extend the utility loss model to include physician competition, and consider the other polar case in which the physicians are completely self-interested. In this alternative model, physicians compete for patients by adopting a practice style that commits them to a general level of service quality and a treatment threshold. Surprisingly, optimal demand management when pro t-maximizing physicians compete on practice style yields results almost identical to the case when physicians are perfect agents for consumers. Competition forces physicians to act in the interests of their patients, and in equilibrium, physicians adopt a treatment threshold that maximizes a consumer s ex post utility. 5 Supply Management and Managed Care A distinguishing feature of managed care is that health-care providers are given explicit incentives to limit treatments. Contracts with physician groups often feature a capitated payment for each patient but leave the physicians responsible for some or all of the treatment costs. This gives physicians an incentive to ration care in order to economize on treatment costs. Such supply management potentially complements and may even replace demand management as a method to control moral hazard. In this section, we introduce a pro t-conscious physician into the model and allow a role for managed care. For simplicity, we rely on the utility loss model. We argue that managed care bene ts consumers and may expand treatment. Indeed, managed care achieves ideal insurance in some cases. The technology of illness and treatment is the same as in our basic model. Consumer preferences have a utility loss representation: U(y) `. The insurance company contracts with the risk-averse consumer, and also with a risk-neutral physician (or physician group) to diagnose the patient and determine treatment. The physician learns the realization of ` from the diagnosis, and subsequently decides on treatment. We interpret managed care as a capitated payment arrangement in which the physician is severity of illness ` exceeds a threshhold L d satisfying U(Y P d ) U(Y P d al d ) bl d = U 0 (Y P d )C: If the probability of illness is small, then L d >L implies L d >L d. The reason is that, if the illness probability is small and P d is close to zero, then L d cannot be very much less than L. The formal proof is as follows. As! 0, P! 0 and P d! 0. Therefore, if L <L d in the limit, then a contradiction. bl d = U 0 (Y )C U(Y ) U(Y al d ) U 0 (Y ) C al d U 0 (Y )[C al ]=bl ; 15

18 credited a total payment of S + B for each diagnosed patient, but is liable for an amount B of the treatment cost. Equivalently, the physician is paid a xed fee, S, for a diagnosis, and an additional bonus, B, if the diagnosed patient does not receive treatment. 28 If the physician treats a patient with ` > L, then his expected payment is [S + F (L)B]. Without loss of generality, we assume that the treatment cost C is paid directly by the insurance company, i.e. the physician receives a net payment that deducts treatment cost liability from the capitation payments. The treatment decision is jointly determined by the physician and patient. To quote Arrow (1963, pp. 960): By certifying to the necessity of given treatment or the lack thereof, the physician acts as a controlling agent on behalf of the insurance companies. Needless to say, it is a far from perfect check; the physicians themselves are not under any control and it may be convenient for them or pleasing to their patients to prescribe more expensive medication, private nurses, more frequent treatments, and other marginal variations of care. In this spirit, we interpret the treatment decision as a collective decision that maximizes a weighted sum of the bene ts to the physician and the patient. 29 This might be interpreted as a reduced-form of a bargaining model, with the weights representing the bargaining strengths of the physician and the patient. Implicitly, we assume that bargaining occurs after the consumer becomes ill, but before the patient learns the severity of illness. Thus, the collective treatment decision in the utility loss model establishes a treatment threshold that maximizes the physician s expected treated payment minus the weighted patient s expected loss from illness, i.e. a value of L that maximizes ( Z ) L S + F (L)B µ `f(`)d` +[1 F (L)][U(Y P ) U(Y P D)] : 0 Themagnitudeoftheweight µ captures the bargaining strength of the patient, i.e. the higher the value of µ the greater the weight given to the patient s expected loss. The solution to the collective decision problem balances the physician s bonus payment against the treatment bene ts of the marginal patient: B µ [L U(Y P )+U(Y P D)] = 0: (15) 28 In principle, the contract could specify a payment to the physician even if the consumer does not become ill. However, under the limited liability assumption introduced below, this payment must be zero. 29 Ellis and McGuire (1990) use a similar assumption. 16

19 This optimality condition is analogous to a treatment constraint in the demand management problem. If B =0, then it is identical. If B>0, so that the physician is at least partially liable for the treatment cost, then it is weaker (L >U(Y P ) U(Y P D)) and some patients are rationed, i.e. a patient who wants treatment does not get it. 30 The other constraints on contractual relationships of the insurance company are as follows. First, the premium and expected copayment must cover the expected costs to the insurance company: P = fs + F (L)B +[1 F (L)] (C D)g: (16) Second, the physician must nd the relationship pro table: [S + F (L)B] U: (17) The term U in this individual rationality constraint is the opportunity cost of the physician s time and e ort in diagnosing and treating the patient. Finally, nancial constraints put lower bounds on payments to the physician, i.e. S S S + B S: (18) The second of these limited liability constraints is generally slack, and will be ignored. The rst may or may not be slack. The assumption that S is bounded from below by S allows the interpretation that the physician must be guaranteed a minimum compensation for the opportunity cost of diagnosis. 31 The optimal insurance contract maximizes the ex ante expected utility of the patient, given by (7) after setting a =0and b =1to conform with the utility loss model, subject to the treatment, individual rationality and limited liability constraints, given by (15) to (18). The problem can be simpli ed further. At an optimum, the premium constraint (16) must bind. Using this and the treatment constraint to eliminate S and B from (17) and (18) leaves a modi ed individual 30 The physician has no incentive to treat the patient and then do not report the treatment to the insurer in order to collect the bonus. This is because the physician would have to be responsible for the treatment cost. 31 Alternatively, the limited liability constraint can be interpreted as capturing risk aversion in a crude way; that is, the physician is risk neutral with respect to income variation above some critical level, and extremely risk averse for income variation below this level (Sappington, 1983). What is crucial for our analysis of managed care is that the physician is less risk averse than the patient with respect to the uncertain cost of treatment, and therefore, better able to absorb this risk. This is natural because the physician can diversify the treatment cost risks across a population of patients, and physicians can further pool this risk within a group practice. 17

20 rationality constraint, P U + [1 F (L)](C D); (19) and a modi ed limited liability constraint P fs + µf(l)[l U(Y P )+U(Y P D)]+[1 F (L)] (C D)g : (20) This reduces the managed care problem to choosing P, D, andl to maximize (7) subject to the modi ed individual rationality constraint (19) and the modi ed limited liability constraint (20). The managed care problem has the same structure as the demand management problem analyzed in Sections 3 and 4 (with S and U normalized to 0), except that the modi ed limited liability constraint (20) relaxes the treatment constraint (4). Therefore, since (4) was binding in the demand management problem, managed care must improve ex ante consumer welfare. We expect this relaxation of the treatment constraint to move the optimal treatment cuto in the direction of ideal insurance. Therefore, if optimal demand management results in de cient treatment relative to the ideal contract (e.g. as in Corollary 4), managed care should cause an expansion of treatment. Our next result shows that ideal insurance sometimes can be achieved when supply management is possible. Consider a relaxed managed care insurance problem in which the modi ed limited liability constraint (20) is ignored. That is, consider the maximization of (7) subject only to (19). The only di erence between this problem and the maximization problem for the ideal contract in Section 2 is that the premium must also compensate for the physician s opportunity cost of diagnosis. Proposition 1 applies directly, and the solution to the relaxed program speci es the ideal treatment threshold, L ; and a premium, P,thatsolveL = U 0 (Y P )C and P = U + [1 F (L )]C. The ideal copayment is zero. 32 Proposition 4 The optimal treatment decision, premium, and copayment under managed care are the same as for the ideal contract if and only if the minimum payment for diagnosis is low enough so that the limited liability constraint does not bind, i.e. [S + µf(l )L ] U. Under what conditions is the the limited liability constraint slack and ideal insurance possible? If copayment is set at zero, then the value of B must be set at µl to satisfy the treatment constraint (15) for the implementation of L. For the physician s reservation wage constraint to hold, the value of S must be set to U F (L )B = U µl F (L ). If this value of S is at least S, then the 32 The formal proof is straightforward and omitted. 18

Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care

Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care Ching-to Albert Ma Boston University Boston, MA 02215 ma@bu.edu and Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong Kong Michael

More information

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Alary D. Bien F. TSE (LERNA) University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note, we consider an adverse selection problem

More information

Health Insurance, Treatment Plan, and. Delegation to Altruistic Physician

Health Insurance, Treatment Plan, and. Delegation to Altruistic Physician Health Insurance, Treatment Plan, and Delegation to Altruistic Physician Ting Liu Ching-to Albert Ma Department of Economics Department of Economics Michigan State Univeristy Boston University 0 Marshall-Adams

More information

Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks

Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks Ching-to Albert Ma Henry Y. Mak Department of Economics Department of Economics Boston Univeristy Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis 270 Bay State

More information

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets Yijuan Chen Australian National University Xiangting u Renmin University of China Sanxi Li Renmin University of China ANU Working

More information

Optimal demand management policies with probability weighting

Optimal demand management policies with probability weighting Optimal demand management policies with probability weighting Ana B. Ania February 2006 Preliminary draft. Please, do not circulate. Abstract We review the optimality of partial insurance contracts in

More information

Corporate Income Taxation

Corporate Income Taxation Corporate Income Taxation We have stressed that tax incidence must be traced to people, since corporations cannot bear the burden of a tax. Why then tax corporations at all? There are several possible

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Age and Choice in Health Insurance: Evidence from Switzerland

Age and Choice in Health Insurance: Evidence from Switzerland Age and Choice in Health Insurance: Evidence from Switzerland Karolin Becker and Peter Zweifel* November 5, 2004 Abstract: Elements of regulation inherent in most social health insurance systems are a

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment

Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment Optimal Health Insurance for Prevention and Treatment Randall P. Ellis Department of Economics Boston University Willard G. Manning Harris School of Public Policy Studies The University of Chicago We thank

More information

CostandQualityIncentivesinHealthCare: Altruistic Providers

CostandQualityIncentivesinHealthCare: Altruistic Providers CostandQualityIncentivesinHealthCare: Altruistic Providers Ching-to Albert Ma Department of Economics Boston University 27 Bay State Road Boston Massachusetts 2215 ma@bu.edu December, 1997 JEL Classification

More information

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance.

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Franck Bien David Alary University Paris Dauphine November 10, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we want to characterize the optimal health insurance

More information

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts Vijay Krishna y and John Morgan z November 7, 2008 Abstract We study strategic voting in a Condorcet type model in which voters have identical preferences but di erential

More information

Sharp and Diffuse Incentives in Contracting

Sharp and Diffuse Incentives in Contracting Risk & Sustainable Management Group Risk and Uncertainty Working Paper: R07#6 Research supported by an Australian Research Council Federation Fellowship http://www.arc.gov.au/grant_programs/discovery_federation.htm

More information

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems Interlinkages between Payment and Securities Settlement Systems David C. Mills, Jr. y Federal Reserve Board Samia Y. Husain Washington University in Saint Louis September 4, 2009 Abstract Payments systems

More information

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009 The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 010 October 009 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 408 The design and e ciency of loyalty rewards Ramon

More information

Adverse Selection. Chapter 3

Adverse Selection. Chapter 3 Chapter 3 Adverse Selection Adverse selection, sometimes known as The Winner s Curse or Buyer s Remorse, is based on the observation that it can be bad news when an o er is accepted. Suppose that a buyer

More information

Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?

Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking? Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking? Jurg Blum * Institut zur Erforschung der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, University of Freiburg, D-79085

More information

Application of sensitivity analysis in investment project evaluation under uncertainty and risk

Application of sensitivity analysis in investment project evaluation under uncertainty and risk International Journal of Project Management Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 217±222, 1999 # 1999 Elsevier Science Ltd and IPMA. All rights reserved Printed in Great Britain 0263-7863/99 $ - see front matter PII: S0263-7863(98)00035-0

More information

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS Gustavo A. Marrero Alfonso Novales y July 13, 2011 ABSTRACT: In a Barro-type economy with exogenous consumption aspirations, raising income taxes favors

More information

A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion

A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion William S. Neilson Department of Economics University of Tennessee Knoxville, TN 37996-0550 wneilson@utk.edu March 2009 Abstract This paper takes the

More information

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Cécile Aubert Abstract Two agents sequentially contracts with different principals under moral

More information

The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias

The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias Anne Beyer and Ilan Guttman Stanford University September 2007 Abstract The paper models the interaction between a sell-side analyst and a risk-averse

More information

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley

Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Boalt Hall UC Berkeley Title: A Note on Settlements under the Contingent Fee Method of Compensating Lawyers Author: Polinsky, A. Mitchell, Stanford Law School Rubinfeld, Daniel L., University of California,

More information

Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary

Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary Exact Nonparametric Tests for Comparing Means - A Personal Summary Karl H. Schlag European University Institute 1 December 14, 2006 1 Economics Department, European University Institute. Via della Piazzuola

More information

Auditor liability rules under imperfect information and costly litigation: the welfare-increasing eœect of liability insurance

Auditor liability rules under imperfect information and costly litigation: the welfare-increasing eœect of liability insurance The European Accounting Review 2000, 9:3, 371 385 Auditor liability rules under imperfect information and costly litigation: the welfare-increasing eœect of liability insurance Ralf Ewert, Eberhard Feess

More information

Choice under Uncertainty

Choice under Uncertainty Choice under Uncertainty Part 1: Expected Utility Function, Attitudes towards Risk, Demand for Insurance Slide 1 Choice under Uncertainty We ll analyze the underlying assumptions of expected utility theory

More information

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 28: 25 32, 2003 c 2003 The Geneva Association On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance CHU-SHIU LI Department of Economics, Feng Chia

More information

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land). Chapter 3 Credit and Business Cycles Here I present a model of the interaction between credit and business cycles. In representative agent models, remember, no lending takes place! The literature on the

More information

Pricing Health Bene ts: A Cost-Minimization Approach

Pricing Health Bene ts: A Cost-Minimization Approach Pricing Health Bene ts: A Cost-Minimization Approach Nolan H. Miller March 14, 2005 Abstract We study the role of health bene ts in an employer s compensation strategy, given the overall goal of minimizing

More information

Accident Law and Ambiguity

Accident Law and Ambiguity Accident Law and Ambiguity Surajeet Chakravarty and David Kelsey Department of Economics University of Exeter January 2012 (University of Exeter) Tort and Ambiguity January 2012 1 / 26 Introduction This

More information

CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS

CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS LUÍS VASCONCELOS y Abstract. I analyze a simple model of hold-up with asymmetric information at the contracting stage.

More information

The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University

The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance. Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University \ins\liab\dlirpr.v3a 06-06-07 The Reasonable Person Negligence Standard and Liability Insurance Vickie Bajtelsmit * Colorado State University Paul Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas Thistle s research

More information

14.451 Lecture Notes 10

14.451 Lecture Notes 10 14.451 Lecture Notes 1 Guido Lorenzoni Fall 29 1 Continuous time: nite horizon Time goes from to T. Instantaneous payo : f (t; x (t) ; y (t)) ; (the time dependence includes discounting), where x (t) 2

More information

IDENTIFICATION IN A CLASS OF NONPARAMETRIC SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS. Steven T. Berry and Philip A. Haile. March 2011 Revised April 2011

IDENTIFICATION IN A CLASS OF NONPARAMETRIC SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS. Steven T. Berry and Philip A. Haile. March 2011 Revised April 2011 IDENTIFICATION IN A CLASS OF NONPARAMETRIC SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS By Steven T. Berry and Philip A. Haile March 2011 Revised April 2011 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1787R COWLES FOUNDATION

More information

Our development of economic theory has two main parts, consumers and producers. We will start with the consumers.

Our development of economic theory has two main parts, consumers and producers. We will start with the consumers. Lecture 1: Budget Constraints c 2008 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. Two Goods are Often Enough 3. Properties of the Budget Set 4. How the Budget Line Changes 5. The Numeraire 6. Taxes, Subsidies,

More information

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade?

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade? Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy te Gains from Free Trade? Yasukazu Icino Department of Economics, Konan University June 30, 2010 Abstract I examine lump-sum transfer rules to redistribute te

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector

Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector David Bardey, Fernando Jaramillo and Ximena Peña May 014 bstract We study the e ect of UI bene ts in a typical developing country where the

More information

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development Edgar A. Ghossoub University of Texas at San Antonio Robert R. Reed University of Alabama July, 20 Abstract In this paper, we examine the impact

More information

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies

Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies Optimal Paternalism: Sin Taxes and Health Subsidies Thomas Aronsson and Linda Thunström Department of Economics, Umeå University SE - 901 87 Umeå, Sweden April 2005 Abstract The starting point for this

More information

Cooperation with Network Monitoring

Cooperation with Network Monitoring Cooperation with Network Monitoring Alexander Wolitzky Microsoft Research and Stanford University July 20 Abstract This paper studies the maximum level of cooperation that can be sustained in sequential

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information By: Michael Rothschild and Joseph Stiglitz Presented by Benjamin S. Barber IV, Xiaoshu Bei, Zhi Chen, Shaiobi

More information

Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet

Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet Yongmin Chen y Chuan He z August 2006 Abstract Paid placement, where advertisers bid payments to a search engine to have their products appear next

More information

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 69 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi 1 Kobe University Received 1 April 2003; accepted

More information

Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline

Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline Marie Hoerova European Central Bank Cyril Monnet FRB Philadelphia November 2010 PRELIMINARY Abstract This paper provides a theory for the joint existence

More information

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Carlo Reggiani Tommaso Valletti y 15th May 2011 - Very preliminary and incomplete Abstract Net neutrality is a hotly debated topic. A key point

More information

Moral hazard in health insurance: How important is forward looking behavior?

Moral hazard in health insurance: How important is forward looking behavior? Moral hazard in health insurance: How important is forward looking behavior? Aviva Aron-Dine, Liran Einav, Amy Finkelstein, and Mark Cullen y January 2012 Abstract. We investigate whether individuals exhibit

More information

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains?

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains? The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains? Wilfred J. Ethier Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania First version: 30 November 2007 This printing: 21 April 2009 The Greater the Differences,

More information

MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES

MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES C The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2005, Vol. 72, No. 4, 525-538 MULTIPLE LOSSES, EX ANTE MORAL HAZARD, AND THE IMPLICATIONS FOR UMBRELLA POLICIES Michael Breuer ABSTRACT Under certain cost conditions

More information

Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance*

Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance* Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance* Erik Höglin Stockholm School of Economics erik:hoglin@hhs:se July 2007 ABSTRACT. This paper considers optimal unemployment and disability insurance in an

More information

Representation of functions as power series

Representation of functions as power series Representation of functions as power series Dr. Philippe B. Laval Kennesaw State University November 9, 008 Abstract This document is a summary of the theory and techniques used to represent functions

More information

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems

Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Normalization and Mixed Degrees of Integration in Cointegrated Time Series Systems Robert J. Rossana Department of Economics, 04 F/AB, Wayne State University, Detroit MI 480 E-Mail: r.j.rossana@wayne.edu

More information

Moral Hazard, Market Power, and Second Best Health Insurance

Moral Hazard, Market Power, and Second Best Health Insurance Moral Hazard, Market Power, and Second Best Health Insurance by Berthold U. Wigger* Department of Economics University of Erlangen-Nuremberg D-90403 Nürnberg berthold.wigger@wiso.uni-erlangen.de and Markus

More information

Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial

Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial Another Example in which Lump-Sum Money Creation is Bene cial Alexei Deviatov and Neil Wallace y October 10th, 2000 Abstract A probabilistic version of lump-sum money creation is studied in a random matching

More information

How Does the Life Settlement A ect the Primary Life Insurance Market?

How Does the Life Settlement A ect the Primary Life Insurance Market? How Does the Life Settlement A ect the Primary Life Insurance Market? Hanming Fang Edward Kung y June 12, 2008 Abstract We study the e ect of life settlement market on the structure of the long-term contracts

More information

Optimal Piecewise Linear Income Taxation

Optimal Piecewise Linear Income Taxation D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 6007 Optimal Piecewise Linear Income Taxation Patricia Apps Ngo Van Long Ray Rees October 2011 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for

More information

How To Solve A Minimum Set Covering Problem (Mcp)

How To Solve A Minimum Set Covering Problem (Mcp) Measuring Rationality with the Minimum Cost of Revealed Preference Violations Mark Dean and Daniel Martin Online Appendices - Not for Publication 1 1 Algorithm for Solving the MASP In this online appendix

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1758R March 21 Revised August 21 TARGETING IN ADVERTISING MARKETS: IMPLICATIONS FOR OFFLINE VS. ONLINE

More information

Costly Voting when both Information and Preferences Di er: Is Turnout Too High or Too Low?

Costly Voting when both Information and Preferences Di er: Is Turnout Too High or Too Low? Costly Voting when both Information and Preferences Di er: Is Turnout Too High or Too Low? Sayantan Ghosal and Ben Lockwood University of Warwick October, 2008 Abstract We study a model of costly voting

More information

How To Find Out How Health Insurance Affects Medical Spending

How To Find Out How Health Insurance Affects Medical Spending Moral hazard in health insurance: How important is forward looking behavior? Aviva Aron-Dine, Liran Einav, Amy Finkelstein, and Mark Cullen y July 2012 Abstract. We investigate whether individuals exhibit

More information

Growth in the Nonpro t Sector and Competition for Funding

Growth in the Nonpro t Sector and Competition for Funding Growth in the Nonpro t Sector and Competition for Funding Debra Yurenka November 2007 Abstract: I use September 11, 2001 as an example of an unanticipated event that increased fundraising productivity

More information

A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION. Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense. Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo

A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION. Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense. Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo A GENERALIZATION OF THE PFÄHLER-LAMBERT DECOMPOSITION Jorge Onrubia Universidad Complutense Fidel Picos REDE-Universidade de Vigo María del Carmen Rodado Universidad Rey Juan Carlos XX Encuentro de Economía

More information

American Economic Association

American Economic Association American Economic Association The Economics of Moral Hazard: Comment Author(s): Mark V. Pauly Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 3, Part 1 (Jun., 1968), pp. 531-537 Published by: American

More information

Analyzing the Demand for Deductible Insurance

Analyzing the Demand for Deductible Insurance Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 18:3 3 1999 1999 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Analyzing the emand for eductible Insurance JACK MEYER epartment of Economics, Michigan State

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary

The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary The Elasticity of Taxable Income: A Non-Technical Summary John Creedy The University of Melbourne Abstract This paper provides a non-technical summary of the concept of the elasticity of taxable income,

More information

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful?

Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? Economics Letters 87 (2005) 313 317 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Optimal health insurance contract: Is a deductible useful? David Bardey a, T, Romain Lesur b a GREMAQ UMR CNRS 5604-Manufacture des

More information

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model 21.1: Introduction This is an important chapter in that it introduces, and explores the implications of, an empirically relevant utility function representing intertemporal

More information

Midterm March 2015. (a) Consumer i s budget constraint is. c i 0 12 + b i c i H 12 (1 + r)b i c i L 12 (1 + r)b i ;

Midterm March 2015. (a) Consumer i s budget constraint is. c i 0 12 + b i c i H 12 (1 + r)b i c i L 12 (1 + r)b i ; Masters in Economics-UC3M Microeconomics II Midterm March 015 Exercise 1. In an economy that extends over two periods, today and tomorrow, there are two consumers, A and B; and a single perishable good,

More information

Pricing Cloud Computing: Inelasticity and Demand Discovery

Pricing Cloud Computing: Inelasticity and Demand Discovery Pricing Cloud Computing: Inelasticity and Demand Discovery June 7, 203 Abstract The recent growth of the cloud computing market has convinced many businesses and policy makers that cloud-based technologies

More information

Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation

Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation Optimal Age Specific Income Taxation Jean-Marie Lozachmeur 1 October, 2005 1 GREMAQ, University of Toulouse. Mailing: Gremaq, 21 Allée de Brienne F- 31000 Toulouse. E-mail: jean-marie.lozachmeur@univ-tlse1.fr.

More information

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Elena Del Rey and Laura Romero October 004 Abstract In this paper we investigate the optimal choice of prices and/or exams by universities

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility.

Common sense, and the model that we have used, suggest that an increase in p means a decrease in demand, but this is not the only possibility. Lecture 6: Income and Substitution E ects c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline 1. Introduction 2. The Substitution E ect 3. The Income E ect 4. The Sign of the Substitution E ect 5. The Total Change in Demand

More information

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction Kevin E. Beaubrun-Diant and Fabien Tripier y June 8, 00 Abstract We herein advance a contribution to the theoretical literature on nancial frictions and show

More information

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint. Lecture 2b: Utility c 2008 Je rey A. Miron Outline: 1. Introduction 2. Utility: A De nition 3. Monotonic Transformations 4. Cardinal Utility 5. Constructing a Utility Function 6. Examples of Utility Functions

More information

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Daniele Coen-Pirani Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890, USA Abstract This paper studies

More information

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines No 23 Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines Geza Sapi, Irina Suleymanova June 2011 IMPRINT DICE DISCUSSION PAPER Published by Heinrich

More information

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements Florian Morath Johannes Münster y December 5, 2014 Abstract We study platform design in online markets in which buying involves

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education

Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 5330 Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education Tom McKenzie Dirk Sliwka

More information

Eight Recommendations to Improve Employee Engagement

Eight Recommendations to Improve Employee Engagement REWARD STRATEGY AND PRACTICE Eight Recommendations to Improve Employee Engagement Tom McMullen, Hay Group * To start, let's de ne employee engagement as the level of commitment that employees feel toward

More information

Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba

Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba Submitted to the Economics Department on October 24, 2005, in partial ful

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 14-14 Employment Gains from Minimum-Wage Hikes under Perfect Competition: A Simple General-Equilibrium Analysis Richard A. Brecher and Till Gross Carleton University November 2014 CARLETON ECONOMIC

More information

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Ilona Babenko Michael Lemmon Yuri Tserlukevich Hong Kong University of Science and Technology and University of Utah March 2009 Our goals

More information

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication) Filipe R. Campante Davin Chor July 200 Abstract In this online appendix, we present the proofs for

More information

GOVERNMENT CONTRACT COSTS, PRICING & ACCOUNTING REPORT

GOVERNMENT CONTRACT COSTS, PRICING & ACCOUNTING REPORT Reprinted with permission from Government Contract Costs, Pricing & Accounting Report, Volume 10, Issue 2, K2015 Thomson Reuters. Further reproduction without permission of the publisher is prohibited.

More information

The Plan Sponsor's Guide to Delegating, Recordkeeping Made Simple

The Plan Sponsor's Guide to Delegating, Recordkeeping Made Simple THE EXCELLENT FIDUCIARY The Plan Sponsor's Guide to Delegating, Part II: Recordkeeping Made Simple Ronald E. Hagan * An ERISA recordkeeper is one of the most heavily reliedupon experts within a plan sponsor's

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

How To Understand The Relationship Between Health Insurance And Moral Hazard

How To Understand The Relationship Between Health Insurance And Moral Hazard Optimal health insurance contract : can moral hazard incresase indemnity? David Alary SDFi, University Paris Dauphine Franck Bien LEGOS, University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note, we generalize the

More information

Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Creina Day * School of Economics The Australian National University Canberra ACT 0200 Australia T: + 61 2

More information

An optimal redistribution scheme for trade gains

An optimal redistribution scheme for trade gains An optimal redistribution scheme for trade gains Marco de Pinto y University of Kassel May 25, 202 Abstract The contribution of this paper is to derive an optimal redistribution scheme for trade gains

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Monetary Policy Implementation Frameworks: A Comparative Analysis Antoine Martin Cyril Monnet Staff Report no. 313 January 2008 Revised October 2009 This

More information

Demand for Health Insurance

Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance Demand for Health Insurance is principally derived from the uncertainty or randomness with which illnesses befall individuals. Consequently, the derived demand for health insurance

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints WORING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 448 Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond and Måns Söderbom May 2010 ISSN 1403-2473 (print) ISSN 1403-2465 (online) Department

More information