Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?"

Transcription

1 Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking? Jurg Blum * Institut zur Erforschung der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, University of Freiburg, D Freiburg, Germany Received 4 February 1998; accepted 14 July 1998 Abstract In a dynamic framework it is shown that capital adequacy rules may increase a bank's riskiness. In addition to the standard negative e ect of rents on risk attitudes of banks a further intertemporal e ect has to be considered. The intuition behind the result is that under binding capital requirements an additional unit of equity tomorrow is more valuable to a bank. If raising equity is excessively costly, the only possibility to increase equity tomorrow is to increase risk today. Ó 1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classi cation: G21; G28 Keywords: Capital adequacy rules; Banking regulation; Risk taking 1. Introduction There is an ongoing debate about the e ects of capital adequacy rules on banks' risk taking behavior. This paper introduces a new argument which has been neglected so far. It is shown that in a dynamic setting a new intertemporal e ect can arise which leads to an increase in risk. The key insight is that under * Tel.: ; fax: ; blumj@vwl.uni-freiburg.de /99/$ ± see front matter Ó 1999 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S ( 9 8 )

2 756 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 binding capital requirements an additional unit of equity tomorrow is more valuable to a bank. If raising equity is excessively costly, the only possibility to increase equity tomorrow is to increase risk today. E ects of capital adequacy rules on banks' behavior have been analyzed before. The literature most closely related to this paper deals with consequences of capital rules for banks' asset risk. 1 For value-maximizing banks, Furlong and Keeley (1989) demonstrate that capital requirements reduce risktaking incentives, while Flannery (1989) concludes that higher risk taking may be induced. In a mean±variance framework, Koehn and Santomero (1980, 1988), and Rochet (1992) show that improperly chosen risk weights may increase the riskiness of banks. Other authors argue that capital requirements reduce monitoring incentives, which reduces the quality of banks' portfolios (Besanko and Kanatas, 1993; Boot and Greenbaum, 1993). Dewatripont and Tirole (1995) view capital rules as a means to e ciently allocate control rights between di erent groups of claimholders, thereby indirectly in uencing the bank managers' incentives. Finally, Gehrig (1995) points out that capital requirements in uence the nature of strategic competition among banks. While each of the above articles emphasizes a di erent aspect of capital adequacy requirements, they all have in common that they concentrate on static e ects. In this context the present paper illustrates the importance of taking into account the dynamic perspective of the banking business. In the following the decision problem of a single bank is analyzed, both when it is regulated and when it is not regulated. The resulting optimal choices are compared with the rst-best solution of the model. Due to limited liability an unregulated bank has a tendency to take `excessive risks', i.e., risks higher than rst best. If the bank only faces a binding capital rule in the rst period, tightening the requirement decreases these risks. If capital requirements are implemented in the second period, however, banks may increase asset risk in period 1. This is true because tightening the regulation has two e ects. First, a tighter restriction lowers the expected pro ts of the bank. If pro ts are lower, the bank has less to lose in the event of bankruptcy. Therefore, increasing risk, and hence the probability of default, is less costly for the bank the stronger the restriction. Second, changes in the regulation a ect the marginal return on risk. In the present model this marginal return on risk may be raised and therefore may reinforce the rst e ect, which leads to an overall increase in risk. The reason is the fact that under a binding regulation equity tomorrow is more valuable to the bank. In a regime of binding capital requirements the amount that can be invested in the risky but pro table asset is restricted to a multiple of the value 1 See also the special issue of the Journal of Banking and Finance about `The Role of Capital in Financial Institutions', which is related to this topic (Vol. 19, No. 3-4, pp. 393±742).

3 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± of equity. This implies that an additional unit of equity leads to an additional investment larger than one unit in the risky asset. Due to this `leverage e ect' equity is more valuable to a regulated bank. A bank facing binding capital rules therefore has a higher incentive to increase equity tomorrow. However, if a bank nds it prohibitively costly to raise additional equity in the capital market or is completely unable to do so, the only way to increase the amount of equity tomorrow is to increase risk today The model The model has the following simple time structure. At time t ˆ 0 a bank can invest its available funds. After one period at time t ˆ 1 returns are realized. If the bank does not default, another investment can be undertaken. Again after one period the nal returns are realized at time t ˆ 2, and all parties are compensated. I assume that bank managers are risk neutral and act perfectly in the interest of shareholders. This implies that they maximize the expected value of equity. The bank is nanced by equity and deposits. While the initial stock of equity W 0 is exogenously given, the supply of deposits D 0 at t ˆ 0 can be chosen by the bank. After one period, the bank has to pay the costs of C D 0 (with C 0 ; C 00 > 0 and C 0 ˆ 0). This cost function can be thought of as stemming from an incomplete competition framework. If banks are horizontally di erentiated, they each enjoy a local monopoly. If they want to attract more deposits, they have to raise interest rates to capture a greater market share. Doing so the bank not only incurs the costs of these marginal deposits, but also raises the costs on all infra-marginal deposits. Hence the costs of deposits are rising at an increasing rate. All depositors are protected by deposit insurance. Since deposits are fully insured, depositors always get their money back, no matter how risky the bank. Therefore, their demand of deposits is independent of the bank's riskiness. The assumption of universal risk neutrality enables us to separate risk e ects due to risk choice from risk e ects due to risk aversion of depositors, managers, and regulators. At t ˆ 0 the bank has two investment opportunities: A safe asset with (gross) rate of return R f P 1 and a risky portfolio. The risk±return structure of the 2 This leverage e ect due to the rigid link between equity and the volume of loans induced by capital adequacy rules may also amplify macroeconomic uctuations. If negative shocks to aggregate demand reduce the ability of rms to service their debts to banks, this reduction in debt service lowers bank equity. Because of the capital requirements, this in turn reduces bank lending and industry investment. See Blum and Hellwig (1995).

4 758 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 portfolio can be in uenced by the bank. In accordance with nance theory, at least in a certain range there is supposed to be a positive trade-o between risk and expected return. To avoid corner solutions with in nite risk, I assume that after some point a further increase in risk leads to a decrease in expected return. Speci cally, I assume the following two-point distribution of the gross rate of return ~R; with the lower realization normalized to zero: ~R ˆ X with probability p X ; ~R ˆ 0 with probability 1 p X ; for X P R f ; with p 0 X < 0; p 00 X 6 0 and p R f ˆ 1: These assumptions imply that E ~RjX Š ˆ p X X is strictly concave. In order for the expected return to be increasing in X at R f ; I further assume that p 0 R f > 1=R f : The unique level of risk that maximizes expected return is denoted by X 3. Obviously, the safe asset is (weakly) dominated by the risky portfolio. Thus, since all the funds are invested in the risky portfolio, the probability of default is 1 p X for every given X. If the available funds at t ˆ 1 are not su cient to cover the costs C D 0, the bank defaults and all the available funds (if any) are transferred to the deposit insurance fund which pays depositors their contracted returns. Due to limited liability bank owners cannot be forced to pay any additional amount to cover unful lled claims. At time t ˆ 1 the model has the same structure as at t ˆ 0. While the costs of deposits D 1 are again C D 1 (with C 0 ; C 00 > 0 and C 0 ˆ 0), the amount of equity W 1 is determined by the initial amount W 0 at t ˆ 0 plus the pro ts or losses of the rst period. For convenience, however, I only consider a reduced form of a risky asset at t ˆ 1. To simplify the exposition, I abstract from the uncertainty in the second period and replace the random variable in period 2 with its expected value R > R f. The model could easily be generalized to allow for richer structures in period 2. While possibly more realistic, a true replication of the rst-period structure in period 2, however, would render the model analytically intractable. The main consequence of the present approach is that the incentive for asset substitution in period 2 is neglected. But since we are interested in the choice of risk at t ˆ 0, doing so does not qualitatively a ect the results of the paper. 3 The assumptions on the convexity of the cost function of deposits and the concavity of the return distribution are very similar to Gennotte and Pyle (1991). They also need two curvature assumptions to enable comparative statics and to guarantee interior solutions. They also make an assumption about the concavity of the return distribution. But since they have a completely elastic supply of deposits at the risk-free rate, they introduce a `cost function of loan initiation' which is increasing and convex in the level of investment and in their risk index.

5 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± First best Absent any bankruptcy costs, a risk-neutral social planner chooses that level of risk that maximizes expected returns, X, i.e., X satis es 4 p 0 X X p X ˆ 0: It is important to note that in this model it is socially e cient to incur a positive amount of risk. A perfectly safe investment policy, i.e., X ˆ R f ; is not optimal. An increase in risk implies on the one hand a higher probability of default and on the other hand a higher return given no default. Up to X the net e ect of such an increase in risk on the expected return is positive. By choosing a completely safe investment, these additional gains would be foregone The unregulated bank An unregulated bank solves max p X f ~W 1 D 1 R C D 1 g 1 p X maxf0; C D 0 g; X ;D 0 ;D 1 where ~W 1 ˆ X W 0 D 0 C D 0 is the value of equity at t ˆ 1 in case of success. Due to limited liability the value of equity in case of failure is zero and the bank cannot continue operation. Hence, the second term is zero. Inserting, we get max p X f X W 0 D 0 C D 0 D 1 Š R C D 1 g: X ;D 0 ;D 1 The optimality conditions are " p 0 ^X ^X p ^X p 0 C ^D 0 ^X ^D # 1 R C ^D 1 ˆ 0; 2 ^D 0 W 0 R ^D 0 W 0 ^X C 0 ^D 0 ˆ 0; 3 R C 0 ^D 1 ˆ 0: 4 The higher the (expected) pro ts the bank makes by issuing deposits in period 2, ^D 1 R C ^D 1, the lower the risk taken in period 1. The reason for this is the fact that in case of failure (and therefore bankruptcy) the bank not only has a 1 4 The rst-best level of a variable Z is denoted by Z. The (optimal) levels of an unregulated and a regulated bank are denoted by ^Z and Z r ; respectively. 5 In fact, most banking systems encourage banks taking risky positions. For example, in most industrialized countries the banking system as a whole does perform a positive amount of (risky) maturity transformation. See also Goodman and Santomero (1986).

6 760 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 payo of zero, but it also loses these pro ts in period 2. If these future pro ts, or `rents', are high, it is optimal for the bank to reduce risk to increase the probability of getting these rents at the expense of a lower value of equity at t ˆ 1 in case of success. 6 If these rents are high enough, it is even possible that a bank chooses a lower level of risk than rst best. In that case, capital adequacy requirements clearly would not be an appropriate instrument to remedy the situation. To avoid this possibility, I assume that the future rent is not too high, i.e., RC ^D 0 > ^D 1 R C ^D 1. Given this assumption, at t ˆ 0 the bank chooses a level of risk which is higher than rst best, ^X > X. This follows from a comparison of Eqs. (1) and (2), and the concavity of the expected return function The regulated bank In order to analyze the impact of capital rules on risk taking, I rst look at the case where only in the rst period a requirement is binding. Then I consider a bank that faces a requirement only in the second period. It turns out that the e ect of capital adequacy rules on risk taking incentives can be totally di erent in the two scenarios. While in the rst case capital adequacy rules lower the risk, in the second case they actually lead to an increase in risk. Finally, the case where a bank is facing a binding requirement in both periods is discussed. Basically, capital adequacy requirements have two e ects on risk taking incentives. First, they in uence the marginal costs of taking risk. The tighter the requirements, the lower the pro ts in case of success and the less a bank has to lose if it defaults. Since the marginal costs of taking risk are these pro ts times the decrease in the probability of success, a higher requirement tends to increase risk. Second, capital rules a ect the marginal return of taking risk. Here the actual e ect depends crucially on the regime we are in. If the regulation is only binding in the rst period, marginal returns of taking risk are reduced. Increasing risk raises the rate of return in case of success. The gain from such an increase is proportional to the amount invested at this rate of return. Under a binding requirement the amount that can be invested is a multiple of the given value of equity. The tighter the regulation, the lower this multiple. Therefore, a stricter regulation today tends to reduce risk. In contrast, a binding regulation in the second period increases the marginal return of taking risk in the rst period. An additional unit of equity in period 2 allows additional investment in the risky but pro table asset of a multiple of this unit, as opposed to a one-for-one relationship in the unregulated case. 6 See also Boot and Greenbaum (1993). There, banks have a lower incentive to monitor projects and thereby increase risk, if future rents are reduced.

7 While the amount of equity today is exogenously given, the amount of equity tomorrow is not xed, but can actually be in uenced through the investment decision today. By increasing risk today the bank has a higher amount of equity available tomorrow in case of success. Therefore, the introduction of a capital requirement for tomorrow induces a higher risk today Binding requirement in the rst period According to the Basel Accord of 1988 the value of equity has to be at least as high as a given fraction of all risk-weighted assets. 7 In this model a socalled `Cooke ratio' c 0 in the rst period implies that a bank can invest no more than W 0 =c 0 k 0 W 0 in the risky portfolio. 8 If the capital adequacy requirement is binding, as much as possible is invested in the risky asset, k 0 W 0 : For this, W 0 k 0 1 deposits are necessary. Beyond that the bank can issue further deposits ~D 0, as long as these funds are invested in the safe asset. The total amount of deposits is therefore D r 0 ˆ maxf k 0 1 W 0 ; C 0 1 R f g 6 ^D 0 5 or J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± D r 0 ˆ k 0 1 W 0 ~D 0 : The problem the bank has to solve is max p X ~W 1 D 1 R C D 1 Š; ~D 0 P 0; X ; ~D 0 ;D 1 where again ~W 1 is the value of equity at t ˆ 1 in case of success, ~W 1 ˆ k 0 W 0 X ~D 0 R f C D r 0 : The rst-order conditions are p 0 X f ~W 1 D 1 R C D 1 g p X k 0 W 0 R ˆ 0; 6 R C 0 D 1 ˆ 0; R f C 0 D r 0 ~D 6 0; 0 R f C 0 D r 0 Š ˆ 0; ~D 0 P 0: The rst term in Eq. (6) represents the marginal cost of increasing risk. The expression in curly brackets is the pro t of the bank in case of success. Increasing risk slightly lowers the probability of success by p 0 X ; and therefore lowers the expected pro t. The second term is the marginal return on risk. A 7 For more details on the Basel Accord, see Dewatripont and Tirole (1995). 8 Note that these capital rules do not imply a maximum debt-to-equity ratio. Rather the leverage is indirectly determined through the banks' behavior. Also observe that in contrast to most models in the literature (and in accordance with reality) the capital requirements are not necessarily binding.

8 762 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 higher risk implies a higher rate of return on the total amount of funds invested in the risky asset at t ˆ 0; k 0 W 0. This higher return in case of success in turn translates into a higher amount of equity at t ˆ 1, which can be reinvested in the risky asset with return R. Hence, increasing risk by one unit increases the pro ts given no default by k 0 W 0 R. At the optimal level of risk, marginal costs are equal to the marginal return. We now want to determine the impact of an increase in the capital requirement on the risk taking behavior of the regulated bank. In order to do this, totally di erentiating Eq. (6) and rearranging we get dx p 0 X W 0 R X C 0 D r 0 ˆ p X W0 R dk 0 p 00 X f ~W 1 D 1 R C D 1 g 2p 0 X k 0 W 0 R : While the denominator is clearly negative, the numerator is not obviously of a given sign. This ambiguity re ects the two opposing e ects of a tightening of the capital rule. The rst e ect is the in uence of the Cooke ratio on the marginal cost of risk, p 0 X W 0 R X C 0 D r 0. Since a regulated bank faces a binding restriction, the highest possible payo is lower than the maximal payo of an unregulated bank. The tighter the restriction, the lower this payo, and increasing the probability of default by increasing risk becomes less costly, since a lower payo implies that a bank has less to lose in the event of default. The second e ect is the impact of a changing requirement on the marginal return on risk, p X W 0 R. A tighter restriction reduces the amount that can be invested in the risky asset. Since the return from taking risk is proportional to this amount, a higher Cooke ratio reduces the marginal return from taking risk. At the point where the capital regulation just becomes binding, by de nition the risk of a regulated bank and the risk of an unregulated bank are exactly the same. From Eq. (3) we also know that at that point X ˆ C 0 D r 0. Therefore, if the capital rule just becomes binding, a further tightening reduces the level of risk, dx =dk 0 > 0. It turns out that the return e ect always dominates the cost e ect, i.e., increasing the requirement always reduces the level of risk. Proposition 1. If the bank faces a binding capital adequacy requirement in the rst period, an increase in the requirement reduces the level of risk, dx =dc 0 < 0: The proof is in the appendix Binding requirement in the second period If in contrast to Section a bank faces a binding Cooke ratio c 1 in the second period, the amount of funds that can be invested in the risky asset at t ˆ 1 is restricted to W 1 =c 1 k 1 W 1 : Again, in addition to this the bank can invest as much money as desired in the safe asset, ~D 1 :

9 The bank maximizes max p X k 1 ~W 1 R ~D 1 R f C D r 1 Š; ~D 1 P 0; X ;D 0 ; ~D 1 where again ~W 1 is the value of equity at t ˆ 1 in case of success, ~W 1 ˆ W 0 D 0 X C D 0 ; and the total amount of deposits in period 2 is given by D r 1 ˆ k 1 1 ~W 1 ~D 1 : The rst-order conditions are J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± p 0 X fk 1 ~W 1 R ~D 1 R f C D r 1 g 7 p X W 0 D 0 fk 1 R k 1 1 C 0 D r 1 g ˆ 0; X C 0 D 0 ˆ 0; R f C 0 D r 1 6 0; ~D 1 R f C 0 D r 1 Š ˆ 0; ~D 1 P 0: As before, the rst term in Eq. (7) represents the marginal cost of increasing risk and the second term the marginal return on risk. While the interpretation of the cost term is the same as in the previous section, the marginal return on risk is now di erent. The key insight of the following argument is the fact that under a binding capital requirement the marginal value of equity is higher than in the absence of any regulation. Without regulation, an additional unit of equity at t ˆ 1 is invested in the risky asset and generates an additional return of R. If a bank is facing a binding capital rule, an additional unit of equity allows an investment of k 1 in the risky asset and generates a return of k 1 R. Since k 1 > 1, the bank has to increase the supply of deposits by k 1 1 to nance the di erence between the possible investment of size k 1 and the available unit of equity. These deposits cost k 1 1 C 0 D r 1. Since R P C 0 D r 1 if the requirement is binding, the marginal value of equity at t ˆ 1 is higher in a regime of a binding capital rule: k 1 R k 1 1 C 0 D r 1 P R: To analyze the impact of an increase in the capital requirement on the risk taking behavior of the regulated bank, we totally di erentiate and rearrange Eq. (7) to get dx h n o n oi ˆ p 0 X ~W 1 R C 0 D r 1 dk p X D 0 W 0 R C 0 D r 1 H 1 1.h n o p 00 X k 1 ~W 1 R ~D 1 R f C D r 1 2p 0 X D 0 W 0 n o i k 1 R k 1 1 C 0 D r 1 p X H 2 ; 8

10 764 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 where H 1 ˆ k 1 1 ~W 1 C 00 D r 1 if ~D 1 ˆ 0; H 1 ˆ 0 if ~D 1 > 0 and H 2 ˆ k D 0 W 0 2 C 00 D r 1 if ~D 1 ˆ 0; H 2 ˆ 0 if ~D 1 > 0: As before, the denominator is negative. But now it is possible that the numerator is also negative, i.e., it is possible that risk increases if the capital requirement is tightened, dx =dk 1 < 0. While as before a decrease in k 1 lowers the marginal cost of taking risk, it may also raise the marginal return on risk. As long as the marginal return increases or as long as it decreases less than the marginal cost falls, the level of risk will increase. 9 At the point where the capital requirement just becomes binding, we know from Eq. (4) that R ˆ C 0 D r 1 : At that point, the numerator of Eq. (8) is therefore p X D 0 W 0 H 1 < 0; and risk unambiguously increases if the regulation is tightened. If c 1 is raised further, risk will still increase. Eventually, the sign of Eq. (8) will change and risk will fall again 10. However, risk can never be reduced below the unregulated level ^X : This can be seen if we consider the tightest possible regulation, k 1 ˆ 1: Comparing the rst-order condition " # p 0 X r X r p X r p 0 X r C D r 0 D r 0 W Dr 1 R f C D r 1 0 R D r 0 W ˆ with Eq. (2), it is clear that X r > ^X ; since D r 1 R f C D r 1 < ^D 1 R C ^D 1 : The relationship between the Cooke ratio c 1 and the level of risk X r is summarized in the following proposition (see also Fig. 1). Proposition 2. When the capital requirement in the second period rst becomes binding at c 1 ; tightening the requirement raises the level of risk, dx =dc 1 > 0. If the requirement is further increased, risk eventually falls again, but never below the level of an unregulated bank, X r > ^X for all c 1 > c 1. 9 Within an options framework, Flannery (1989) reaches a similar conclusion. He states that `an increase in the maximum permissible leverage [M] reduces portfolio risk. This occurs because each dollar of equity is more valuable the higher is M' (p. 249). In his model this is true because an increase in risk has two opposing e ects. On the one hand it increases the option value of equity. On the other hand it reduces (expected) permissible leverage, which is smaller than M. If M is reduced, the former e ect becomes more important and risk is increased. 10 Using Eq. (9), it is straightforward to show that the denominator of Eq. (8) is positive at k 1 ˆ 1.

11 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± Fig. 1. It is interesting to note that even if a bank only expects a future capital requirement to increase, this may lead to perverse e ects on the risk choice today. In that case a future regulation, aimed at making the banking sector safer tomorrow, will actually make banking riskier today Binding requirement in both periods If a bank is both subject to a binding requirement today and tomorrow, the net e ect on risk is ambiguous. For instance, if a uniform capital requirement today and tomorrow is introduced, it is not clear whether the allocation is actually improved or if it is made worse. Denoting the binding capital requirement in both periods by k, the bank's problem becomes max p X k ~W 1 R ~D 1 R f C D r 1 Š; ~D 0 ; ~D 1 P 0; X ; ~D 0 ; ~D 1 where D r 0 and Dr 1 are de ned as before, and ~W 1 ˆ kw 0 X ~D 0 R f C D r 0. The rst-order condition regarding the level of risk is now p 0 X k ~W 1 R ~D 1 R f C D r 1 Š p X kw 0 k R k 1 C 0 D r 1 Š ˆ 0: 10 To derive the e ect of a change in the regulation on the level of risk, we again totally di erentiate Eq. (10) and get

12 766 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 dx dk ˆ h n o i p 0 X R C 0 D r 1 W ~ 1 kw 0 X C 0 D r 0 C 0 D r 1 W 0 X C 0 D r 0 D p X W 0 2k R 2k 1 C 0 D r 1 H 3Š ; 11 D where D < 0 is the left-hand side of Eq. (10) di erentiated with respect to X, and H 3 ˆ k k 1 C 00 D r 1 f ~W 1 k 1 W 0 X C 0 D r 0 g if ~D 1 ˆ 0; H 3 ˆ 0 if ~D 1 > 0: The numerator of Eq. (11) is not necessarily of a single sign, i.e., the relation between the Cooke ratio and the level of risk need not be monotonic. As in the previously considered cases, the marginal cost e ect always induces a higher level of risk. Whether the marginal return e ect leads to an increase in risk depends on the parameters of the model. Interestingly, the less stringent the regulation, i.e., the lower the Cooke ratio, the more likely it is that a tightening of the regulation increases risk. This is true because the `leverage e ect' 1=c is higher the lower c. One unit of equity allows an investment of 1=c units in the risky asset. The higher the leverage, the more valuable an additional unit of equity and, therefore, incurring a higher level of risk is more pro table for the bank. A similar reasoning leads to the observation that risk is more likely to be increased the higher the initial amount of equity W 0. Of course, if the amount of equity is very high, the regulation is not binding and the above reasoning does not apply. The problem of perverse incentive e ects, therefore, is most pronounced for banks for which the requirement is just binding in period 2. Finally, a tightening of the regulation is more likely to lead to an increase in risk the more convex the cost of deposits function C :. A binding requirement reduces the amount of deposits a bank can issue, and hence lowers the marginal costs of deposits. This means that issuing more deposits becomes more attractive to the bank. And since a bank may only issue more deposits if it has more equity available, it has a higher incentive to raise the level of risk in order to have a better equity position in case of success. The more convex the cost function, the stronger this incentive. Again, this e ect is most pronounced for banks for which the requirement is just binding in the second period. Eq. (11) can be somewhat simpli ed, if we consider that level of k, where the regulation is strictly binding in period one and just binding in period two. 11 In that case R ˆ C 0 D r 1 and Eq. (11) becomes 11 The converse case is not possible since the level of equity is always higher in the second period than in the rst period if the investment is successful.

13 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± Fig. 2. dx dk ˆ p0 X RW 0 X C 0 D r 0 p X W 0 R H 3 Š : D Since the rst term in the numerator is negative, a su cient condition for risk to increase if the regulation is tightened is R < H 3. As discussed above, this condition is more likely to be satis ed the more convex the cost function C :, the higher k, and the higher the initial amount of equity W 0. If the regulation is tightened further, risk will eventually decrease. Even a level of risk lower than rst best can be attained. To see this, we inspect the rst-order condition with respect to risk if k ˆ 1: " # R ~D p 0 X r X r p X r p 0 X r 0 R f C ~D 0 ~D 1 R f C ~D 1 ˆ 0: RW 0 Since the expression in square brackets is positive and the expected return function is concave, it follows that the level of risk with maximum regulation is lower than rst best, X r < X. To summarize, if a bank is subject to a capital regulation in both periods, risk initially falls as the requirement c is raised from a level where it is just binding in the rst period, c. As soon as the regulation also binds in the second period at ~c, a further tightening may raise the level of risk, even above the unregulated level. Eventually, risk will fall until it reaches a level lower than rst best at the maximal regulation. One possible example of the relationship between the level of risk and the Cooke ratio c is illustrated in Fig. 2.

14 768 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± Discussion This paper has shown that in a dynamic model with incentives for asset substitution, capital adequacy requirements may actually increase risks. If regulators are mainly concerned about reducing the insolvency risk of banks, introducing capital rules, therefore, may not be such a good idea after all. 12 One of the e ects of such a regulation is the reduction of a bank's pro ts. If future pro ts are lower, a bank has a smaller incentive to avoid default. In addition to this, the `leverage e ect' of capital rules raises the value of equity to the bank. For every dollar of equity, more than one dollar can be invested in the pro table but risky asset. In order to raise the amount of equity tomorrow it may be optimal for a bank to increase risk today. While the e ects illustrated in this paper are potentially important, it has to be kept in mind that the present model is only an example rather than a general theory. For instance, one could analyze more general return distribution. Unfortunately, due to the vagueness of the concept of `risk', the generalization of the model to arbitrary return distributions is not possible. In order to be able to make meaningful statements, one necessarily has to restrict the class of distributions under consideration. The distribution used in this model has two important properties: (i) an increase in risk leads to a higher probability of default, and (ii) the conditional expected return given no default rises as risk is increased. Whatever de nition of risk one wants to use, as long as these two properties are satis ed, the results of this paper hold. For instance, one class of distributions that satis es these conditions are distributions with the same mean that can be ordered according to the concept of `increasing risk' by Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970). 13 Another consequence of the assumed two-point distribution is that changes in the amount of equity and deposits do not a ect the default probability directly. If we consider continuous return distributions, increasing the amount of equity, e.g., lowers the probability of bankruptcy ceteris paribus. While the calculations would be greatly complicated through the inclusion of those marginal e ects, no additional insight would be gained. The qualitative results would still hold. The results of this paper are a reminder that one has to be careful when assessing the e ectiveness of capital adequacy rules. The present model illustrates that by arguing in a purely static framework, important dynamic e ects 12 Alternatively, if regulation is to be implemented, it should be done quickly in order to reduce the scope of risk taking in the interim phase. 13 Actually, it is possible that a so-called `mean-preserving spread' does neither increase the probability of default nor the expected return given no default. However, such an increase in risk can never decrease these two measures.

15 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± of the kind described here may be neglected. It is quite possible that the actual e ects of the regulation are contrary to the ones intended. 4. Appendix A. Proof of Proposition 1 Rearranging Eq. (6) " p 0 X X p X p 0 X C Dr 0 ~D 0 R f D # 1R C D 1 k 0 W 0 Rk 0 W 0 and denoting the expression in square brackets by A we get p 0 X X p X p 0 X A ˆ 0: Total di erentiation yields dx da ˆ p 0 X p 00 X X A 2p 0 X : Because of p 0 : < 0 and p 00 : 6 0, this is positive if X P A. To verify whether X P A is satis ed, simply note that in case of no default a bank always makes positive pro t, Xk 0 W 0 ~D 0 R f C D r 0 > 0. Therefore, risk falls if A decreases. In the case of ~D 0 ˆ 0 we have oa ˆ o C D r 0 D! 1R C D 1 ok 0 ok 0 k 0 W 0 Rk 0 W 0 ˆ 0 ˆ C0 W k 0 1 k 0 W 0 C W 0 k 0 1 k0 2W D 1R C D 1 0 Rk0 2W > 0; 0 since C 0 W 0 k 0 1 k 0 W 0 > C 0 W 0 k 0 1 k 0 1 W 0 > C W 0 k 0 1. In the case of ~D 0 > 0; D r 0 ˆ ~D 0 W 0 k 0 1 is constant (since C 0 D r 0 ˆ R f ) and oa ˆ o ok 0 ok 0 C D r 0 ~D 0 R f D! 1R C D 1 k 0 W 0 Rk 0 W 0 ˆ Rf k 0 W 2 0 C Dr 0 R f D r 0 W 0 k 0 1 W 0 k 2 0 W 2 0 D 1R C D 1 Rk0 2W : 0 Since the last term is positive, this expression is certainly positive if R f k 0 W 0 C D r 0 R f D r 0 W 0 k 0 1 > 0:

16 770 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755±771 Rearranging, we get R f D r 0 W 0 C D r 0 > 0: Since R f ˆ C 0 D r 0, we can write this as D r 0 C0 D r 0 R f W 0 C D r 0 > 0: Because of the strict convexity of C : and C 0 ˆ 0, this inequality always holds. To summarize, A increases if k 0 increases for all ~D 0 P 0. Therefore, since k 0 ˆ 1=c 0, risk decreases if c 0 increases. Acknowledgements Without implicating them, I would like to thank Thomas Gehrig, Niklaus Muller, Georg Noldeke, Mark de Snaijer, Markus Staub, seminar participants at the University of Basel, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments and discussions. Especially Martin Hellwig deserves credit for his continued encouragement and support of this work. Financial support of the WWZ Forderverein at the University of Basel and the Schweizerischer Nationalfonds is gratefully acknowledged. References Besanko, D., Kanatas, G., Credit market equilibrium with bank monitoring and moral hazard. Review of Financial Studies, 213±232. Blum, J., Hellwig, M., The macroeconomic implications of capital adequacy requirements for banks. European Economic Review 39, 739±749. Boot, A., Greenbaum, S., Bank regulation, reputation and rents theory and policy implications. In: Mayer, C., Vives, X. (Eds.), Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 262±285. Dewatripont, M., Tirole, J., The prudential regulation of banks. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Flannery, M., Capital regulation and insured banks' choice of individual loan default rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 24, 235±258. Furlong, F., Keeley, M., Capital regulation and bank risk-taking: A note. Journal of Banking and Finance 13, 883±891. Gehrig, T., Capital adequacy rules: Implications for banks' risk-taking. Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 131, 747±764. Gennotte, G., Pyle, D., Capital controls and bank risk. Journal of Banking and Finance 15, 805±824. Goodman, L., Santomero, A., Variable-rate deposit insurance: A re-examination. Journal of Banking and Finance 10, 203±218. Kim, D., Santomero, A., Risk in banking and capital regulation. Journal of Finance 43, 1219±1233.

17 J. Blum / Journal of Banking & Finance 23 (1999) 755± Koehn, H., Santomero, A., Regulation of bank capital and portfolio risk. Journal of Finance 35, 1235±1244. Rochet, J.-C., Capital requirements and the behaviour of commercial banks. European Economic Review 36, 1137±1178. Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J., Increasing risk: I. A de nition. Journal of Economic Theory 2, 225±243.

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk

Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Optimal insurance contracts with adverse selection and comonotonic background risk Alary D. Bien F. TSE (LERNA) University Paris Dauphine Abstract In this note, we consider an adverse selection problem

More information

Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline

Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline Central Bank Lending and Money Market Discipline Marie Hoerova European Central Bank Cyril Monnet FRB Philadelphia November 2010 PRELIMINARY Abstract This paper provides a theory for the joint existence

More information

Corporate Income Taxation

Corporate Income Taxation Corporate Income Taxation We have stressed that tax incidence must be traced to people, since corporations cannot bear the burden of a tax. Why then tax corporations at all? There are several possible

More information

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems

Interlinkages between Payment and Securities. Settlement Systems Interlinkages between Payment and Securities Settlement Systems David C. Mills, Jr. y Federal Reserve Board Samia Y. Husain Washington University in Saint Louis September 4, 2009 Abstract Payments systems

More information

Regulation and Bankers Incentives

Regulation and Bankers Incentives Regulation and Bankers Incentives Fabiana Gómez University of Bristol Jorge Ponce Banco Central del Uruguay May 7, 2015 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract We formally analyze and compare the effects of

More information

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development

The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development The Stock Market, Monetary Policy, and Economic Development Edgar A. Ghossoub University of Texas at San Antonio Robert R. Reed University of Alabama July, 20 Abstract In this paper, we examine the impact

More information

Midterm March 2015. (a) Consumer i s budget constraint is. c i 0 12 + b i c i H 12 (1 + r)b i c i L 12 (1 + r)b i ;

Midterm March 2015. (a) Consumer i s budget constraint is. c i 0 12 + b i c i H 12 (1 + r)b i c i L 12 (1 + r)b i ; Masters in Economics-UC3M Microeconomics II Midterm March 015 Exercise 1. In an economy that extends over two periods, today and tomorrow, there are two consumers, A and B; and a single perishable good,

More information

Agency Con icts, Prudential Regulation, and Marking to Market

Agency Con icts, Prudential Regulation, and Marking to Market Agency Con icts, Prudential Regulation, and Marking to Market Tong Lu The University of Houston Haresh Sapra The University of Chicago June 20, 202 Ajay Subramanian Georgia State University Abstract We

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Ester Faia Goethe University Frankfurt Nov 2015 Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Nov 2015 1 / 27 Introduction The RBC model explains the co-movements in the uctuations

More information

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets

Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets Quality differentiation and entry choice between online and offline markets Yijuan Chen Australian National University Xiangting u Renmin University of China Sanxi Li Renmin University of China ANU Working

More information

Capital Requirements, Market Power, and Risk-Taking in Banking

Capital Requirements, Market Power, and Risk-Taking in Banking Capital Requirements, Market Power, and Risk-Taking in Banking Rafael Repullo CEMFI and CEPR April 2002 Abstract This paper presents a dynamic model of imperfect competition in banking where the banks

More information

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities Elena Del Rey and Laura Romero October 004 Abstract In this paper we investigate the optimal choice of prices and/or exams by universities

More information

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land).

4. Only one asset that can be used for production, and is available in xed supply in the aggregate (call it land). Chapter 3 Credit and Business Cycles Here I present a model of the interaction between credit and business cycles. In representative agent models, remember, no lending takes place! The literature on the

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services

On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi / Journal of Economic Research 8 (2003) 69{76 69 On the Interconnection of Networks and Gains from Trade in Business Services Toru Kikuchi 1 Kobe University Received 1 April 2003; accepted

More information

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah www.frouah.com www.volopta.com In this Note we derive the Black Scholes PDE for an option V, given by @t + 1 + rs @S2 @S We derive the

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard Cécile Aubert Abstract Two agents sequentially contracts with different principals under moral

More information

Adverse Selection. Chapter 3

Adverse Selection. Chapter 3 Chapter 3 Adverse Selection Adverse selection, sometimes known as The Winner s Curse or Buyer s Remorse, is based on the observation that it can be bad news when an o er is accepted. Suppose that a buyer

More information

THE WELFARE IMPLICATIONS OF COSTLY MONITORING IN THE CREDIT MARKET: A NOTE

THE WELFARE IMPLICATIONS OF COSTLY MONITORING IN THE CREDIT MARKET: A NOTE The Economic Journal, 110 (Aril ), 576±580.. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK and 50 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. THE WELFARE IMPLICATIONS OF COSTLY MONITORING

More information

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Monetary Policy Implementation Frameworks: A Comparative Analysis Antoine Martin Cyril Monnet Staff Report no. 313 January 2008 Revised October 2009 This

More information

Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector

Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector Unemployment Insurance in the Presence of an Informal Sector David Bardey, Fernando Jaramillo and Ximena Peña May 014 bstract We study the e ect of UI bene ts in a typical developing country where the

More information

Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS

Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Fiscal Reform, Growth and Current Account Dynamics WORKING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS AND ECONOMETRICS Creina Day * School of Economics The Australian National University Canberra ACT 0200 Australia T: + 61 2

More information

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices

Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Margin Requirements and Equilibrium Asset Prices Daniele Coen-Pirani Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890, USA Abstract This paper studies

More information

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction

The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction The Credit Spread Cycle with Matching Friction Kevin E. Beaubrun-Diant and Fabien Tripier y June 8, 00 Abstract We herein advance a contribution to the theoretical literature on nancial frictions and show

More information

The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias

The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias The E ect of Trading Commissions on Analysts Forecast Bias Anne Beyer and Ilan Guttman Stanford University September 2007 Abstract The paper models the interaction between a sell-side analyst and a risk-averse

More information

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009

The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 2010 October 2009 The Design and Efficiency of Loyalty Rewards Ramon Caminal This version: October 010 October 009 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 408 The design and e ciency of loyalty rewards Ramon

More information

Spot Market Power and Futures Market Trading

Spot Market Power and Futures Market Trading Spot Market Power and Futures Market Trading Alexander Muermann and Stephen H. Shore The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania March 2005 Abstract When a spot market monopolist participates in the

More information

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade?

Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy the Gains. from Free Trade? Can a Lump-Sum Transfer Make Everyone Enjoy te Gains from Free Trade? Yasukazu Icino Department of Economics, Konan University June 30, 2010 Abstract I examine lump-sum transfer rules to redistribute te

More information

Liquidity Coinsurance and Bank Capital

Liquidity Coinsurance and Bank Capital Liquidity Coinsurance and Bank Capital Fabio Castiglionesi y Fabio Feriozzi z Gyöngyi Lóránth x Loriana Pelizzon { March 2011 Abstract This paper analyzes whether banks use their capital to deal with liquidity

More information

Portfolio selection based on upper and lower exponential possibility distributions

Portfolio selection based on upper and lower exponential possibility distributions European Journal of Operational Research 114 (1999) 115±126 Theory and Methodology Portfolio selection based on upper and lower exponential possibility distributions Hideo Tanaka *, Peijun Guo Department

More information

A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion

A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion A Simpli ed Axiomatic Approach to Ambiguity Aversion William S. Neilson Department of Economics University of Tennessee Knoxville, TN 37996-0550 wneilson@utk.edu March 2009 Abstract This paper takes the

More information

The Prison S Dilemma and Its Connections

The Prison S Dilemma and Its Connections Games Played in a Contracting Environment V. Bhaskar Department of Economics University College London Gower Street London WC1 6BT February 2008 Abstract We analyze normal form games where a player has

More information

Hedging Using Forward Contracts

Hedging Using Forward Contracts 10 CHAPTER 1 Business Snapshot1.1 Hedge Funds Hedge funds have become major users of derivatives for hedging, speculation, and arbitrage. A hedge fund is similar to a mutual fund in that it invests funds

More information

Incentive-based Regulation of Banks: An Interpretation of Basel II

Incentive-based Regulation of Banks: An Interpretation of Basel II Incentive-based Regulation of Banks: An Interpretation of Basel II Isil Erel* IT Sloan School of anagement October 2005 ABSTRACT This paper models the incentives of banks to undertake "Regulatory Capital

More information

Problem 1 (Issuance and Repurchase in a Modigliani-Miller World)

Problem 1 (Issuance and Repurchase in a Modigliani-Miller World) Problem 1 (Issuance and Repurchase in a Modigliani-Miller World) A rm has outstanding debt with a market value of $100 million. The rm also has 15 million shares outstanding with a market value of $10

More information

Capital markets, nancial intermediaries, and liquidity supply

Capital markets, nancial intermediaries, and liquidity supply Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (1998) 1157±1179 Capital markets, nancial intermediaries, and liquidity supply Paolo Fulghieri a,b, Riccardo Rovelli c, * a Finance Area, INSEAD, Boulevard de Constance,

More information

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it.

Optimal Investment. Government policy is typically targeted heavily on investment; most tax codes favor it. Douglas Hibbs L, L3: AAU Macro Theory 0-0-9/4 Optimal Investment Why Care About Investment? Investment drives capital formation, and the stock of capital is a key determinant of output and consequently

More information

Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework

Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework Journal of Banking & Finance 25 2001) 1789±1804 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Optimal portfolio selection in a Value-at-Risk framework Rachel Campbell, Ronald Huisman, Kees Koedijk * Department of Business

More information

Manufacturing exibility: Measures and relationships

Manufacturing exibility: Measures and relationships European Journal of Operational Research 118 (1999) 49±449 www.elsevier.com/locate/orms Theory and Methodology Manufacturing exibility: Measures and relationships Rodney P. Parker a, *, Andrew Wirth b

More information

Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education

Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R S E R I E S IZA DP No. 5330 Universities as Stakeholders in their Students Careers: On the Benefits of Graduate Taxes to Finance Higher Education Tom McKenzie Dirk Sliwka

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines

Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines No 23 Technology Licensing by Advertising Supported Media Platforms: An Application to Internet Search Engines Geza Sapi, Irina Suleymanova June 2011 IMPRINT DICE DISCUSSION PAPER Published by Heinrich

More information

THE FINANCING DECISIONS BY FIRMS: IMPACT OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE CHOICE ON VALUE

THE FINANCING DECISIONS BY FIRMS: IMPACT OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE CHOICE ON VALUE IX. THE FINANCING DECISIONS BY FIRMS: IMPACT OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE CHOICE ON VALUE The capital structure of a firm is defined to be the menu of the firm's liabilities (i.e, the "right-hand side" of the

More information

Introduction to Binomial Trees

Introduction to Binomial Trees 11 C H A P T E R Introduction to Binomial Trees A useful and very popular technique for pricing an option involves constructing a binomial tree. This is a diagram that represents di erent possible paths

More information

Labor Market Cycles, Unemployment Insurance Eligibility, and Moral Hazard

Labor Market Cycles, Unemployment Insurance Eligibility, and Moral Hazard Labor Market Cycles, Unemployment Insurance Eligibility, and Moral Hazard Min Zhang y Miquel Faig z May 4, 2011 Abstract If entitlement to UI bene ts must be earned with employment, generous UI is an additional

More information

EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Cheap Talk

EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Cheap Talk EconS 53 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Cheap Talk. Cheap talk with Stockbrokers (From Tadelis, Ch. 8, Exercise 8.) A stockbroker can give his client one of three recommendations regarding a certain

More information

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge

Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Net neutrality and innovation at the core and at the edge Carlo Reggiani Tommaso Valletti y 15th May 2011 - Very preliminary and incomplete Abstract Net neutrality is a hotly debated topic. A key point

More information

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment

Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Employee Stock Options, Financing Constraints, and Real Investment Ilona Babenko Michael Lemmon Yuri Tserlukevich Hong Kong University of Science and Technology and University of Utah March 2009 Our goals

More information

A Welfare Criterion for Models with Distorted Beliefs

A Welfare Criterion for Models with Distorted Beliefs A Welfare Criterion for Models with Distorted Beliefs Markus Brunnermeier, Alp Simsek, Wei Xiong August 2012 Markus Brunnermeier, Alp Simsek, Wei Xiong () Welfare Criterion for Distorted Beliefs August

More information

Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet

Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet Paid Placement: Advertising and Search on the Internet Yongmin Chen y Chuan He z August 2006 Abstract Paid placement, where advertisers bid payments to a search engine to have their products appear next

More information

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints WORING PAPERS IN ECONOMICS No 448 Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints Stephen R. Bond and Måns Söderbom May 2010 ISSN 1403-2473 (print) ISSN 1403-2465 (online) Department

More information

Capital Adequacy Regulation: In Search of a Rationale

Capital Adequacy Regulation: In Search of a Rationale Financial Institutions Center Capital Adequacy Regulation: In Search of a Rationale by Franklin Allen Douglas Gale 03-07 The Wharton Financial Institutions Center The Wharton Financial Institutions Center

More information

Sharp and Diffuse Incentives in Contracting

Sharp and Diffuse Incentives in Contracting Risk & Sustainable Management Group Risk and Uncertainty Working Paper: R07#6 Research supported by an Australian Research Council Federation Fellowship http://www.arc.gov.au/grant_programs/discovery_federation.htm

More information

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS

GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS GROWTH, INCOME TAXES AND CONSUMPTION ASPIRATIONS Gustavo A. Marrero Alfonso Novales y July 13, 2011 ABSTRACT: In a Barro-type economy with exogenous consumption aspirations, raising income taxes favors

More information

PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES*

PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES* THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 0022-1821 Volume L June 2002 No. 2 PAYMENT SYSTEMS AND INTERCHANGE FEES* Richard Schmalensee{ In a typical bank credit card transaction, the merchant's bank pays an

More information

Labor Market Cycles and Unemployment Insurance Eligibility

Labor Market Cycles and Unemployment Insurance Eligibility Labor Market Cycles and Unemployment Insurance Eligibility Miquel Faig Min Zhang y Febrary 16, 2008 Abstract If entitlement to UI bene ts must be earned with employment, generous UI is an additional bene

More information

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts

Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts Voluntary Voting: Costs and Bene ts Vijay Krishna y and John Morgan z November 7, 2008 Abstract We study strategic voting in a Condorcet type model in which voters have identical preferences but di erential

More information

Credit monitoring and development: The impact of nancial integration

Credit monitoring and development: The impact of nancial integration Credit monitoring and development: The impact of nancial integration Lin Guo 1 Université de Paris I Panthéon Sorbonne March 31, 2010 1 CES-EUREQua, Maison des Sciences Economiques, 106-112, boulevard

More information

14.451 Lecture Notes 10

14.451 Lecture Notes 10 14.451 Lecture Notes 1 Guido Lorenzoni Fall 29 1 Continuous time: nite horizon Time goes from to T. Instantaneous payo : f (t; x (t) ; y (t)) ; (the time dependence includes discounting), where x (t) 2

More information

Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable

Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable Incentive Compensation for Risk Managers when Effort is Unobservable by Paul Kupiec 1 This Draft: October 2013 Abstract In a stylized model of a financial intermediary, risk managers can expend effort

More information

Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks

Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks Tiered and Value-based Health Care Networks Ching-to Albert Ma Henry Y. Mak Department of Economics Department of Economics Boston Univeristy Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis 270 Bay State

More information

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance.

Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Adverse selection and moral hazard in health insurance. Franck Bien David Alary University Paris Dauphine November 10, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we want to characterize the optimal health insurance

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole Luís M. B. Cabral New York University and CEPR November 2005 1 Introduction Beginning with their seminal 2002 paper,

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Real Business Cycle Theory Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Introduction to DSGE models Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models have become the main tool for

More information

1 Present and Future Value

1 Present and Future Value Lecture 8: Asset Markets c 2009 Je rey A. Miron Outline:. Present and Future Value 2. Bonds 3. Taxes 4. Applications Present and Future Value In the discussion of the two-period model with borrowing and

More information

Subordinated Debt and the Quality of Market Discipline in Banking by Mark Levonian Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Subordinated Debt and the Quality of Market Discipline in Banking by Mark Levonian Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Subordinated Debt and the Quality of Market Discipline in Banking by Mark Levonian Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Comments by Gerald A. Hanweck Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Visiting Scholar,

More information

Taxation of Shareholder Income and the Cost of Capital in a Small Open Economy

Taxation of Shareholder Income and the Cost of Capital in a Small Open Economy Taxation of Shareholder Income and the Cost of Capital in a Small Open Economy Peter Birch Sørensen CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 5091 CATEGORY 1: PUBLIC FINANCE NOVEMBER 2014 An electronic version of the paper

More information

Application of sensitivity analysis in investment project evaluation under uncertainty and risk

Application of sensitivity analysis in investment project evaluation under uncertainty and risk International Journal of Project Management Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 217±222, 1999 # 1999 Elsevier Science Ltd and IPMA. All rights reserved Printed in Great Britain 0263-7863/99 $ - see front matter PII: S0263-7863(98)00035-0

More information

Computational Finance Options

Computational Finance Options 1 Options 1 1 Options Computational Finance Options An option gives the holder of the option the right, but not the obligation to do something. Conversely, if you sell an option, you may be obliged to

More information

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Brunel University Msc., EC5504, Financial Engineering Prof Menelaos Karanasos Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model Recall that the price of an option is equal to

More information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information by Sanford Grossman This model shows how the heterogeneous information

More information

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets Nathaniel Hendren January, 2014 Abstract Both Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976) show that

More information

On Prevention and Control of an Uncertain Biological Invasion H

On Prevention and Control of an Uncertain Biological Invasion H On Prevention and Control of an Uncertain Biological Invasion H by Lars J. Olson Dept. of Agricultural and Resource Economics University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742, USA and Santanu Roy Department

More information

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty

Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty Lecture notes for Choice Under Uncertainty 1. Introduction In this lecture we examine the theory of decision-making under uncertainty and its application to the demand for insurance. The undergraduate

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance*

Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance* Optimal Unemployment and Disability Insurance* Erik Höglin Stockholm School of Economics erik:hoglin@hhs:se July 2007 ABSTRACT. This paper considers optimal unemployment and disability insurance in an

More information

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk Proponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible to beat the market consistently. In support of their

More information

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need

The recent turmoil in nancial markets has highlighted the need Economic Quarterly Volume 100, Number 1 First Quarter 2014 Pages 51 85 A Business Cycle Analysis of Debt and Equity Financing Marios Karabarbounis, Patrick Macnamara, and Roisin McCord The recent turmoil

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper)

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research

More information

Risk intermediation in supply chains

Risk intermediation in supply chains IIE Transactions (2000) 32, 819±831 Risk intermediation in supply chains VIPUL AGRAWAL and SRIDHAR SESHADRI Operations Management Department, Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY

More information

How To Understand The Relationship Between Information Quality And Profit

How To Understand The Relationship Between Information Quality And Profit Accounting Conservatism, Aggregation, and Information Quality Qintao Fan y Xiao-jun Zhang z Abstract This paper demonstrates that conservative aggregation in accounting often improves the overall quality

More information

Does strengthening Collective Action Clauses (CACs) help?

Does strengthening Collective Action Clauses (CACs) help? Does strengthening Collective Action Clauses (CACs) help? Sayantan Ghosal a, Kannika Thampanishvong b a Department of Economics, University of Warwick, Coventry, United Kingdom. b School of Economics and

More information

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II. The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model Universidad de Montevideo Macroeconomia II Danilo R. Trupkin Class Notes (very preliminar) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model 1 Introduction One shortcoming of the Solow model is that the saving rate is exogenous

More information

Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba

Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba Three Essays on Monopolist Second-degree Discrimination Strategies in the Presence of Positive Network E ects by Gergely Csorba Submitted to the Economics Department on October 24, 2005, in partial ful

More information

Cooperation with Network Monitoring

Cooperation with Network Monitoring Cooperation with Network Monitoring Alexander Wolitzky Microsoft Research and Stanford University July 20 Abstract This paper studies the maximum level of cooperation that can be sustained in sequential

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

E cient Credit Policies in a Housing Debt Crisis

E cient Credit Policies in a Housing Debt Crisis Housing Credit E cient Credit Policies in a Housing Debt Crisis Janice Eberly and Arvind Krishnamurthy Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, and Stanford GSB May 2015 Housing Credit Introduction

More information

Money and Capital in an OLG Model

Money and Capital in an OLG Model Money and Capital in an OLG Model D. Andolfatto June 2011 Environment Time is discrete and the horizon is infinite ( =1 2 ) At the beginning of time, there is an initial old population that lives (participates)

More information

Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1

Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1 Health Insurance, Moral Hazard, and Managed Care 1 Ching-to Albert Ma Department of Economics Boston University 270 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215 ma@bu.edu Michael H. Riordan Graduate School of Business

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS

CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS CONTRACTUAL SIGNALLING, RELATIONSHIP-SPECIFIC INVESTMENT AND EXCLUSIVE AGREEMENTS LUÍS VASCONCELOS y Abstract. I analyze a simple model of hold-up with asymmetric information at the contracting stage.

More information

The Business Consequences of Subtinated Debt

The Business Consequences of Subtinated Debt Regulation, Subordinated Debt and Incentive Features of CEO Compensation in the Banking Industry 1 Kose John Stern School of Business New York University 44 West 4 th Street New York, NY 10012 Email: kjohn@stern.nyu.edu

More information

Unemployment insurance/severance payments and informality in developing countries

Unemployment insurance/severance payments and informality in developing countries Unemployment insurance/severance payments and informality in developing countries David Bardey y and Fernando Jaramillo z First version: September 2011. Tis version: November 2011. Abstract We analyze

More information

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance

On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 28: 25 32, 2003 c 2003 The Geneva Association On Compulsory Per-Claim Deductibles in Automobile Insurance CHU-SHIU LI Department of Economics, Feng Chia

More information

1 Uncertainty and Preferences

1 Uncertainty and Preferences In this chapter, we present the theory of consumer preferences on risky outcomes. The theory is then applied to study the demand for insurance. Consider the following story. John wants to mail a package

More information

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts 0. Fixed-Income Securities Fixed-income securities (FIS) are bonds that have no default risk and their payments are fully determined in advance. Sometimes corporate bonds that do not necessarily have certain

More information

Labor Contracts, Equal Treatment and Wage-Unemployment Dynamics

Labor Contracts, Equal Treatment and Wage-Unemployment Dynamics Labor Contracts, Equal Treatment and Wage-Unemployment Dynamics Abstract This paper analyses a model in which rms cannot pay discriminate based on year of entry to a rm, and develops an equilibrium model

More information