(a) Compute the price and marginal revenue for each number of units. Table 20.1 summarizes the marginal revenues and costs for this problem.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "(a) Compute the price and marginal revenue for each number of units. Table 20.1 summarizes the marginal revenues and costs for this problem."

Transcription

1 22.1 Marginal Value, Marginal Cost and Deadweight Loss (a) With decreasing marginal value for buyers (as expected with efficient allocation of goods / downward sloping demand curve) and increasing marginal costs of production, social surplus is maximized at the quantity such that Marginal Value = Marginal Cost. Here, this occurs somewhere between unit 4 and unit 5, so the optimum is corresponds to quantity = 4. At Q* = 4, the value to buyers of goods sold is = 22 and the production cost of sellers is = 6, so social surplus = 22 6 = 16. (a) Compute the price and marginal revenue for each number of units. Table 20.1 summarizes the marginal revenues and costs for this problem. Step 1: Identify the price corresponding to each quantity by reading off the price by column from left to right in the row labeled Buyer Value Step 2: Compute total revenue = Quantity multiplied by price for each value of quantity. Step 3: Compute total costs by adding the production costs from left to right in the row labeled Seller Cost. Step 4: Compute Profit = Total Revenue Total Costs for each quantity (column). Table 22.1 Marginal and Total Costs and Revenues Quantity Price Total Revenue Total Costs Profit Marginal Revenue Marginal Cost DWL (if not produced) (c) Referring to the table in (b), the optimal quantity for a monopolist is 3, with a resulting profit of 15 3 = 12. Note that if the monopolist could produce fractional quantities, there would be an even more profitable quantity between 3 and 4 since MR(Q=3) = 3 > MC(Q = 3) = 2. Alternately, it is possible to compute the profit levels for each possible quantity in order to identify the profit maximizing choice: 1. Price = 7 implies quantity = 1 with total cost 0. Profit = 1 x 7 0 = Price = 8 implies quantity = 2 with total cost 1. Profit = 2 x 6 1 = 11.

2 3. Price = 5 implies quantity = 3 with total cost 3. Profit = 3 x 5 3 = Price = 4 implies quantity = 4 with total cost 6. Profit = 4 x 4 6 = Price = 3 implies quantity = 5 with total cost 10. Profit = 5 x 3 10 = Price = 2 implies quantity = 6 with total cost 15. Profit = 6 x 2 15 = Price = 1 implies quantity = 7 with total cost 21. Profit = 7 x 1 21 = (d) The deadweight loss is the cost of lost social surplus. With production limited to integers, deadweight loss corresponds to the social value of unit 4, which the monopolist will not produce. That is, DWL = Buyer Value (unit 4) = Seller Cost (Unit 4) = 4 3 = Geometry of the Cost and Demand Functions in Monopoly Pricing (a) The monopolist maximizes Q P(Q) C(Q) = 16Q Q 2 8Q. This has first-order condition 8 2Q = 0, Therefore the optimal quantity is Q* = 4, and optimal price is P(Q*) = 16 4 = 12. (b) Now the monopolist s objective function is Π(Q) = 16Q Q 2 2 Q 2 = 16Q - 3 Q 2. This has first-order condition 16 = 6Q and yields solution Q* = 16 / 6 = 8 / 3. Although both cost functions C(Q) = 8Q and C(Q) = 2Q 2 yield C(Q) = 32 at Q = 4, (the monopoly quantity from (a)) they are not identical in terms of marginal cost. In fact, MC (a) = 8, MC (b) = 4Q, so that MC is larger in (b) if Q > 2. That is, the cost function in (b) represents an increase in marginal cost from (a) for quantities near the optimum in (a). As a result, the monopoly solution in (b) involves a lower quantity than in (a). (c) Now the monopolist s objective function is Π(Q) = 16Q Q 3 / 4 8 Q = 8Q Q 3 / 4. This has first-order condition 8 = 3Q 2 / 4 and yields solution Q* = SQRT(32 / 3), which is approximately Although both demand functions P(Q) = 16 Q and P(Q) = 16 Q 2 / 4 yield P(Q) = 12 and Q = 4 (the monopoly quantity from (a)), they are not identical in terms of marginal revenue. MR (a) = 16 2Q, while MR (c) = 16-3Q 2 / 4. Thus MR (c) > MR (a) if 2Q > 3Q 2 / 4, which holds for Q < 8/3 marginal revenue is higher for (c) than for (a) if Q < 8/3 and higher for (c) than for (a) if Q > 8/3. That is, the demand function in (c) represents a reduction in marginal revenue from (a) for quantities near the optimum in (a). As a result, the monopoly solution in (c) involves a lower quantity than in (a).

3 22.3 Monopoly and Comparison of Cost Functions (a) Substituting for p 1 (Q) and p 2 (Q), p 2 (Q) > p 1 (Q) if (10 Q) > 10 Q. Solving this inequality, (10 Q) > 10 Q Q + Q 2 > 10 Q 91 19Q + Q 2 > 0 The left-hand side is strictly convex (d 2 LHS / dq 2 > 0), so dlhs / dq = 0 identifies the global minimum: dlhs / dq = 2Q 19 = 0 at Q = 19 / 2. At Q = 19/2, LHS = * 19/2 + (19 / 2) 2 = Since this is the global minimum, LHS > 0 for all Q, indicating p 2 (Q) > p 1 (Q) for Q < 10. Thus, p 2 (Q) > p 1 (Q) whenever p 1 (Q) > 0. (For Q > 10, both p 1 (Q) and p 2 (Q) are equal to 0.) (b) First note that dp 1 (Q) / dq = 1, dp 2 (Q) / dq = 2(10-Q), so both functions are decreasing for Q < 10 (the range of values where these price functions are positive). The condition for general equilibrium in an industry with constant marginal cost is simply MC = p(q). Define Q 1 * and Q 2 * to be the general equilibrium quantities for demand functions 1 and 2 respectively given MC = c. Since p 2 (Q) > p 1 (Q), it must be that p 2 (Q 1 *) > p 1 (Q 1 *) = c. Since dp 2 (Q) / dq < 0 and p 2 (Q 1 *) > c, the equilibrium condition p 2 (Q 2 *) = c requires Q 2 * > Q 1 *. (c) Revenue 1 (Q) = Q p 1 (Q) = 10Q Q 2 MR 1 (Q) = 10 2Q Revenue 2 (Q) = Q p 2 (Q) = Q(10 Q) 2 + Q = 101Q 20Q 2 + Q 3 MR 2 (Q) = Q + 3Q 2 Both MR 1 (Q) and MR 2 (Q) are declining in Q for Q < 10, so the first-order condition for profit maximization (i.e. MR(Q) = MC = c) is sufficient for profit maximization for a monopolist.

4 $ Figure 10.3 Comparing Marginal Revenue Functions MR1(Q) MR2(Q) Define Q 1M * and Q 2M * to be the general equilibrium prices for demand functions 1 and 2 respectively given MC = c. A monopolist would only choose Q 1M * > Q 2M * if MR 1 (Q) > MR 2 (Q) for some values of Q. Comparing MR 1 (Q) and MR 2 (Q), MR 1 (Q) MR 2 (Q) = (10 2Q) (101 40Q + 3Q 2 ) = 38 Q 3Q 2 91 This difference is a declining function of Q for Q < 38 / 6. Solving the quadratic equation 38 Q - 3Q 2 91 = 0 yields the relevant solution Q = (38 SQRT(352)) / At Q = 3.21, MR 1 (Q) = MR 2 (Q) = Since MR 1 (Q), MR 2 (Q) and the difference MR 1 (Q) - MR 2 (Q) are all declining in Q, 3.58 > MR 1 (Q) > MR 2 (Q) for Q > If c < 3.58, then MR 1 (Q 1M ), MR 2 (Q 2M ) = c with Q* 1M, Q* 2M > 3.21 and Q* 1M > Q* 2M. However, if c > 3.58, then MR 1 (Q 1M ), MR 2 (Q 2M ) = c with Q* 1M, Q* 2M < 3.21 and Q* 1M < Q* 2M. Choosing c* = 3.58, Q* 1M < Q* 2M if c > c* and Q* 1M > Q* 2M if c < c*. Q

5 22.4 Elasticities and the Price-Cost Margin (a) Rewriting p(q) = (q / α) -1/ε = (α / q) 1/ε. The monopolist solves Max (q) Π(q) = qp(q) c(q) = α 1/ε q (ε -1) / ε cq d Π / dq = α 1/ε [(ε -1) / ε] q -1 / ε c. If ε < 1, then both terms in d Π / dq are negative for q > 0, so in fact d Π / dq < 0, indicating that q = 0 is the optimum. But the odd part about this choice is that the with this demand function, p(q) as q 0. In fact, for q positive but very small, production costs c(q) are infinitesimal, but total revenue q p(q) = α 1/ε q (ε -1) / ε actually becomes infinite since q (ε -1) / ε = 1 / q (1 - ε) / ε as q 0. Thus, the monopolist s optimum for ε < 1 is to choose a very tiny quantity and charge an essentially infinite price. For this reason, the optimal price is not well defined. But the real problem is that the demand function is unrealistic it assumes that demand goes to zero too slowly as price becomes infinite. (b) From above, d Π / dq = α 1/ε [(ε -1) / ε] q -1 / ε c. Setting this equal to 0, we find (FOC) α 1/ε [(ε -1) / ε] q -1 / ε = c, OR c q 1 / ε = α 1/ε [(ε -1) / ε], OR q* = α [(ε -1) / cε] ε Now substitute in the formula p(q) = (q / α) -1/ε = (α / q) 1/ε to find the optimal p. p* = (α / q*) 1/ε = (ε -1) / c ε. The price-cost margin is given by (p m c) / p m = c / (ε -1). Alternately, it is also possible to work with q(p) and solve for (FOC) for the optimal price, as follows. Max (p) Π(p) = αp 1-ε cα p -ε dπ / dp = α [(1 ε) p -ε + c ε p -(ε+1) ] = α p -ε-1 [(1 ε) p + c ε ] = 0 So FOC for this problem has solution p m = c ε / (ε -1), corresponding to quantity q m = αp m -ε = α [c ε / (ε -1)] ε, consistent with our earlier results.

6 22.5 Exchange Equilibrium with Monopoly Production (a) As in the previous problem, once L 2 is fixed, person 2 has endowment (0, 8 L 2 ) and demands bundle (4qL 2, 4 L 2 ), while person 1 has endowment (2, 0) and demands bundle (1, 1/q). The equilibrium price q*(l 2 ) must clear the market for both goods. The market clearing condition for good y is given by 4 L 2 + 1/q = 8 L 2 OR q = 1 / (4 L 2 ). The equilibrium price as a function of L 2 is given by q*(l 2 ) = 1/ (4 L 2 ). Thus, person 2 can anticipate consuming the bundle (1, 4 L 2 ) after accounting for the effect of the choice of L 2 on q*. (b) Person 2 maximizes v(x 2, y 2, L 2 ) = (4L 2 * 1) 1/2 L 2 2 = 2 L 2 1/2 L 2 2. The first-order condition for the optimal value of L 1 is 1/2 1 / L 2 = 2 L 2 OR 3/2 L 2 = 1/2, which has solution L 2 = 1 / 4 1/ and associated price q*(l 2 ) = 4-2/ (c) Monopoly Outcome In the monopoly outcome, person 2 chooses L 2 = 1 / 4 1/3 and each consumer chooses the same equilibrium bundle (1, 4 2/3 ). Person 2 s utility is then v(x 2M, y 2M, L 2M ) = (4 2/3 * 1) 1/2 (1/4 1/3 ) Person 1 s utility is u(x 1M, y 1M ) = (4 2/3 * 1) 1/ Competitive Outcome In the competitive outcome, person 2 chooses L 2 = 1 and each consumer chooses the same equilibrium bundle (1, 4). Person 2 s utility is then v(x 2C, y 2C, L 2C ) = (4 * 1) 1/2 (1) 2 = 1. Person 1 s utility is u(x 1C, y 1C ) = (4 * 1) 1/2 = 2. Revealed Preference Logic As monopolist, person 2 can choose from any production level and the equilibrium (i.e. marketclearing) price associated with that production level. One such option is the competitive equilibrium with L 2 = 1, q*(l 2 ) = 4 L 2 = 4. By revealed preference, person 2 must do at least as well in the monopoly outcome as in the competitive equilibrium. Further, we should expect person 2 to gain higher utility in the monopoly outcome because the competitive outcome neglects the effect of production on marginal revenues to person 2 strongly suggesting that the

7 competitive outcome will involve too much production relative to the optimal level for a monopolist. (d) The monopoly outcome is not Pareto optimal. To see this, note that the marginal utility for person 2 for additional consumption of good y from the monopoly outcome is given by v / y 2 = (x 2M / y 2M ) 1/2 / 2 = (1 / 4 2/3 ) 1/2 / Since each unit of labor devoted to production yields eight units of good y, the marginal cost of an additional unit of good y is equal to (1/8) v / L 2 = L 2 / 4= 1 / 4 4/ The marginal utility for additional production of good y is greater than its cost. Therefore the outcome is not Pareto optimal.

8 23.1 Price Discrimination with Two Types of Consumers (a) A competitive market will set the same price for men and women with price equal to marginal cost = 4. Soving for the quantities for men and women that correspond to this price, we have q m = 30 p m = 26, and similarly q w = (24 p w ) / 2 = 10, for total quantity of 36. (b) Now we definitely want to work in quantity as a function of price so that we can add the two demand curves: Q m (p) = 30 p m ; Q w (p) = 12 p w / 2. So if price p < 24, both groups consume positive amounts. For this range of prices, we can simply add the two demand functions to get total demand: Q total (p) = 42 3p/2 if p < 24. However, if p > 20, only men consume widgets, so Q total (p) = Q m (p) = 30 p if p > 24. Note that these two separate formulas give the same outcome Q = 6 at p = 24 where we switch from a regime of having both types buying to having only men buying the good. Note also that if we add the two demand functions for p > 24, we will be including negative consumption for women in the total demand, which does not make sense. Now, we have a two-part kinked demand curve for men and women with quantity as function of price. So we can solve for the monopolist optimum by deriving first-order conditions, but we have to be careful about comparing the option of selling to both consumers or selling to neither group of consumers. PART 1: Both men and women consume positive amounts: Max Q(p) (p c) = (42 3p/2) (p 4) = 48 p 3p 2 / Taking the derivative with respect to p yields the first-order condition 48 3p = 0, corresponding to optimum p* = 16. This price is in the given range p < 24, so in fact it must be the best choice of price so that both men and women will purchase the good corresponding to quantity 18 (14 for men and 4 for women), revenue of 18 * 16 = 288 and profit of (16 4) * 18 = 216. PART 2: Only men consume positive amounts. Max Q(p) (p c) = (30 p) (p 4) = 34 p p This has first-order condition 34 2p = 0 or p* = 17. But that price does not meet the condition where only men are consuming (p > 24), so it cannot be the optimum.

9 That is, FOC cannot hold for sales only to men in the range of prices (24 < p < 30) where only men purchase widgets. This indicates a boundary solution p = 24 as the optimal price for the monopolist in this range of outcomes. At p = 24, the monopolist sells 6 units to men and none to women, for a profit of 6 * (24 4) = 120, but this is not as large a profit as the price identified above, p* = 16. That is, with these particular demand functions, it is optimal to sell to both consumers with p* = 16 and total quantity 18. (c) Here, the goal should be to distribute quantity X to the men and women who have highest value for it. That means that at the margin, the last man and last woman who consume the good should have the same value for it. Thus, the optimal division among men and women satisfies p m (q m ) = p w (q w ) And q m + q w = X. This yields two equations in two unknowns, so it should be straightforward to identify a unique solution. First, 30 q m = 24 2q w OR q m = 6 + 2q w. This already indicates an element of the solution. The first six units produced should be distributed to men. Intuitively since six men value units at 24 or more per unit, but no woman values a unit at more than 24, the first six units should be distributed to men. Second, q m + q w = X OR q m = X q w. Assuming that total units produced X > 6, this means that we have two equations that characterize the optimal distribution of units: q m = 6 + 2q w q m = X q w Substituting the second equation into the first, we have q m = 6 + 2(X q m ) OR 3 q m = 6 + 2X OR q m = 2 + 2X / 3, and therefore q w = X/3 2, for X > 6. Note that with X = 18, the optimal quantity in (b), these formulas indicate that it is socially optimal to divide this quantity by giving 14 units to men and 4 units to women, exactly matching the result in (b).

10 (d) Now it s easiest to solve the problem by computing marginal revenues for each group separately. Since men have p m (q m ) = 30 q m, Revenue(men) 2 = 30 q m q m MR(men) = 30 2 q m. Since women have p w (q w ) = 24 2q w, Revenue(women) 2 = 24 q w 2q w MR(women) = 24 4 q w. With constant MC = 4, the optimal price discriminating scheme sets MR(men) = MR(women) = MC = 4, so q m = 13, q w = 5, implying p m = 17, p w = 14. This actually indicates an identical quantity to the non-discriminating outcome in part (b), but at the same time, an inefficient distribution (from the perspective of social surplus) since men get fewer units than in the outcome in (b) and in (c) when X=18. (e) It is simplest to repeat the analysis from (b) but with the new value for c. PART 1: Both men and women consume positive amounts: Max Q(p) (p c) = (42 3p/2) (p 20) = 72 p 3p 2 / Taking the derivative with respect to p yields the first-order condition 72 3p = 0, corresponding to optimum p* = 24. At p* = 24, men consume 6 units and women consume 0 for a total of 6. Total profit is given by Q(p* MC) = 6 (24 20) = 24. PART 2: Only men consume positive amounts. Max Q(p) (p c) = (30 p) (p 20) = 50 p p This has first-order condition 50 2p = 0 or p* = 25, corresponding to q = 5, all consumed by men, with profit 5 (30 25) = 25. Comparing these two possible optimal outcomes, the monopolist does best to set p * = 25 and q* = 5, with only men purchasing widgets. (f) From part (d), MR(men) = 30 2 q m. MR(women) = 24 4 q w.

11 With MC = 20, the optimal price discriminating scheme sets q m = 5 and q w = 1, so that MR = 20 for each group. The outcome is identical to that for men in (e) when price discrimination was not allowed, but is a clear improvement for women, who can now enjoy some consumer surplus since some women value widgets at more than their cost (20) of production Domestic Monopoly and Exports (a) The profit maximization problem is Max y (80 y) + z * 30 F (y + z) 2 /4 This produces two first-order conditions, one from differentiating with respect to y and one from differentiating with respect to z: 80 2y (y+z) / 2 = 0 30 (y+z) / 2 = 0. At an interior solution with both y* > 0 and z* > 0, both first-order conditions hold. The second equation identifies the value for Q = (y + z*) = 60. Then substituting this into the first equation, we can identify the specific values for y and z. That is, y* = 25 and z* = 35. (b) If y* = 0, then the first-order condition 30 (y+z) / 2 = 0 identifies the optimal value for z. Specifically z* = 60. Note that at y* = 0, z* = 60, MC = (y + z) / 2 = 30, which is equal to the marginal revenue on the world market. (c) If z* = 0, then the first-order condition 80 2y - (y+z) / 2 = 0 identifies the optimal value for y. Specifically y* = 32. Note that at y* = 32, z* = 0, MC = (y + z) / 2 = 16, while marginal revenue in the domestic market equals 80 2y* = 16, so these quantities equate MR and MC on the domestic market. (d) Profit = Total Revenue Total Cost In (a): y* = 25, z* = 35, and domestic price = 55. Total revenue = 25 * * 30 = Total cost = F + ( ) 2 /4 = F. In (b): y* = 0, z* = 60. Total revenue = 60 * 30 = Total cost = F + ( ) 2 /4 = F. In (c), y* = 32, z* = 0, and domestic price = 48. Total revenue = 32 * 64 = Total cost = F + (32) 2 /4 = F.

12 Thus, total profit = 1525 F in (a), 900 F in (b), and 1280 F in (c). Comparing (a) and (b), the firm produces the same total quantity in each case and thus has the same production costs in each case. However, the firm increases its total revenue and total profits by selling units on the domestic market until the point where MR(domestic) = 30, the world price. That is, the firm increases profits from (b) to (a) because it can sell units on the domestic market at prices greater than 30. Comparing (a) and (c), the firm sells more units on the domestic market in (c) and achieves a higher profit on the domestic market in (c). However, the firm gains in two ways by selling on the world market in (a). First, the firm prefers to sell units 26 to 32 on the world market, as it does in (a), because its marginal revenue is 30 per unit in the world market, but less than that in the domestic market. Second, the firm can achieve additional profits by producing units 33 to 60 and selling them on the world market at a price greater than marginal cost. (e) In this problem, the monopolist s profit function is simply equal to Domestic Revenue + World Revenue Cost of Production. Further, domestic revenue is a concave (quadratic) function of domestic quantity whereas world revenue is a linear function of world quantity. In economic terms, domestic revenue involves decreasing returns / decreasing marginal utility, whereas world revenue involves constant returns as a function of quantity. Ignoring the costs of production, these two revenue terms combine to produce a profit function that is identical in form to a quasilinear utility function with two goods for a consumer maximization problem. As in the consumer problem, the solution to the monopolist s problem takes the following form: 1. Produce in the domestic market so long as MR(domestic) > MR(world). 2. Once MR(domestic) = MR(world), then produce in the world market. The only distinction between the monopolist problem and the consumer problem with quasilinear utility is the stopping point. The consumer is limited by the budget constraint and the optimal solution corresponds to continual purchasing until the budget is exhausted. The monopolist is limited by the cost function and the optimal solution is determined by the point where MR = MC. Note that MR is (weakly) decreasing in quantity produced, while MC is increasing in quantity produced, so the point where MR = MC is indeed an optimum for profits. (f) As computed in (d), the firm s profit with y* = 25, z* = 35 is equal to 1525 F. Thus, the firm can operate profitably if F < Total cost is F and total quantity is 60, so ATC = (900 + F) / 60 = 15 + (F/60). (g) ATC is greater than 30 if F/60 > 15, or F > 900. Thus, both conditions hold if 900 < F < In this range of values, the firm may appear to be dumping its product on the world market because it is producing units and selling them at price below ATC. However, the real inefficiency here is that the firm is artificially reducing quantity on the domestic market,

13 where price = 55 is much greater than the price on the world market (and dumping is an artifact of that behavior) Learning by Doing (a) The first-order conditions for myopic monopoly profit maximization are given by MR = MC in each period. In Period 1, MR 1 = 48 2Q 1 and MC 1 = 24, so the myopic optimal quantity is given by Q 1m = 12. Then period 2 MC = MC 2 = 18. Setting MR 2 = MC 2 yields 48-2Q 2 = 18, so the myopic optimal quantity is given by Q 2m = 15. (b) Given Q 1 and Q 2, the monopolist has Period 1 Revenue: (48 - Q 1 ) Q 1 Period 1 Cost : 24 Q 1 Period 2 Revenue: (48 Q 2 ) Q 2 Period 1 Cost : (24 Q 1 / 2) Q 2 So the monopolist s total profit over two periods is given by π(q 1, Q 2 ) = (48 - Q 1 ) Q 1 + (48 Q 2 ) Q 2-24 Q 1 (24 Q 1 / 2) Q 2 The first-order conditions are given by π / Q 1 = 48-2Q Q 2 /2 = 0; (1) π / Q 2 = 48-2Q Q 1 /2 = 0. (2) Solving (2) for Q 2 gives Q 2 = 12 + Q 1 /4. Substituting this into (1) gives 24-2Q 1 + (12 + Q 1 /4)/2 = 0 OR Q 1 / 8 = 0 OR Q 1 = 16. Solving for Q 2 given Q 1 =16 gives Q 2 =16. Note that you could also solve (1) and (2) by inspection, observing that the symmetry of these conditions should produce an optimal pair of quantities where Q 1 = Q 2. A forward-looking monopolist increases Q 1 from the myopic value of 12 from (a) to account for the effect of Q 1 in reducing marginal costs in period 2. In addition, the monopolist also increases Q 2 from the myopic value of 15 from (a) as a result of increased production in period 1 and thus reduced marginal costs in period 2. (c) Setting 48 Q 1 = 24 yields Q 1 = 24. In turn, Q 1 = 24 reduces marginal cost from 24 to 12 in period 2.

14 Value ($) With MC = 12 in period 2, the planner directs the firm to choose quantity Q 2 satisfying 48 Q 2 = 12 or Q 2 = 36. (d) Figure 21.3 shows the demand curve and marginal cost curves in period 1, assuming quantity Q 1 = 32. Figure 21.3(a) Learning by Doing Values p(q) = 48 - Q MC 16 Price 8 Q1 = Total Value of Goods in Period 1: The total value of goods produced in period 1 is the area under the demand curve for quantities up to 32 and is equal to the sum of (1) the triangle with endpoints (0, 48), (0, 16), (32, 16); (2) the rectangle with endpoints (0,0), (0, 16), (32, 0), (32, 16). As a function of Q 1 the triangle has height Q 1 and base Q 1 so its area is half the product or 1/2 Q 1 2. As a function of Q 1, the rectangle has area Q 1 (48 -Q 1 ). Adding these two gives the value of goods produced in period 1: Q 1 (48 -Q 1 ) + 1/2 Q 1 2 or 48 Q 1-1/2 Q 1 2. Total Value of Goods in Period 2: Iterating this reasoning, the total value of goods produced in period 2 takes the similar form 48 Q 1-1/2 Q 1 2. Total Cost of Goods in Period 1: The total cost of goods produced in period 1 is simply Q 1 * MC 1 = 24 Q 1. Total Cost of Goods in Period 2: The total cost of goods produced in period 1 is simply Q 2 * MC 2 = (24 Q 1 / 2) Q 2. Q1

15 Adding values and subtracting costs in periods 1 and 2 gives the objective function for the social planner: Social Surplus(Q 1, Q 2 ) = 48 Q 1-1/2 Q Q 2-1/2 Q Q 1 (24 Q 1 / 2) Q 2 = 24 Q 1 1/2 Q Q 2 1/2 Q Q 1 Q 2 / 2 Differentiating with respect to Q 1 and Q 2 gives the first-order conditions for the two-period planner s problem: 24 - Q 1 + Q 2 / 2 = 0, (3) 24 - Q 2 + Q 1 / 2 = 0. (4) Solving for Q 1 in (3) yields Q 1 = 24 + Q 2 / 2. Substituting this equation in (4) yields 24 - Q Q 2 / 4 = 0, OR Q 2 = 48, which in turn identifies Q 1 = 48. Comparing the results of (c) and (d), the planner also produces too little in both periods by myopically setting price = MC in each period. Note that the benevolent social planner solves the following maximization problem: (e) Given any choice of Q 1, the marginal cost in the second period will be 24 Q 1 / 2. Thus, a one unit increase (say) in Q 1 will cause a one-half unit reduction in marginal cost in period 2, corresponding to a reduction in total costs in period 2 of Q 2 / 2. Combining the direct (immediate cost) and indirect (reduced future costs) of production in the first period yields an Adjusted Marginal Cost of 24 - Q 2 / 2. With this adjustment, the planner can be seen as choosing first-period quantity to set first-period price = adjusted marginal cost: 48 Q 1 = 24 - Q 2 / 2

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example A Detailed Price Discrimination Example Suppose that there are two different types of customers for a monopolist s product. Customers of type 1 have demand curves as follows. These demand curves include

More information

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8 Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets I. Perfect Competition Overview Characteristics and profit outlook. Effect

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. MBA 640 Survey of Microeconomics Fall 2006, Quiz 6 Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) A monopoly is best defined as a firm that

More information

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination

Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination 1 Examples on Monopoly and Third Degree Price Discrimination This hand out contains two different parts. In the first, there are examples concerning the profit maximizing strategy for a firm with market

More information

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY

CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY CHAPTER 10 MARKET POWER: MONOPOLY AND MONOPSONY EXERCISES 3. A monopolist firm faces a demand with constant elasticity of -.0. It has a constant marginal cost of $0 per unit and sets a price to maximize

More information

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall 2013. University of Chicago

Monopoly. E. Glen Weyl. Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall 2013. University of Chicago and Pricing Basics E. Glen Weyl University of Chicago Lecture 8 Price Theory and Market Design Fall 2013 Introduction and Pricing Basics Definition and sources of monopoly power Basic monopolistic incentive

More information

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY

N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics. Chapter 15. MONOPOLY N. Gregory Mankiw Principles of Economics Chapter 15. MONOPOLY Solutions to Problems and Applications 1. The following table shows revenue, costs, and profits, where quantities are in thousands, and total

More information

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers.

An increase in the number of students attending college. shifts to the left. An increase in the wage rate of refinery workers. 1. Which of the following would shift the demand curve for new textbooks to the right? a. A fall in the price of paper used in publishing texts. b. A fall in the price of equivalent used text books. c.

More information

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets

Chapter 6 Competitive Markets Chapter 6 Competitive Markets After reading Chapter 6, COMPETITIVE MARKETS, you should be able to: List and explain the characteristics of Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition Explain why a

More information

Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2

Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2 Monopoly: static and dynamic efficiency M.Motta, Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press, 2004; ch. 2 Economics of Competition and Regulation 2015 Maria Rosa Battaggion Perfect

More information

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS ECON 103, 2008-2 ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS Due the Week of June 23 Chapter 8 WRITE [4] Use the demand schedule that follows to calculate total revenue and marginal revenue at each quantity. Plot

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Chapter 11 Monopoly practice Davidson spring2007 MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) A monopoly industry is characterized by 1) A)

More information

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly WSG8 7/7/03 4:34 PM Page 113 8 Market Structure: Perfect Competition and Monopoly OVERVIEW One of the most important decisions made by a manager is how to price the firm s product. If the firm is a profit

More information

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position Chapter 27: Taxation 27.1: Introduction We consider the effect of taxation on some good on the market for that good. We ask the questions: who pays the tax? what effect does it have on the equilibrium

More information

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY

MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY MICROECONOMICS II PROBLEM SET III: MONOPOLY EXERCISE 1 Firstly, we analyze the equilibrium under the monopoly. The monopolist chooses the quantity that maximizes its profits; in particular, chooses the

More information

Final Exam 15 December 2006

Final Exam 15 December 2006 Eco 301 Name Final Exam 15 December 2006 120 points. Please write all answers in ink. You may use pencil and a straight edge to draw graphs. Allocate your time efficiently. Part 1 (10 points each) 1. As

More information

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS economicsentrance.weebly.com Basic Exercises Micro Economics AKG 09 Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS Budget Constraint... 4 Practice problems... 4 Answers... 4 Supply and Demand... 7 Practice Problems...

More information

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior

Monopoly and Monopsony Labor Market Behavior Monopoly and Monopsony abor Market Behavior 1 Introduction For the purposes of this handout, let s assume that firms operate in just two markets: the market for their product where they are a seller) and

More information

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization 2.1. Introduction Suppose that an economic relationship can be described by a real-valued

More information

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE

Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: Why do monopolies arise? Why is MR < P for a monopolist? How do monopolies choose their P and Q? How do monopolies affect society s well-being?

More information

Demand, Supply and Elasticity

Demand, Supply and Elasticity Demand, Supply and Elasticity CHAPTER 2 OUTLINE 2.1 Demand and Supply Definitions, Determinants and Disturbances 2.2 The Market Mechanism 2.3 Changes in Market Equilibrium 2.4 Elasticities of Supply and

More information

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts

LABOR UNIONS. Appendix. Key Concepts Appendix LABOR UNION Key Concepts Market Power in the Labor Market A labor union is an organized group of workers that aims to increase wages and influence other job conditions. Craft union a group of

More information

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits.

Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits. Equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition in the short-run. A firm is under equilibrium at that point where it maximizes its profits. Profit depends upon two factors Revenue Structure Cost Structure

More information

Basic Monopoly Theory

Basic Monopoly Theory Basic Theory E. Glen Weyl University of Chicago Lecture 9 Regular Section Elements of Economic Analysis II Fall 2011 Introduction Competitive model so far assumes price-taking: 1 If firm charged even little

More information

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline

Chapter 3. The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and Producer Surplus. Chapter Objectives. Chapter Outline Chapter 3 The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and roducer Surplus Chapter Objectives After reading this chapter you should be able to Understand that elasticity, the responsiveness of quantity to changes

More information

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity

Profit Maximization. 2. product homogeneity Perfectly Competitive Markets It is essentially a market in which there is enough competition that it doesn t make sense to identify your rivals. There are so many competitors that you cannot single out

More information

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost:

or, put slightly differently, the profit maximizing condition is for marginal revenue to equal marginal cost: Chapter 9 Lecture Notes 1 Economics 35: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes and Sample Questions Chapter 9: Profit Maximization Profit Maximization The basic assumption here is that firms are profit maximizing.

More information

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS

Chapter 15: Monopoly WHY MONOPOLIES ARISE HOW MONOPOLIES MAKE PRODUCTION AND PRICING DECISIONS Chapter 15: While a competitive firm is a taker, a monopoly firm is a maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. its product does not have close substitutes. The

More information

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q).

Thus MR(Q) = P (Q) Q P (Q 1) (Q 1) < P (Q) Q P (Q) (Q 1) = P (Q), since P (Q 1) > P (Q). A monopolist s marginal revenue is always less than or equal to the price of the good. Marginal revenue is the amount of revenue the firm receives for each additional unit of output. It is the difference

More information

Second degree price discrimination

Second degree price discrimination Bergals School of Economics Fall 1997/8 Tel Aviv University Second degree price discrimination Yossi Spiegel 1. Introduction Second degree price discrimination refers to cases where a firm does not have

More information

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market?

1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized market? Managerial Economics Study Questions With Solutions Monopoly and Price Disrcimination 1) If the government sets a price ceiling below the monopoly price, will this reduce deadweight loss in a monopolized

More information

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2

BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2 BEE2017 Intermediate Microeconomics 2 Dieter Balkenborg Sotiris Karkalakos Yiannis Vailakis Organisation Lectures Mon 14:00-15:00, STC/C Wed 12:00-13:00, STC/D Tutorials Mon 15:00-16:00, STC/106 (will

More information

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4

SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4 Sloan School of Management 15.010/15.011 Massachusetts Institute of Technology SOLUTIONS TO HOMEWORK SET #4 1. a. If the markets are open to free trade, the monopolist cannot keep the markets separated.

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron. Principles of Microeconomics Fall 2007, Quiz #6 Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question on the accompanying scantron. 1) A monopoly is

More information

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions We saw in the text that utility functions and indifference curves are different ways to represent a consumer s preferences. Calculus can

More information

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3 Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Jeffrey Parker Problem Set #6 Due: Wednesday, November 3 1. Cournot Duopoly. Bartels and Jaymes are two individuals who one day discover a stream

More information

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly

Learning Objectives. Chapter 6. Market Structures. Market Structures (cont.) The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly Chapter 6 The Two Extremes: Perfect Competition and Pure Monopoly Learning Objectives List the four characteristics of a perfectly competitive market. Describe how a perfect competitor makes the decision

More information

Solving Quadratic Equations

Solving Quadratic Equations 9.3 Solving Quadratic Equations by Using the Quadratic Formula 9.3 OBJECTIVES 1. Solve a quadratic equation by using the quadratic formula 2. Determine the nature of the solutions of a quadratic equation

More information

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing)

Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing) Lecture 6: Price discrimination II (Nonlinear Pricing) EC 105. Industrial Organization. Fall 2011 Matt Shum HSS, California Institute of Technology November 14, 2012 EC 105. Industrial Organization. Fall

More information

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run? Perfect Competition Questions Question 1 Suppose there is a perfectly competitive industry where all the firms are identical with identical cost curves. Furthermore, suppose that a representative firm

More information

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit

Figure: Computing Monopoly Profit Name: Date: 1. Most electric, gas, and water companies are examples of: A) unregulated monopolies. B) natural monopolies. C) restricted-input monopolies. D) sunk-cost monopolies. Use the following to answer

More information

EXAM TWO REVIEW: A. Explicit Cost vs. Implicit Cost and Accounting Costs vs. Economic Costs:

EXAM TWO REVIEW: A. Explicit Cost vs. Implicit Cost and Accounting Costs vs. Economic Costs: EXAM TWO REVIEW: A. Explicit Cost vs. Implicit Cost and Accounting Costs vs. Economic Costs: Economic Cost: the monetary value of all inputs used in a particular activity or enterprise over a given period.

More information

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization Dudley Cooke Trinity College Dublin Dudley Cooke (Trinity College Dublin) Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization 1 / 51 EC2040 Topic 3 - Multi-variable Calculus

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2010, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) (Refer Slide Time: 00:28) Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd ) We will continue our discussion

More information

Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations

Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations Linear Programming Notes V Problem Transformations 1 Introduction Any linear programming problem can be rewritten in either of two standard forms. In the first form, the objective is to maximize, the material

More information

Sample Problems. Practice Problems

Sample Problems. Practice Problems Lecture Notes Quadratic Word Problems page 1 Sample Problems 1. The sum of two numbers is 31, their di erence is 41. Find these numbers.. The product of two numbers is 640. Their di erence is 1. Find these

More information

First degree price discrimination ECON 171

First degree price discrimination ECON 171 First degree price discrimination Introduction Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases Buying in bulk usually offers a price discount these are price discrimination reflecting

More information

Profit Maximization. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Profit Maximization. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Profit Maximization PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 1 The Nature and Behavior of Firms A firm An association of individuals Firms Who have organized themselves

More information

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers

Midterm Exam #1 - Answers Page 1 of 9 Midterm Exam #1 Answers Instructions: Answer all questions directly on these sheets. Points for each part of each question are indicated, and there are 1 points total. Budget your time. 1.

More information

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young

Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young Chapter 9 Pricing and Output Decisions: i Perfect Competition and Monopoly M i l E i E i Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e By Paul Keat and Philip Young Pricing and

More information

Chapter 6. Linear Programming: The Simplex Method. Introduction to the Big M Method. Section 4 Maximization and Minimization with Problem Constraints

Chapter 6. Linear Programming: The Simplex Method. Introduction to the Big M Method. Section 4 Maximization and Minimization with Problem Constraints Chapter 6 Linear Programming: The Simplex Method Introduction to the Big M Method In this section, we will present a generalized version of the simplex method that t will solve both maximization i and

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1 Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1 What follows are some examples of different preference relations and their respective demand functions. In all the following examples, assume we have two goods x

More information

Employment and Pricing of Inputs

Employment and Pricing of Inputs Employment and Pricing of Inputs Previously we studied the factors that determine the output and price of goods. In chapters 16 and 17, we will focus on the factors that determine the employment level

More information

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets. Economies of scale and international trade In the models discussed so far, differences in prices across countries (the source of gains from trade) were attributed to differences in resources/technology.

More information

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4

Economics 2020a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 2010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4 Economics 00a / HBS 4010 / HKS API-111 FALL 010 Solutions to Practice Problems for Lectures 1 to 4 1.1. Quantity Discounts and the Budget Constraint (a) The only distinction between the budget line with

More information

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue 10 20 40

Marginal cost. Average cost. Marginal revenue 10 20 40 Economics 101 Fall 2011 Homework #6 Due: 12/13/2010 in lecture Directions: The homework will be collected in a box before the lecture. Please place your name, TA name and section number on top of the homework

More information

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9 Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9 print name on the line above as your signature INSTRUCTIONS: 1. This Exam #2 must be completed within the allocated time (i.e., between

More information

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice CHAPTER OUTLINE 4.1 Preferences Properties of Consumer Preferences Preference Maps 4.2 Utility Utility Function Ordinal Preference Utility and Indifference Curves Utility and

More information

Final Exam (Version 1) Answers

Final Exam (Version 1) Answers Final Exam Economics 101 Fall 2003 Wallace Final Exam (Version 1) Answers 1. The marginal revenue product equals A) total revenue divided by total product (output). B) marginal revenue divided by marginal

More information

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE

Chapter. Perfect Competition CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE Perfect Competition Chapter 10 CHAPTER IN PERSPECTIVE In Chapter 10 we study perfect competition, the market that arises when the demand for a product is large relative to the output of a single producer.

More information

Economics 431 Fall 2003 1st midterm Answer Key

Economics 431 Fall 2003 1st midterm Answer Key Economics 431 Fall 003 1st midterm Answer Key 1) (7 points) Consider an industry that consists of a large number of identical firms. In the long run competitive equilibrium, a firm s marginal cost must

More information

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly] ECON9 (Spring 0) & 350 (Tutorial ) Chapter Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly (Part ) Price competition with homogenous products: The Bertrand duopoly model [Simultaneous move price setting duopoly]

More information

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint.

c 2008 Je rey A. Miron We have described the constraints that a consumer faces, i.e., discussed the budget constraint. Lecture 2b: Utility c 2008 Je rey A. Miron Outline: 1. Introduction 2. Utility: A De nition 3. Monotonic Transformations 4. Cardinal Utility 5. Constructing a Utility Function 6. Examples of Utility Functions

More information

-1- Worked Solutions 5. Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12.

-1- Worked Solutions 5. Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12. -1- Worked Solutions 5 Lectures 9 and 10. Question Lecture 1. L9 2. L9 3. L9 4. L9 5. L9 6. L9 7. L9 8. L9 9. L9 10. L9 11. L9 12. L10 Unit 5 solutions Exercise 1 There may be practical difficulties in

More information

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}. Walrasian Demand Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 5, September 16 Outline 1 Walrasian Demand 2 Properties of Walrasian Demand 3 An Optimization Recipe 4 First and Second Order Conditions Definition Walrasian

More information

Sample Midterm Solutions

Sample Midterm Solutions Sample Midterm Solutions Instructions: Please answer both questions. You should show your working and calculations for each applicable problem. Correct answers without working will get you relatively few

More information

Pre Test Chapter 3. 8.. DVD players and DVDs are: A. complementary goods. B. substitute goods. C. independent goods. D. inferior goods.

Pre Test Chapter 3. 8.. DVD players and DVDs are: A. complementary goods. B. substitute goods. C. independent goods. D. inferior goods. 1. Graphically, the market demand curve is: A. steeper than any individual demand curve that is part of it. B. greater than the sum of the individual demand curves. C. the horizontal sum of individual

More information

NOTES FOR MICROECONOMICS. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Stern School of Business

NOTES FOR MICROECONOMICS. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Stern School of Business NOTES FOR MICROECONOMICS by Prof. Nicholas Economides Stern School of Business Spring 2015 Copyright Nicholas Economides MICROECONOMICS is about 1. Buying decisions of the individual 2. Buying and selling

More information

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas

Price Discrimination: Part 2. Sotiris Georganas Price Discrimination: Part 2 Sotiris Georganas 1 More pricing techniques We will look at some further pricing techniques... 1. Non-linear pricing (2nd degree price discrimination) 2. Bundling 2 Non-linear

More information

A public good is often defined to be a good that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable in consumption.

A public good is often defined to be a good that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable in consumption. Theory of Public Goods A public good is often defined to be a good that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable in consumption. The nonrivalrous property holds when use of a unit of the good by one consumer

More information

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK

SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK SUPPLY AND DEMAND : HOW MARKETS WORK Chapter 4 : The Market Forces of and and demand are the two words that economists use most often. and demand are the forces that make market economies work. Modern

More information

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics. Page 1 1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics. 2. Markets and Competition a. Market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. P. 66. b. These individuals

More information

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis

Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Economics 201 Fall 2010 Introduction to Economic Analysis Jeffrey Parker Problem Set #5 Solutions Instructions: This problem set is due in class on Wednesday, October 13. If you get stuck, you are encouraged

More information

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS 23-1 Briefly indicate the basic characteristics of pure competition, pure monopoly, monopolistic competition, and oligopoly. Under which of these market classifications

More information

Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!!

Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!! Practice Multiple Choice Questions Answers are bolded. Explanations to come soon!! For more, please visit: http://courses.missouristate.edu/reedolsen/courses/eco165/qeq.htm Market Equilibrium and Applications

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Chapter 11 Perfect Competition - Sample Questions MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Perfect competition is an industry with A) a

More information

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically

Long-Run Average Cost. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Long-Run Average Cost. Long-Run Average Cost. Economies of Scale & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically Slide 1 Slide 3 Econ 410: Micro Theory & Scope Minimizing Cost Mathematically Friday, November 9 th, 2007 Cost But, at some point, average costs for a firm will tend to increase. Why? Factory space and

More information

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences 1 Price Elasticity of Supply 1 14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen September 12, 2007 Lecture 4 Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences Outline 1. Chap 2: Elasticity -

More information

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy

Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy Chapter 7 Monopoly, Oligopoly and Strategy After reading Chapter 7, MONOPOLY, OLIGOPOLY AND STRATEGY, you should be able to: Define the characteristics of Monopoly and Oligopoly, and explain why the are

More information

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor. ECON 3310 Homework #4 - Solutions 1: Suppose the following indicates how many units of output y you can produce per hour with different levels of labor input (given your current factory capacity): PART

More information

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year. Answers To Chapter 2 Review Questions 1. Answer a. To be classified as in the labor force, an individual must be employed, actively seeking work, or waiting to be recalled from a layoff. However, those

More information

Do not open this exam until told to do so.

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Do not open this exam until told to do so. Department of Economics College of Social and Applied Human Sciences K. Annen, Winter 004 Final (Version ): Intermediate Microeconomics (ECON30) Solutions Final

More information

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition CHAPTER 12 MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition Chapter Summary Now that you understand the model of a perfectly competitive market, this chapter complicates

More information

Monopoly Quantity & Price Elasticity Welfare. Monopoly Chapter 24

Monopoly Quantity & Price Elasticity Welfare. Monopoly Chapter 24 Monopol monopl.gif (GIF Image, 289x289 pixels) Chapter 24 http://i4.photobu Motivating Questions What price and quantit does a monopol choose? What are the welfare effects of monopol? What are the effects

More information

COST THEORY. I What costs matter? A Opportunity Costs

COST THEORY. I What costs matter? A Opportunity Costs COST THEORY Cost theory is related to production theory, they are often used together. However, the question is how much to produce, as opposed to which inputs to use. That is, assume that we use production

More information

15.010/15.011: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS DECISIONS MIDTERM EXAM REVIEW SESSION OCTOBER 9, 2004

15.010/15.011: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS DECISIONS MIDTERM EXAM REVIEW SESSION OCTOBER 9, 2004 15.010/15.011: ECONOMIC ANALYSIS FOR BUSINESS DECISIONS MIDTERM EXAM REVIEW SESSION OCTOBER 9, 2004 PAGE MARKET DEFINITION, SUPPLY/DEMAND, ELASTICITIES 2 GOVERNMENT POLICIES 7 PRODUCTION/COST 13 NETWORK

More information

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm

How To Calculate Profit Maximization In A Competitive Dairy Firm Microeconomic FRQ s 2005 1. Bestmilk, a typical profit-maximizing dairy firm, is operating in a constant-cost, perfectly competitive industry that is in long-run equilibrium. a. Draw correctly-labeled

More information

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline

AP Microeconomics Chapter 12 Outline I. Learning Objectives In this chapter students will learn: A. The significance of resource pricing. B. How the marginal revenue productivity of a resource relates to a firm s demand for that resource.

More information

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly 1 R.E.Marks 1998 Oligopoly Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing In this section we consider how firms compete when there are few sellers an oligopolistic market (from the Greek). Small

More information

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets We have learned the production function and cost function, the question now is: how much to produce such that firm can maximize his profit? To solve this question,

More information

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it? Maximising onsumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it? This is a topic that has many powerful applications in understanding economic policy applications: (a) the impact

More information

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 14 - Monopoly Fall 2010 Herriges (ISU) Ch. 14 Monopoly Fall 2010 1 / 35 Outline 1 Monopolies What Monopolies Do 2 Profit Maximization for the Monopolist 3

More information

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics

Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Econ 101: Principles of Microeconomics Chapter 16 - Monopolistic Competition and Product Differentiation Fall 2010 Herriges (ISU) Ch. 16 Monopolistic Competition Fall 2010 1 / 18 Outline 1 What is Monopolistic

More information

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000. PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000. PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam. , Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes 00000 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam. SIGNED: PRINT NAME: Econ 201 Final Exam 1. For a profit-maximizing monopolist, a. MR

More information

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7. 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table.

AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7. 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table. AGEC 105 Spring 2016 Homework 7 1. Consider a monopolist that faces the demand curve given in the following table. a. Fill in the table by calculating total revenue and marginal revenue at each price.

More information

Econ Wizard User s Manual

Econ Wizard User s Manual 1 Econ Wizard User s Manual Kevin Binns Matt Friedrichsen Purpose: This program is intended to be used by students enrolled in introductory economics classes. The program is meant to help these students

More information

The Basics of Game Theory

The Basics of Game Theory Sloan School of Management 15.010/15.011 Massachusetts Institute of Technology RECITATION NOTES #7 The Basics of Game Theory Friday - November 5, 2004 OUTLINE OF TODAY S RECITATION 1. Game theory definitions:

More information

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Review of Fundamental Mathematics Review of Fundamental Mathematics As explained in the Preface and in Chapter 1 of your textbook, managerial economics applies microeconomic theory to business decision making. The decision-making tools

More information