Determinants of Defection: The Effect of Information Signals on Strategic Voting. Abstract

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Determinants of Defection: The Effect of Information Signals on Strategic Voting. Abstract"

Transcription

1 Determinants of Defection: The Effect of Information Signals on Strategic Voting Abstract While theoretical work on strategic voting emphasizes the importance of elite messages in persuading minor party supporters to abandon their first preference, few empirical studies have examined this relationship. I argue that while poll results certainly increase the likelihood of changing one s vote, explicit information signals can increase this probability even more. Furthermore, these effects will be moderated by the presence of a counter message and the sponsor of the explicit information signal. These hypotheses are tested with data generated from two experiments.

2 Minor party candidates are becoming a permanent fixture in elections in the United States. While minor party candidates have had a difficult time winning higher levels of office, their effects on the outcomes of elections have been felt across many contests, most notably the 2000 U.S. Presidential election. After the election, many scholars and pundits argued that Nader s presence in the race cost Al Gore the election, presumably the second preference of Nader supporters (Burden 2003). The 2000 election is not an anomaly: in 2002, Libertarian candidates may have cost Republican candidates the election in Senate races in South Dakota and Nevada and in gubernatorial races in Wisconsin and Oregon (Miller 2002), and in 2004, the Democratic candidate may have lost the senate seat in Alaska given the presence of the Green Party candidate (Tsong 2004) and the gubernatorial race in Washington due to the Libertarian party candidate (Modie 2004). The examples above illustrate the possibility that the presence of minor party candidates and the behaviour of their supporters may cost the Condorcet winner, or the alternative that beats all others in pair wise comparison, the election. However, if minor party supporters had switched their vote to their second preference in these contexts, then the Condorcet winner may have carried the election. With so many examples of when strategic voting could have made a difference, I examine the conditions under which minor party supporters abandon their first choice and vote for their second preference. Extant scholarship, primarily experimental based, has offered factors such as electoral history, poll results, ballot position, and signals from campaign spending (e.g., Felsenthal et al. 1988; Forsythe et al. 1993; Rapoport et al. 1991; Rietz, Myerson and Weber 1998). However, such studies generally provide poll results in the context of perfect information, which is rarely, if ever, present in elections. Furthermore, studies have not examined how more explicit campaign messages might impact the likelihood of defection, or how the presence of certain counter-messages might dampen such cues. There are three questions that this paper addresses. First, do information signals about 1

3 the competitive context of the race increase the likelihood that minor party supporters switch their vote to their second preference? 1 Second, does the presence of explicit information signals further increase this probability? Finally, what factors (message source and presence of countercoordination messages) condition an individual s receptivity to explicit information signals? These questions are addressed using two experimental designs in which subjects were presented with a context in which their first preference had little chance of winning, while their least preferred candidate was leading the race. However, if a certain percentage of subjects switched their vote, then the second preferred candidate could win. An experiment is beneficial to examining the factors that help subjects switch their vote in that the effects of different types of information can be isolated; thus, we know if subjects were exposed only to poll results or to poll results and an explicit information signal, such as a vote for your first preference is a vote for your least preferred candidate. Finally, experiments make it easier to test the conditional effects of the sponsor of the message and the presence of counter messages, which is often difficult to measure with data from campaigns. Answers to these questions have broad implications for the quality of representation in the American political system. As mentioned before, if the behaviour of minor party supporters results in the Condorcet winner losing real elections, it indicates a clear problem in the quality of representation. If we know about the factors that lead minor party supporters to switch their vote to their second preference, then we might be more likely to avoid these failures. Presumably, with knowledge of these factors, the major party candidate who is being harmed by the presence of the minor party, or interest groups with concerns similar to minor party supporters, will know how to appeal to this segment of the electorate. Past Work on Information Signals and Strategic Voting Strategic voting occurs when voters cast ballots for their second preference as opposed to their first preference because they do not want to cast a wasted vote. Such a context may occur 2

4 when voters perceive their first preference as having little to no chance of winning and when the race is close between their second and third preference. McKelvey and Ordeshook (1972) developed an expected utility model which demonstrates that if an individual s first preference has little chance of winning, the race is close between her second and third preference, and the difference in utility between them is sufficiently large, then she might be inclined to vote for her second preference. Many scholars have applied this model (or a variant of it) to multi-candidate elections across countries and across time, and have demonstrated strong support for it (e.g., Abramson et al. 1992, 2004; Bartels 1988; Black 1978; Blais and Nadeau 1996; Ordeshook and Zeng 1997). There is however one problem the probability that a voter casts a decisive vote will always be close to zero in a large electorate. Riker and Ordeshook (1968) acknowledged this problem, and argued that what matters is the voter s subjective sense of being decisive between pairs of candidates, which will be inflated on its own or due to messages being sent by elites (also see Aldrich 1993). In terms of the latter, elites send cues that the probability of an individual s vote being decisive is higher than it is objectively. Game theoretic models have resolved the irrationality of strategic voting by demonstrating that strategic voting occurs when voters take into account possible actions by other voters. In one class of games characterized by complete and perfect information and sequential voting (e.g. Farquharson 1969; Niemi and Frank 1981; Niou 2001; and Rapoport, Felsenthal and Maoz 1991), elites incite strategic voting by coordinating the behaviour of voters with the same preferences. In another class of games characterized by simultaneous games of incomplete information, elites play an indirect role in the publishing of poll results (e.g., Cox 1997; Fey 1997; Myerson and Weber 1993; Palfrey 1989). While all of the theoretical models posit some role for elites, few empirical studies of multicandidate elections have looked at the role elites play in inciting strategic voting. Some 3

5 exceptions include studies in the U.K., where scholars have presented qualitative evidence of efforts by the parties to woo minor party supporters (Evans, Curtice and Norris 1998), and have tested indirect indicators of elite messages (Fieldhouse, Pattie and Johnston 1996). Some work in the U.S. has also looked at the effects of elite cues to vote strategically in the form of candidate visits in the 1992, 1996, and 2000 elections (Burden 2005). The results of the study were mixed with respect to the effect of candidate visits. The vast majority of studies on the effectiveness of signals to vote strategically have been conducted by a group of scholars who use experimental methods (e.g., Felsenthal, Rapoport, and Maoz 1988; Forsythe et al. 1993, 1996; Rapoport, Felsenthal and Maoz 1991; Rietz, Myerson, and Weber 1998). 2 All of the studies use a context in which the Condorcet loser is the plurality winner. For example, one bloc of voters (A) has one candidate as their first preference, and this bloc is the largest in the electorate. At the same time, the first preference of voters in Bloc A is the least preferred candidate of voters in two other blocs (say B and C), which are individually smaller in size to bloc A, but collectively larger. In order to create an incentive to vote strategically, subjects are paid based on the outcome of the race. Thus, preferences are solely determined by the monetary compensation associated with each candidate winning the election. Typically, the electorate is small and the candidates are abstract, with letters for names. Thus, in order to ensure that the Condorcet loser does not win the election, voters in blocs B and C need to coordinate on a candidate. These scholars have found several factors that aid in coordination in plurality elections. 3 First, they have found that subjects learn to vote strategically through repeated elections. That is, when subjects learn that a Condorcet loser wins in Round 1, they are more likely to switch their vote in Round 2 (Felsenthal, Rapoport, and Maoz 1988; Rapoport, Felsenthal, and Maoz 1991; Forsythe et al. 1993, 1996). For example, Forsythe et al. (1993) found that in Round 1, the Condorcet loser won 2/3rds of the time, while in the next round, the Condorcet loser won less than half of the time. Second, Forsythe et al. (1993) also 4

6 tested the impact of pre-election polls and the results indicated that the Condorcet loser only won 33.3 percent of the time, compared to 87.5 percent of the time without polls. In later work, Forsythe et al. (1996) found that across several rounds of play, the Condorcet loser won 26 percent of the time without polls, and only 19.8 percent of the time with polls. 4 Rietz, Myerson and Weber (1998) tested for the effects of polls and added a campaign contribution signal, in which subjects were allowed to contribute money toward ads for candidates, which popped up on each subjects screen. They found that the poll and campaign contribution treatments had similar effects, with the Condorcet loser winning only percent of the time, a percentage identical to the poll condition in the Forsythe et al. study (1993). The overall level of strategic voting in these studies is quite similar, ranging from 32.7 percent in Rietz, Forsythe, and Myerson (1991) to percent in Forsythe et al. (1993). In a recent review of the experimental work, Rietz (forthcoming) argues that without any type of information, voters are often unable to coordinate on their second preference. His research cluster has found that the signals that help subjects to coordinate their votes vary in effectiveness, with repeated elections being the least effective. Non-binding pre-election polls and campaign contributions have similar effects and are much more effective than the former. Finally, the most effective method is institutional: a majority requirement with a runoff system. While these experiments have greatly expanded our understanding of the conditions under which citizens can coordinate on their second preference, there are some limitations and some areas for extension. First, while the studies are very high in internal validity, they are lower in external validity with respect to the electoral context. For example, existing studies are very abstract in nature, with letters for candidates instead of names, and rely on a small electorate, which is not usually the case in any U.S. election. Second, and related to the issue of external validity, the payoffs are generally structured so that subjects are only paid based on who wins the election. This feature is important since it allows the researchers to assign preferences to subjects 5

7 (based on the money received from the outcome of the election). There are two potential critiques to this set-up. First, this framework does not model any expressive benefit a minor party supporter might receive from voting for their first preference or a long-term goal of building a political party. 5 That is, only instrumental benefits are incorporated. Second, some might argue that preferences derived from monetary compensation are not a good reflection of preferences in real elections. There are also many areas for extensions. Existing studies have yet to test more explicit information signals that are often used in multi-candidate elections, such as voting for Ralph Nader helps elect George W. Bush 6 in the 2000 election or a vote for Anderson is a vote for Reagan 7 in the 1980 election. Second, we do not know whether the source of an explicit signal has any impact on an individual s receptivity to it. Finally, studies have also not considered the role of counter information on the part of the trailing candidate. In an election, we might expect that the minor party candidate would respond to coordination cues being sent by other elites. This question is far from idle the minor party candidates with enough support to tip the outcome of the election may also have the resources necessary to counter any information signals to switch one s vote that are sent by a major party. I overcome the artificiality of existing studies by placing my experiments in the context of a mock mayoral election. In one study, I also compare a purely instrumental payoff structure to one that incorporates both instrumental and expressive benefits. In a second study, subjects are all paid a flat fee for participation in the study. Instead of assigning preferences based on monetary compensation, subjects develop their own preferences based on candidates positions on an issue. Furthermore, in both studies, I examining explicit coordination signals, sponsored by different elites, and counter-coordination signals. Given that I only run one election at a time, I am unable to test for the effects of repeated elections. Since the results are similar across extant studies, the loss of information from being able to conduct repeated elections is justified. 6

8 Types of Coordination Cues Past experimental studies of strategic voting find that without information on the competitive context of the race, few minor party supporters switch their vote, resulting in the Condorcet loser winning the election (e.g., Felsenthal et al. 1988; Rapoport et al. 1991; Forsythe et al. 1993, 1996). Minor party supporters might be led to abandon their first preference from tracking polls alone. Having learned that their first preference has no chance of winning, while the race is close between the major party candidates, they might be inclined to switch their vote, in the hope of ensuring at least their second best outcome. However, minor party supporters generally do not know whether others like them have the same second preference. 8 Given this uncertainty, additional information might be required to induce strategic voting, which could come in the form of messages being sent by elites, such as the other major party candidate, the media, or interest groups. 9 These elites might send a cue that other minor party supporters have a similar preference profile and that if they all coordinate on candidate B, they can ensure their second best outcome. 10 To summarize, we should find higher levels of strategic voting among those who are exposed to messages about the competitive context of the race, and this effect should be more pronounced among those who are exposed to explicit strategic voting messages, compared to those who are only exposed to tracking polls. Conditional Factors One factor that might affect the likelihood of voting strategically is the response by the minor party candidate. As Cox (1997) points out, minor party candidates might try to counter the instrumental arguments of the major party candidate by focusing on the long-term goals of the minor party. Furthermore, they might emphasize one s duty to vote for their first preference. Studies on persuasion find that individuals are receptive to one-sided persuasive messages; whereas they will be less likely to incorporate a message if an argument against that message is 7

9 presented (e.g., Lau Smith and Fiske 1991; Petty and Cacioppo 1986; Zaller 1992). Thus, the presence of a counter-strategic voting message might render the explicit message ineffective. The impact of explicit messages to change one s vote might also vary depending on the sponsor of the cue. Many studies of persuasion and priming find that individuals are more likely to incorporate messages when they trust the sender of the message, especially in low information and motivation environments (e.g., Chaiken 1980; Miller and Krosnick 2000; Petty and Cacioppo 1986). Given this literature, we might expect that minor party supporters will be more likely to incorporate and use messages that are sponsored by interest groups that share their preferences, compared to messages sponsored by the major party candidate that is trying to appeal to them. They might view some interest groups as having credibility over the issues they care about (Ansolabehere and Iyengar 1994; Iyengar and Valentino 1999; Petrocik 1996), while they distrust the motives of the major party candidate. 11 To briefly summarize, the hypotheses that are tested with the data generated from the experiments are as follows: H1: Exposure to polling results will increase the likelihood of voting for one s second preference. H2: Exposure to explicit information signals will further increase the likelihood of voting for one s second preference. H3: Exposure to counter-information signals will depress the likelihood of voting for one s second preference. H4: Signals sponsored by credible interest groups will be more effective than candidate sponsored signals. Study 1 Method Participants 8

10 289 student subjects were recruited for the study from universities in California, North Carolina and Pennsylvania. Participants were recruited with flyers and were compensated monetarily for participating in the study. Given that the format of the study was the same across the universities, the data was pooled in the analyses that follow. With this pooled data, the demographic breakdown of the student sample is as follows: 55.7 percent male, 71.3 percent white, 40.8 percent Democrat, 22.8 percent Republican; and, a mean political information score of 3.5 out of 6 points. Context of the Study Subjects took part in a mock three-candidate mayoral election in Allentown, Pennsylvania. They were led to believe that it was a special mayoral election that took place a few months before the study. The subjects were assigned preferences over the three candidates, and all subjects were given the same preference profile, to ensure an identical pool of minor party supporters. 14 However, the subjects read that there were six different types of voters in the electorate, representing the six possible strict preference orderings over the three candidates. The competitive context of the race was also held constant (among the treated groups): David Howells (the least preferred candidate) was the plurality winner, while Lou Ervin (the first preference) had no chance of winning. Thomas Burke (the second preference) narrowly trailed Howells. Two different forms of compensation were used in the study. In one version, subjects were compensated based on the outcome of the race, receiving $15 if Ervin won (their first preference), $10 if Burke won (their second preference), and $5 if Howells won (their third preference). In a second version, an expressive component was built in the payoff structure. Thus, subjects were compensated based on the outcome of the election, to capture instrumental considerations of strategic voting, and for whom they voted, to capture an expressive benefit of voting for one s favourite candidate (e.g., Carter and Guerette 1992; Fischer 1996; Hirschman 9

11 1970; Schuessler 2000). A subject was compensated the highest amount if he or she voted for Ervin and he won ($15). If Burke won the election, and the subject voted for Ervin, then she received 10 dollars, while if she voted for Burke, she received 9 dollars. If Howells won, and she voted for Ervin, she received 5 dollars, while if she voted for Burke, she received 3 dollars. Given the competitive context, the highest actual payoff, for either compensation scheme, was 10 dollars. Overall, we should find that those in the former compensation set-up are more likely to switch their vote. Finally, to simulate behaviour in a large electorate, subjects were told that the outcome would be determined by adding the votes they cast with the results in Allentown and the votes cast in other classes that took part in the study. Procedure Upon arrival, subjects were told that they would be participating in a mock election for a mayoral race that took place in Allentown, Pennsylvania. They were told that the purpose of the study was to see what types of information people consider in elections. The subjects then filled out a short pre-survey, which included a battery of demographic and political information questions. Subjects were then given a packet, which contained their preference profile, compensation table, and information about the campaign. 15 Subjects then voted and completed a post-survey, which included questions about their perceptions of who would win, and their levels of efficacy and trust. After the post-test, the subjects were debriefed and compensated. Treatment To test the hypotheses related to the type of message and the conditional effects of the sponsor and counter messages, subjects were exposed to one of four types of information (no information, poll information, poll and explicit information signal, and the latter plus a counter signal from the trailing candidate), with the explicit message delivered by either candidate Burke or an interest group. Combining these components, subjects were randomly assigned to one of 10

12 the six groups (control, poll, candidate signal (CIS), interest group signal (IGS), candidate counter signal (CCIS), and interest group counter signal (CIGS). The treatment was embedded in the articles section of the campaign packet. Subjects in the control group read a neutral article about projected levels of turnout in the election and an article about the importance of revitalizing downtown Allentown, while those in the poll treatment read the first neutral article, and an article with a tracking poll in which they learned that Ervin was trailing in the polls with 15 percent support, while Burke had 40 percent support, and Howells was leading with 45 percent support. Those in the two explicit signal treatments read the first neutral article, the poll article, and an article about an advertisement sponsored by either Thomas Burke (CCC), or Good Schools Pennsylvania (ICC), in which the ad says that a vote for Ervin is a vote for Howells and that if all Ervin supporters switch their vote, they can ensure that Howells does not win. Finally, the two counter groups read the neutral article, the poll results, the explicit cue, from Burke or Good Schools Pennsylvania, and an article about Lou Ervin s response to the ad. The article quotes Ervin as arguing that the ad encourages his supporters to go against one of the most cherished acts in a democracy voting for anyone other than one s first preference goes against one s duty as a citizen. To refresh, we should find that those who received polling information, or all treated groups, exhibit higher levels of voting for their second preference, Burke, compared to those in the control group (H1). Furthermore, we should find that those in the explicit signal conditions have a higher level of voting for Burke compared to those in the poll condition (H2), with the interest group sponsored cue being more effective than the candidate sponsored one (H4). Finally, if we compare the counter conditions to the explicit signal conditions, we should find lower levels of voting for Burke in the former (H3). Results 11

13 Before turning to the differences across treatments, there is a simple manipulation check that was conducted. If subjects in the treated groups paid attention to the articles, we should find that the percentage of subjects who think their first preference will win will be significantly lower among the treated groups compared to the control group, since the treated groups read that Ervin had 15 percent support in the polls. As expected, all of the treated groups were less likely to think that their first preference would win compared to the control group, according to a series of difference in proportions tests. The overall percentage who voted for their second preference was 50.5 percent. Figure 1 presents the percentage of subjects who voted for Burke by treatment group. As expected, we find support for H1, in that only about 6 percent of those in the control group voted for Candidate Burke, while the percentage ranged from 47.9 percent to 79.2 percent across the treated groups, and these differences were significant for each comparison group according to difference in proportions tests. [Figure 1 about here] As expected, a higher percentage of subjects voted for Burke in the candidate information signal (CIS), 64 percent, and the interest group signal, 79.2 percent, compared to those in the poll group (47.9 percent), and these differences were significant. Furthermore, the percentage is also significantly higher among those exposed to the interest group cue verses the candidate cue. Finally, while the addition of a counter coordination cue to the candidate cue depressed the percentage voting for Burke, these differences were not statistically significant. However, those who received the counter signal to the interest group signal were significantly less likely to vote for Burke. Overall, it appears that there is some initial support for the arguments that explicit information signals play an important roll in enhancing the likelihood of switching one s vote, above poll results only, especially when sent by an interest group. However, there is mixed support for the argument that counter messages should depress the likelihood of switching one s vote to their second preference. 12

14 While the difference in proportions test indicate some support for the hypotheses, they only indicate whether there were significant differences across treated and control groups. Since each treated group received poll results, the previous results can not tell us the independent effect of explicit information signals or counter information signals. In order to test for these independent effects, a multivariate test is needed. Thus, to separate the effects of poll results, we need to create a dummy variable in which all of those exposed to poll results (all treated groups) are coded as one and zero otherwise (the control group). Next, we need to create dummy variables for those exposed to the explicit information signals. First, I created a general explicit information signal dummy variable, which combines those who received the candidate or interest group signal (CIS, IGS, CCIS and CIGS), and then created separate measures for the candidate information signal and interest group signal. Finally, I created a dummy variable for all of those who received a counter information signal (CCIS and CIGS), and separated those who received a counter message by whether the explicit cue was sponsored by the candidate or interest group. The dependent variable is whether the subject voted for Burke, their second preference, which is coded as 1 if they did and zero otherwise. Given that the dependent variable is dichotomous, I ran probit analysis. In addition to the treatment dummy variables (the control serves as the baseline), a dummy variable was included for whether the subject was compensated based on the outcome only, and for whether the respondent is male. 16 The latter variable, male, is included because there was a slight over-representation of males in some groups compared to others, according to difference in proportion tests. Table 1 presents the results. Model 1 presents the results for a model that includes the control variables, as well as the dummy variables for poll results, explicit information signals, and counter signals. The first column presents the coefficients and standard errors, while the second column presents the first differences. As expected, the poll treatment is significant and in the expected direction; thus, learning of the competitive context of the race made subjects more likely 13

15 to vote for Burke than the control group, in support of H1. Furthermore, the explicit information signal dummy variable is also significant and positive, in support of H2. Thus, subjects receiving an explicit signal became even more likely to switch their vote to their second preference. Finally, as expected (H4), the counter information signal had a negative effect, decreasing the likelihood of switching one s vote. With respect to the control variables, the compensate variable is positive and significant, as is the male dummy variable. Thus, men and those who were paid based on the outcome only were more likely to switch to their second preference. The model also performs well with percent correctly predicted. [Table 1 about here] Since the probit coefficients are not directly interpretable, I calculate the first differences using Clarify (King, Tomz, and Wittenberg 2000; Tomz, Wittenberg, and King 2001). All of the treatment dummies were held at the minimum, along with the control variables. Thus, the baseline subject is a female student who received the 2 nd form of compensation. Exposure to the poll results increased the likelihood of voting for Burke by 32.5 percent. To get the effect of the explicit information signal, the poll results were set at their max, since this group was exposed to the poll results. The change in the probability of voting for Burke among this group was 24.5 percent. Thus, having been exposed to the explicit signal further increased the probability of voting for one s second preference. The effect for those in the counter group was a decrease in the probability of voting for Burke by 21.3 percent. Thus, the addition of a counter message rendered the explicit signal much less effective. One feature of the first Model is that it does not differentiate the sponsor of the explicit signal; thus, in Model 2, separate dummy variables are included for the sponsor of each message. Here, we find that all of the manipulation dummy variables are significant, with the exception of the candidate counter signal. In order to see whether messages sponsored by interest groups are more effective than candidate signals, we need to look at the first differences. As expected, we 14

16 find that the change in the probability of voting for Burke is only 15.5 percent among those exposed to the candidate information signal, but much higher, 33.1 percent, among those exposed to the interest group signal. In this model, the poll results increase the probability of switching one s vote by 32.9 percent, while the counter interest group signal decreases the probability by 30.3 percent. Overall, the results support the four hypotheses. Study 2 For study 2, the context of the study was the same, a mock-mayoral election in Allentown Pennsylvania with Lou Ervin, Thomas Burke, and David Howells. The treatment articles were almost identical and were only slightly modified to shorten the content. 17 However, a few differences were introduced in order to test the robustness of the results. First, a non-student sample was used. Second, a different form of compensation is employed. Some may argue that the compensation in the first study is not realistic, given that voters do not receive monetary compensation based on the outcome of elections. To address this concern in this second study, all subjects were paid the same amount, regardless of the outcome of the election. This should prove a more difficult test for the treatments. Finally, rather than assign preferences to subjects, they were asked to rank order their preference over the three candidates, after being presented with their positions on a school voucher program. A computer program ensured that the first preference of subjects was presented as the trailing candidate. The next sections detail the context of the study, the procedures, the treatment, and the results. Participants and Design Study 2 was a computer-based study that ran from late August to early September Research subjects were adults recruited from three populations: residents of two Northern California towns and employees of a large university in Northern California. 18 The 417 adult participants were compensated $30 for their time. The average reported age of the respondents was 46; 63.1 percent were female; the modal subject (33 percent) indicated having a college 15

17 degree; 78.7 percent identified as white; and, with respect to partisanship, 24.0 percent identified as Republican, 46.8 percent as Democrat, and the remainder as Independent or Other. Subjects were randomly assigned to one of the six treatment groups. Tests of whether subjects were evenly distributed across groups, according to demographic and attitudinal variables (party identification, ideology, political sophistication, gender, education, home ownership, income and race) revealed that there was a slight over-representation of females and home owners in some of the groups. Procedures Participants reported to the experimental lab in order to participate in a study about current events and opinions. Once seated, individually, in front of a computer terminal, a research assistant initiated the program and the participant was randomly assigned to either the control group or one of the six treatment groups. The study began with questions on basic demographics, opinions on school vouchers, and party identification. The subjects were then presented with the candidates positions on a scale of favour to oppose with respect to a voucher program. After being presented with the candidates positions, the subjects rank ordered their preferences over the three candidates. They then proceeded to read the newspaper articles associated with their assigned control or treatment group. The computer program assigned their first preference as the trailing candidate and their least preferred candidate as the leading candidate in the treatment articles. After reading the articles, the subjects voted in the election and were asked similar questions to the previous study. Results The same manipulation check question was asked in Study 2. As in study 1, all of the treated groups were less likely to think that their first preference would win compared to the control group, according to a series of difference in proportions tests. The overall percentage who voted for their second preference was 24.5 percent. Figure 2 presents the percentage of subjects who voted for their second preference by treatment group. As expected, we find support 16

18 for H1, in that only about 11.6 percent of those in the control group voted for their second preference, while the percentage ranged from 18.9 percent to 41.4 percent across the treated groups. According to difference in proportions tests, the control group was significantly less likely to vote for their second preference compared to all of the treated groups, with the exception of the poll treatment group, which was just outside of traditional significance levels (p<.131). As expected, the proportion voting for their second preference is lower for this study, since compensation was not at all based on the outcome of the election. [Figure 2 about here] As expected, a higher percentage of subjects voted for their second preference in the candidate information signal (CIS), 29.9 percent, and the interest group signal, 41.4 percent, compared to those in the poll group (18.8 percent), and these differences were significant. As with the previous study, the percentage voting for their second preference is significantly higher among those exposed to the interest group cue verses those exposed to the candidate cue. The results are also similar with respect to those in the counter information groups. There are no significant differences between the candidate information signal and counter candidate information signal groups. However, those exposed to the counter interest group article voted for their second preference at a lower proportion, 21.9 percent, compared to those exposed to the interest group signal. Since there were some demographic differences across treated and control groups, and to test the independent effects of the different types of signals, we turn to multivariate tests. The same models were used as in the previous analysis, with the exception of the control variables. Home ownership and gender are included as controls since subjects were not evenly distributed according to these characteristics. The results for Model 1, which does not differentiate by the sponsor of the message, are presented in the first two columns of Table 2. As with Study 1, the explicit information signal 17

19 and counter signal are significant, with the former increasing and the latter decreasing the likelihood of voting for one s second preference. However, receiving poll information is just outside of traditional significant levels (p<.123, one-tailed). It is somewhat surprising that poll results have weaker effects in this study. However, given that individuals chose their own candidates and were not paid based on the outcome, it may have taken more of a push to get subjects to switch their vote to their second preference. According to the substantive effects, subjects exposed to poll information became 7.9 percent more likely to switch their vote, with the effect more pronounced among those exposed to explicit signals to switch their vote, 14.8 percent. Finally, messages to stick with one s first preference again decreased the probability of voting for one s second preference, by 10.9 percent. [Table 2 about here] Model 2 presents the results taking into account the sponsor of the message. The results for the poll information dummy variable are the same as in Model 1. As with Study 1, both the candidate and interest group explicit information signals are significant and positive, while the counter interest group signal is significant and negative. Furthermore, the effect of the interest group signal is again larger than the effect of the candidate information signal. The probability of voting for one s second preferences increases by 10.6 percent among those exposed to the candidate signal, and by 21.2 percent among those exposed to the interest group one. Finally, the counter interest group signal again almost washes away the effect of the message to switch one s vote, decreasing the probability of voting for one s second preference by 18.3 percent. 19 Discussion and Conclusions Overall, the results of the study have important implications for the quality of representation in the U.S. As was discussed before, sometimes failures in coordination among minor party supporters can result in the Condorcet winner losing real elections, a clear problem in the quality of representation. The findings of this study shed light on some factors that might 18

20 help or hinder minor party supporters from switching to their second preference, in a context in which they have the same second preference. First, as expected, and consistent with previous work, all subjects were more likely to switch their vote when given some information about the competitive context of the race. Second, explicit information signals added to poll results were often more effective than poll results alone in helping minor party supporters switch to their second preference. The effect for explicit information signals was more pronounced when the message was sponsored by an interest group than by a candidate. However, the presence of a counter cue often dampened the effect of explicit information signals. One striking finding was that subjects exposed to explicit coordination cues in addition to poll results were more likely to switch their vote compared to those only exposed to poll results. This result obtained with both the student sample and adult non-student sample. These findings support the argument that sometimes more information is needed for minor party supporters to switch to their second preference. However, the sponsor of the message may condition this relationship, with the effects being more pronounced in both studies with the interest group message. Another important feature of the results is that they were consistent across the two studies, even though the samples consisted of very different populations, students verses nonstudent adults, and the differences in compensation. The students were paid based on the outcome of the election and were assigned preferences, while the adults received a flat fee for participation and were allowed to determine their own preference rankings. Granted, the levels of defection for each treated group were higher in the student study, but the pattern of the results was the same across the two. In relation to strategies in the empirical world, the results suggest that explicit signals can play an important role in increasing the likelihood of defection among minor party supporters, with the effect likely most pronounced if the message is sent by an interest group aligned with the 19

21 minor party. In the 2000 election, only the National Abortion Rights Action League aired an explicit advertisement warning that a vote for Nader is a vote for Bush, and it only aired 47 times (Campaign Media Analysis Group). These results suggest that if other interest groups that Nader supporters perceived as credible had made similar appeals, more Nader supporters may have voted for Gore. Another important finding was that the presence of a counter message by the minor party candidate, Lou Ervin, did depress the effect of the explicit information signal in both studies, particularly among those who received the interest group information signal. In appealing to strategic voting as a violation of one s civic duty, the explicit information signals to switch one s vote were rendered less effective. This finding can have implications for understanding the circumstances under which minor parties might prove successful in the American political system. While minor parties will likely have few resources to mount a counter-campaign in presidential elections compared to the major party candidates, they might have more resources in other contests, which would enable them to counter the claims by the major parties. While the study enhances our knowledge of the effectiveness of different types of information signals, it also leads to more questions for future research. First, how might counter cues from the other major party fare? Second, how would more implicit information signals fare, compared to more explicit signals? Most of the appeals to Nader supporters sponsored by the DNC and Gore campaign in the 2000 election were not explicit, but implicit in nature, highlighting Bush s weaknesses on the environment. Finally, does the likelihood of defection depend on the nature of the issue? For example, are individuals more likely to defect on economic issues verses moral issues? 20

22 References Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich, Phil Paolino, David W. Rhode Sophisticated Voting in the 1988 Presidential Primaries. American Political Science Review 86: Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich, Matthew Diamond, Abraham Diskin, Renan Levine, and Thomas J. Scotto Strategic Abandonment or Sincerely Second Best? The 1999 Israeli Prime Ministerial Election. Journal of Politics 66: Aldrich, John H Rational Choice and Turnout. American Journal of Political Science 37: Ansolabehere, Stephen and Shanto Iyengar Riding the Wave and Claiming Ownership over Issues: The Joint Effects of Advertising and News Coverage in Campaigns. Public Opinion Quarterly 58: Bartels, Larry M Presidential Primaries and the Dynamics of Public Choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Black, J.H The Multicandidate Calculus of Voting: Applications to Canadian Federal Elections. American Journal of Political Science 22: Blais, Andre and Richard Nadeau Measuring Strategic Voting: A Two-Step Procedure. Electoral Studies 15: Burden, Barry C Minor Parties and Strategic Voting in Recent U.S. Presidential Elections. Electoral Studies 24: Burden, Barry C Minor Parties in the 2000 Presidential Election. In Models of Voting in Presidential Elections: The 2000 Election, ed. Herbert F. Weisberg and Clyde Wilcox. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Carter, John R. and Stephen D. Guerette An Experimental Study of Expressive Voting. Public Choice 73:

23 Chaiken, Shelly Heuristic versus Systematic Information Processing and the Use of Source versus Message Cues in Persuasion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 39: Cooper, Russell, Douglas V. DeJong, Robert Forsythe, and Thomas Ross Communication in Battle of the Sexes Game: Some Experimental Results. The Rand Journal of Economics 20: Cooper, Russell, Douglas V. DeJong, Robert Forsythe, and Thomas Ross Communication in Coordination Games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: Cox, Gary W Making Votes Count. Strategic Coordination in the World s Electoral Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Evans, Geoffrey, John Curtice and Pippa Norris New Labour, New Tactical Voting? The Causes and Consequences of Tactical Voting in the 1997 British General Election. In Denver, David, Justin Fisher, Philip Cowley and Charles Pattie, eds. Elections and Parties Review. London: Frank Cass. Farquharson, Robin Theory of Voting. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Felsenthal, D.S., A Rapoport A, and Z Maoz Tacit Cooperation in Three Alternative Noncooperative Voting Games: A new Model of Sophisticated Behaviour under the Plurality Procedure. Electoral Studies 7: Fey, Mark Stability and Coordination in Duverger s Law: A Formal Model of Preelection Polls and Strategic Voting. American Political Science Review 91: Fieldhouse, E.A., C.J. Pattie and R.J. Johnston Tactical Voting and Party Constituency Campaigning at the 1992 General Election in England. British Journal of Political Science 26: Fischer, A.J A Further Experimental Study of Expressive Voting. Public Choice 88:

24 Fisher, Stephen D. and David P. Myatt Strategic Voting Experiments. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, CA. Forsythe, Robert, Roger B. Myerson, Thomas A. Rietz, and Robert J. Weber An Experiment on Coordination in Multicandidate Elections: The Importance of Polls and Election Histories. Social Choice and Welfare 10: Forsythe, Robert, Roger B. Myerson, Thomas A. Rietz, and Robert J. Weber An Experimental Study of Voting Rules and Polls in Three-Candidate Elections. International Journal of Game Theory 25: Gerber, E.R., R.B. Morton and T.A. Rietz Minority Representation in Multi-member Districts. American Political Science Review 92: Gomez, Brad T., and J. Matthew Wilson Political sophistication and economic voting in the American electorate: A theory of heterogeneous attribution. American Journal of Political Science 4: Hirschman, Albert O Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Iyengar, S. and N. Valentino Who Says What? Source Credibility as a Mediator of Campaign Advertising. In Lupia, A., M. McCubbins, and S. Popkin, Eds. Elements of Reason. New York: Cambridge University Press. King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation. American Journal of Political Science Vol. 44(2): Lau, Richard R., Richard A. Smith and Susan T. Fiske Political Beliefs, Policy Interpretations, and Political Persuasion. Journal of Politics 53: Lupia, Arthur and Mathew McCubbins The Democratic Dilemma. Cambridge; Cambridge University Press. 23

25 McKelvey, Richard D. and Peter C. Ordeshook A General Theory of the Calculus of Voting. In Mathematical Applications in Political Science, Vol. 6, ed. James F. Herndon and Joseph L. Bernd. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press. Miller, Joanne M. and Jon A. Krosnick News Media Impact on the Ingredients of Presidential Evaluations: Politically Knowledgeable Citizens are Guided by a Trusted Source. American Journal of Political Science 44: Miller, John J. 2002, November 20. What did the GOP do to deserve this? Raleigh News and Observer, Section A, page 19. Modie, Neil. 2004, December 14. Libertarian May Have Helped Rossi, Experts Agree. The Seattle Post-Intelligencer, Section B, page 1. Retrieved June 29, 2005, from Myerson, Roger. and Robert. Weber A Theory of Voting Equilibria. American Political Science Review 87: Niemi, Richard G. and Arthur Q. Frank Sophisticated Voting Under the Plurality Procedure. In Political Equilibrium, ed. Peter C. Ordeshook and Kenneth A. Shepsle. Kluwer. Nijhoff Publishing. Niou, Emerson Strategic Voting Under Plurality and Runoff Rules. Journal of Theoretical Politics 13: Ordeshook, Peter C. and Langche Zeng Rational Voters and Strategic Voting: Evidence from the 1986, 1980, and 1992 Elections. Journal of Theoretical Politics 9: Palfrey, T.R A Mathematical Proof of Duverger s Law. In P.C. Ordeshook, ed. Models of Strategic Choice in Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan. Petrocik, John R Issue Ownership in Presidential Elections with a 1980 Case Study. American Journal of Political Science 40:

Chapter 2 Voting Strategically in Canada and Britain

Chapter 2 Voting Strategically in Canada and Britain Chapter Voting Strategically in Canada and Britain André Blais, Eugénie Dostie-Goulet, and Marc André Bodet The objective of this paper is to ascertain the level of strategic voting in Canada and Britain

More information

Jon A. Krosnick and LinChiat Chang, Ohio State University. April, 2001. Introduction

Jon A. Krosnick and LinChiat Chang, Ohio State University. April, 2001. Introduction A Comparison of the Random Digit Dialing Telephone Survey Methodology with Internet Survey Methodology as Implemented by Knowledge Networks and Harris Interactive Jon A. Krosnick and LinChiat Chang, Ohio

More information

Sorting Out Mechanical and Psychological Effects in Candidate Elections: An Appraisal with Experimental Data i

Sorting Out Mechanical and Psychological Effects in Candidate Elections: An Appraisal with Experimental Data i Sorting Out Mechanical and Psychological Effects in Candidate Elections: An Appraisal with Experimental Data i Karine VAN DER STRAETEN (Toulouse School of Economics, France) Nicolas SAUGER (Sciences Po

More information

State Constitutional Reform and Related Issues

State Constitutional Reform and Related Issues California Opinion Index A digest summarizing California voter opinions about State Constitutional Reform and Related Issues October 2009 Findings in Brief By a 51% to 38% margin voters believe that fundamental

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

DUI: Long Ago, Far Away, No Effect

DUI: Long Ago, Far Away, No Effect ABC NEWS POLL: TRACKING #18 - EMBARGOED FOR RELEASE AFTER 9 a.m. Sunday, Nov. 5, 2000 DUI: Long Ago, Far Away, No Effect When it comes to a 24-year-old drunken driving arrest, hardly anyone gives a hoot.

More information

SOUTH CAROLINA: TRUMP LEADS, CARSON 2 nd

SOUTH CAROLINA: TRUMP LEADS, CARSON 2 nd Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Tuesday, August 25, 2015 Contact: PATRICK MURRAY

More information

The Youth Vote in 2012 CIRCLE Staff May 10, 2013

The Youth Vote in 2012 CIRCLE Staff May 10, 2013 The Youth Vote in 2012 CIRCLE Staff May 10, 2013 In the 2012 elections, young voters (under age 30) chose Barack Obama over Mitt Romney by 60%- 37%, a 23-point margin, according to the National Exit Polls.

More information

NEW HAMPSHIRE: TRUMP, SANDERS HOLD LEADS

NEW HAMPSHIRE: TRUMP, SANDERS HOLD LEADS Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Sunday, 7, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

The Independence Referendum: Predicting the Outcome 1. David N.F. Bell

The Independence Referendum: Predicting the Outcome 1. David N.F. Bell The Independence Referendum: Predicting the Outcome 1 David N.F. Bell Division of Economics Stirling Management School, University of Stirling, IZA, Bonn and ESRC Centre for Population Change 1 Thanks

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Latino Voters in the 2012 Election

Latino Voters in the 2012 Election November 7, 2012 71%; 27% Mark Hugo Lopez, Associate Director Paul Taylor, Director FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: 1615 L St, N.W., Suite 700 Washington, D.C. 20036 Tel (202) 419-3600 Fax (202) 419-3608

More information

5. Which normally describes the political party system in the United States? 1. A political party supports this during an election: A.

5. Which normally describes the political party system in the United States? 1. A political party supports this during an election: A. 1. A political party supports this during an election: A. Public Policy B. Platform C. Compromise D. Third Party 2. Third parties usually impact government by: A. Electing large numbers of politicians

More information

TEXAS: CRUZ, CLINTON LEAD PRIMARIES

TEXAS: CRUZ, CLINTON LEAD PRIMARIES Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Thursday, 25, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

IOWA: CARSON, TRUMP TIE FOR LEAD

IOWA: CARSON, TRUMP TIE FOR LEAD Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, August 31, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY

More information

Who Chooses Annuities? An Experimental Investigation of the Role of Gender, Framing and Defaults

Who Chooses Annuities? An Experimental Investigation of the Role of Gender, Framing and Defaults Who Chooses Annuities? An Experimental Investigation of the Role of Gender, Framing and Defaults Julie R. Agnew, Lisa R. Anderson, Jeffrey R. Gerlach and Lisa R. Szykman December 18, 2007 Julie R. Agnew

More information

Social Security and Democratic vote - Jasmine Jefferson

Social Security and Democratic vote - Jasmine Jefferson 50 Virginia Policy Review Social Security and the 2014 Midterm Elections Jasmine Jefferson Introduction Election season is upon us and with a strong Republican majority in the United States House of Representatives

More information

The Economists Voice

The Economists Voice The Economists Voice Volume 1, Issue 2 2004 Article 1 Experimental Political Betting Markets and the 2004 Election Justin Wolfers Eric Zitzewitz Wharton. U.Penn Stanford GSB Copyright c 2004 by the authors.

More information

Stable matching: Theory, evidence, and practical design

Stable matching: Theory, evidence, and practical design THE PRIZE IN ECONOMIC SCIENCES 2012 INFORMATION FOR THE PUBLIC Stable matching: Theory, evidence, and practical design This year s Prize to Lloyd Shapley and Alvin Roth extends from abstract theory developed

More information

2014 May Elections Campaign Tracking Research

2014 May Elections Campaign Tracking Research 2014 May Elections Campaign Tracking Research Report for: Controlled document - Issue 4 TNS 2014 08.08.2014 JN 123256 Controlled document - Issue 5 Contents Executive Summary... 1 1. Background and objectives...

More information

Partisan Bias in the Electoral College: Cheap States and Wasted Votes 1

Partisan Bias in the Electoral College: Cheap States and Wasted Votes 1 Partisan Bias in the Electoral College: Cheap States and Wasted Votes 1 Phillip J. Ardoin Appalachian State University Bryan M. Parsons University of South Carolina This article dissects the sources of

More information

Voluntary Provision of a Public Good

Voluntary Provision of a Public Good Classroom Games Voluntary Provision of a Public Good Charles A. Holt and Susan K. Laury * Abstract: This paper describes a simple public goods game, implemented with playing cards in a classroom setup.

More information

Texas insurance issues Statewide poll

Texas insurance issues Statewide poll Texas insurance issues Statewide poll August -9, 1 Commissioned by Background Methodology Statewide sample of voters Interviews conducted August -9, 1 Margin of error of ±4.% for cases Disclosures To avoid

More information

The Electoral Process STEP BY STEP. the worksheet activity to the class. the answers with the class. (The PowerPoint works well for this.

The Electoral Process STEP BY STEP. the worksheet activity to the class. the answers with the class. (The PowerPoint works well for this. Teacher s Guide Time Needed: One class period Materials Needed: Student worksheets Projector Copy Instructions: Reading (2 pages; class set) Activity (3 pages; class set) The Electoral Process Learning

More information

Online Appendix for The Letter After Your Name : Party Labels on Virginia Ballots published in State Politics and Policy Quarterly

Online Appendix for The Letter After Your Name : Party Labels on Virginia Ballots published in State Politics and Policy Quarterly Online Appendix for The Letter After Your Name : Party Labels on Virginia Ballots published in State Politics and Policy Quarterly Alex Garlick Ph.D. Candidate, University of Pennsylvania www.alexgarlick.com

More information

Voting and Political Demography in 1996

Voting and Political Demography in 1996 California Opinion Index A review of Voting and Political Demography in 1996 February 1997 Findings in Brief Approximately 10.3 million Californians voted in the November 1996 Presidential elections, down

More information

DEBORAH JORDAN BROOKS Dartmouth College Department of Government 6108 Silsby Hall, Hanover, NH 03755 603-646-3919 deborah.brooks@dartmouth.

DEBORAH JORDAN BROOKS Dartmouth College Department of Government 6108 Silsby Hall, Hanover, NH 03755 603-646-3919 deborah.brooks@dartmouth. DEBORAH JORDAN BROOKS Dartmouth College Department of Government 6108 Silsby Hall, Hanover, NH 03755 603-646-3919 deborah.brooks@dartmouth.edu EDUCATION: Yale University, 1994-2000 Ph.D. in Political Science

More information

IOWA: TRUMP TAKES CAUCUS LEAD

IOWA: TRUMP TAKES CAUCUS LEAD Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Wednesday, 27, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

121 State Street HarperPolling.com info@harperpolling.com Harrisburg, PA 17101

121 State Street HarperPolling.com info@harperpolling.com Harrisburg, PA 17101 TO: FROM: Date: RE: Interested Parties Brock McCleary, President April 28, 15 Key Poll Findings Online Gambling in Pennsylvania Our survey of registered voters in Pennsylvania reveals pervasive opposition

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

FLORIDA: TRUMP WIDENS LEAD OVER RUBIO

FLORIDA: TRUMP WIDENS LEAD OVER RUBIO Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, March 14, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

CREST. Follow my Leader? A Cross-National Analysis of Leadership Effects in Parliamentary Democracies. By John Curtice and André Blais

CREST. Follow my Leader? A Cross-National Analysis of Leadership Effects in Parliamentary Democracies. By John Curtice and André Blais CREST RE FOR RESEARCH INTO CENT ELECTIONS AND SOCIAL TRENDS Working Paper Number 91 September 2001 Follow my Leader? A Cross-National Analysis of Leadership Effects in Parliamentary Democracies By The

More information

VIRGINIA: TRUMP, CLINTON LEAD PRIMARIES

VIRGINIA: TRUMP, CLINTON LEAD PRIMARIES Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Thursday, 25, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

NATIONAL: AN ANGRY AMERICA

NATIONAL: AN ANGRY AMERICA Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, January 25, 2016 Contact: PATRICK MURRAY

More information

ALABAMA and OKLAHOMA: TRUMP LEADS IN BOTH CLINTON LEADS IN AL, SANDERS IN OK

ALABAMA and OKLAHOMA: TRUMP LEADS IN BOTH CLINTON LEADS IN AL, SANDERS IN OK Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, February 29, 2016 Contact: PATRICK

More information

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY

IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Public Opinion Quarterly Advance Access published October 18, 2014 Public Opinion Quarterly IDEOLOGY, THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT RULING, AND SUPREME COURT LEGITIMACY Christopher D. Johnston* D. Sunshine Hillygus

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

NATIONAL: GOP ALL OVER THE 2016 MAP

NATIONAL: GOP ALL OVER THE 2016 MAP Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Released: Tuesday, December 16, 2014 Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769 (cell); 732-263-5858

More information

PUBLIC OPINION AND ELECTORAL BEHAVIOR Florida State University

PUBLIC OPINION AND ELECTORAL BEHAVIOR Florida State University PUBLIC OPINION AND ELECTORAL BEHAVIOR POS 3204 Fall, 2011 Office Hours, Monday and Wednesday 9:00 11:30 a.m. or by appointment Professor: Brad T. Gomez Office: 536 Bellamy Bldg. E-mail: bgomez@fsu.edu

More information

THE NASAA ADVOCATE. Strategies for Building Arts Support E-ADVOCACY: ON-LINE STRATEGIES FOR ARTS ADVOCACY

THE NASAA ADVOCATE. Strategies for Building Arts Support E-ADVOCACY: ON-LINE STRATEGIES FOR ARTS ADVOCACY Strategies for Building Arts Support Volume XI, Issue No. 2 S art tates National Assembly of State Arts Agencies 1029 Vermont Ave., NW 2nd Floor Washington, D.C. 20005 Tel.: 202.347.6352 Fax: 202.737.0526

More information

MARYLAND: CLINTON LEADS SANDERS BY 25

MARYLAND: CLINTON LEADS SANDERS BY 25 Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Thursday, 21, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

Title: Split-Ticket Voting in Mixed-Member Electoral Systems: A Theoretical and Methodological Investigation.

Title: Split-Ticket Voting in Mixed-Member Electoral Systems: A Theoretical and Methodological Investigation. Thesis Summary Title: Split-Ticket Voting in Mixed-Member Electoral Systems: A Theoretical and Methodological Investigation. Author: Carolina Plescia (carolina.plescia@univie.ac.at) Supervisors: Prof.

More information

Messaging and the Mandate: The Impact of Consumer Experience on Health Insurance Enrollment Through Exchanges

Messaging and the Mandate: The Impact of Consumer Experience on Health Insurance Enrollment Through Exchanges Messaging and the Mandate: The Impact of Consumer Experience on Health Insurance Enrollment Through Exchanges By Natalie Cox, Benjamin Handel, Jonathan Kolstad, and Neale Mahoney At the heart of the Affordable

More information

Opinion Poll. Minnesota Small Business Owners Support Reforming U.S. Elections. October 30, 2014

Opinion Poll. Minnesota Small Business Owners Support Reforming U.S. Elections. October 30, 2014 Opinion Poll Minnesota Small Business Owners Support Reforming U.S. Elections October 30, 2014 Small Business Majority 1101 14 th Street, NW, Suite 1001 Washington, DC 20005 (202) 828-8357 www.smallbusinessmajority.org

More information

CITIZEN ADVOCACY CENTER

CITIZEN ADVOCACY CENTER CITIZEN ADVOCACY CENTER Third-Party Presidential Candidates: Barriers to Ballot Access LESSON PLAN AND ACTIVITIES All rights reserved. No part of this lesson plan may be reproduced in any form or by any

More information

VOTER TURNOUT IN THE 2011 PROVINCIAL ELECTION: A SURVEY OF VOTERS AND NON-VOTERS

VOTER TURNOUT IN THE 2011 PROVINCIAL ELECTION: A SURVEY OF VOTERS AND NON-VOTERS VOTER TURNOUT IN THE 2011 PROVINCIAL ELECTION: A SURVEY OF VOTERS AND NON-VOTERS March 29, 2012 Prepared for: Elections Manitoba WINNIPEG OTTAWA EDMONTON REGINA admin@pra.ca www.pra.ca Elections Manitoba

More information

MICHIGAN: TRUMP, CLINTON IN FRONT

MICHIGAN: TRUMP, CLINTON IN FRONT Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, 7, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

NATIONAL: SENATE SHOULD CONSIDER SCOTUS PICK

NATIONAL: SENATE SHOULD CONSIDER SCOTUS PICK Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, March 21, 2016 Contact: PATRICK MURRAY

More information

Electoral Studies 28 (2009) 51 61. Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Electoral Studies. journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud

Electoral Studies 28 (2009) 51 61. Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Electoral Studies. journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Electoral Studies 28 (2009) 51 61 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Electoral Studies journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/electstud Strategic voting in established and new democracies: Ticket

More information

NEW HAMPSHIRE: TRUMP LEADS, BUSH SECOND

NEW HAMPSHIRE: TRUMP LEADS, BUSH SECOND Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Tuesday, July 28, 2015 Contact: PATRICK MURRAY

More information

IOWA: CRUZ TAKES CAUCUS LEAD

IOWA: CRUZ TAKES CAUCUS LEAD Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, 7, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

Why does Donald Trump perform better in online versus live telephone polling?

Why does Donald Trump perform better in online versus live telephone polling? Why does Donald Trump perform better in online versus live telephone polling? Morning Consult 1 December 21, 2015 2 Why does Donald Trump perform worse in live telephone versus online polling? In mid-december

More information

Research brief for the AQMeN & ScotCen event Through the public s eye: Researching attitudes on Scotland s constitutional future using the SSA

Research brief for the AQMeN & ScotCen event Through the public s eye: Researching attitudes on Scotland s constitutional future using the SSA Independence and affluence: explaining differences in levels of support for independence by socio-economic status using the Scottish Social Attitudes Survey Christopher McLean, Ipsos MORI Christopher.McLean@ipsos.com

More information

CIRCLE The Center for Information & Research on Civic Learning & Engagement

CIRCLE The Center for Information & Research on Civic Learning & Engagement FACT SHEET CIRCLE The Center for Information & Research on Civic Learning & Engagement Civic Engagement Among Young Men and Women By Karlo Barrios Marcelo, Mark Hugo Lopez, and Emily Hoban Kirby 1 March

More information

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants. George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Social Security Eligibility and the Labor Supply of Elderly Immigrants George J. Borjas Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research Updated for the 9th Annual Joint Conference of the Retirement

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Santorum leads GOP Twitter race despite Romney poll wins

Santorum leads GOP Twitter race despite Romney poll wins Press Release March 01 2012 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE Santorum leads GOP Twitter race despite Romney poll wins Social media analytics firm Brandwatch has been tracking Republican candidates on Twitter since

More information

Release #2343 Release Date: Saturday, July 10, 2010

Release #2343 Release Date: Saturday, July 10, 2010 THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 900 San Francisco,

More information

Elections - Methods for Predicting Which People Will vote

Elections - Methods for Predicting Which People Will vote Center for Public Opinion Dr. Joshua J. Dyck and Dr. Francis Talty, co-directors http://www.uml.edu/polls @UML_CPO UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 8 of 8 Survey produced

More information

OHIO: KASICH, TRUMP IN GOP SQUEAKER; CLINTON LEADS IN DEM RACE

OHIO: KASICH, TRUMP IN GOP SQUEAKER; CLINTON LEADS IN DEM RACE Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, 14, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

Marist College Institute for Public Opinion Poughkeepsie, NY 12601 Phone 845.575.5050 Fax 845.575.5111 www.maristpoll.marist.edu

Marist College Institute for Public Opinion Poughkeepsie, NY 12601 Phone 845.575.5050 Fax 845.575.5111 www.maristpoll.marist.edu Marist College Institute for Public Opinion Poughkeepsie, NY 12601 Phone 845.575.5050 Fax 845.575.5111 www.maristpoll.marist.edu NBC News/Marist Poll Nearly Seven in Ten New Jersey Voters Applaud Christie

More information

Review of the Four Fairness Criteria

Review of the Four Fairness Criteria MATH 11008: Fairness Criteria Review of the Four Fairness Criteria Majority Criterion: If candidate X has a majority of the first-place votes, then candidate X should be the winner of the election. The

More information

behavior research center s

behavior research center s behavior research center s behavior research center s NEWS RELEASE [RMP 2012-III-01] Contact: Earl de Berge Research Director 602-258-4554 602-268-6563 OBAMA PULLS EVEN WITH ROMNEY IN ARIZONA; FLAKE AND

More information

Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang

Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang December 2010 1 Curriculum Vitae Eric C.C. Chang Department of Political Science Michigan State University 313 South Kedzie Hall East Lansing, MI 48824 Phone: (517)432-2047 Email: echang@msu.edu Homepage:

More information

Forecasting in a Polarized Era: The Time for Change Model and the 2012 Presidential Election

Forecasting in a Polarized Era: The Time for Change Model and the 2012 Presidential Election Forecasting in a Polarized Era: The Time for Change Model and the 2012 Presidential Election Alan Abramowitz Alben W. Barkley Professor of Political Science Emory University Atlanta, Georgia 30322 E-mail:

More information

IL: KERRY LEADS BUSH BY 13 PTS; OBAMA ON TOP OF RYAN BY 11 PTS

IL: KERRY LEADS BUSH BY 13 PTS; OBAMA ON TOP OF RYAN BY 11 PTS IL: KERRY LEADS BUSH BY 13 PTS; OBAMA ON TOP OF RYAN BY 11 PTS DEMOCRATS POISED TO PICK-UP U.S. SENATE SEAT BEING VACATED BY FITZGERALD IN AN ELECTION TODAY, JOHN KERRY CARRIES IL & BARACK OBAMA IS ELECTED

More information

Liberty response to The Electoral Commission consultation on the review of ballot paper design

Liberty response to The Electoral Commission consultation on the review of ballot paper design Liberty response to The Electoral Commission consultation on the review of ballot paper design February 2003 Liberty (The National Council for Civil Liberties) is one of the UK s leading civil liberties

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo, Director, The Field Poll THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Frances McCall Rosenbluth. Yale University Hamden, CT 06517 New Haven, CT 06520-8301 203 562-2268 203 432-5672 frances.rosenbluth@yale.

Frances McCall Rosenbluth. Yale University Hamden, CT 06517 New Haven, CT 06520-8301 203 562-2268 203 432-5672 frances.rosenbluth@yale. Frances McCall Rosenbluth Department of Political Science 110 Rogers Road Yale University Hamden, CT 06517 New Haven, CT 06520-8301 203 562-2268 203 432-5672 frances.rosenbluth@yale.edu EDUCATION Columbia

More information

Media Channel Effectiveness and Trust

Media Channel Effectiveness and Trust Media Channel Effectiveness and Trust Edward Paul Johnson 1, Dan Williams 1 1 Western Wats, 701 E. Timpanogos Parkway, Orem, UT, 84097 Abstract The advent of social media creates an alternative channel

More information

Paul Whiteley and Patrick Seyd

Paul Whiteley and Patrick Seyd Party Election Campaigning in Britain: The Labour Party Paul Whiteley and Patrick Seyd Paul Whiteley, Department of Government, University of Essex, Colchester, C04 3SQ, United Kingdom. Whiteley@essex.ac.uk

More information

A Study About Identity Theft

A Study About Identity Theft A Study About Identity Theft Prepared For: The National Foundation for Credit Counseling Prepared By: Harris Interactive Inc. Public Relations Research 1 INTRODUCTION AND METHODOLOGY This Identity Theft

More information

NATIONAL: HOUSE SPEAKERSHIP SHADOWS GOP 2016

NATIONAL: HOUSE SPEAKERSHIP SHADOWS GOP 2016 Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Tuesday, 20, Contact: PATRICK MURRAY 732-979-6769

More information

Badger Poll@ #14, Release #2 University of Wisconsin Survey Center University of Wisconsin Madison April 3, 2004

Badger Poll@ #14, Release #2 University of Wisconsin Survey Center University of Wisconsin Madison April 3, 2004 Badger Poll@ #14, Release #2 University of Wisconsin Survey Center University of Wisconsin Madison April 3, 2004 NOTE: When using material from this release please cite the Badger Poll@ conducted by the

More information

Games Manipulators Play

Games Manipulators Play Games Manipulators Play Umberto Grandi Department of Mathematics University of Padova 23 January 2014 [Joint work with Edith Elkind, Francesca Rossi and Arkadii Slinko] Gibbard-Satterthwaite Theorem All

More information

Test-Score Effects of School Vouchers in Dayton, Ohio, New York City, and Washington, D. C.: Evidence from Randomized Field Trials

Test-Score Effects of School Vouchers in Dayton, Ohio, New York City, and Washington, D. C.: Evidence from Randomized Field Trials Test-Score Effects of School Vouchers in Dayton, Ohio, New York City, and Washington, D. C.: Evidence from Randomized Field Trials by William G. Howell Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science,

More information

HPU POLL MEMO RELEASE 10/13/2014. Likely Voters in North Carolina, Colorado, and New Hampshire

HPU POLL MEMO RELEASE 10/13/2014. Likely Voters in North Carolina, Colorado, and New Hampshire HPU POLL MEMO RELEASE 10/1/2014 ELEMENTS Populations represented Sample sizes Mode of data collection Type of sample (probability/nonprobability) DETAILS Likely Voters in North Carolina, Colorado, and

More information

Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers

Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers Yiling Chen 2,, Arpita Ghosh 1, Preston McAfee 1, and David Pennock 1 1 Yahoo! Research. Email: arpita, mcafee, pennockd@yahoo-inc.com 2 Harvard University.

More information

JAPAN. Date of Elections: December 27, 1969. Characteristics of Parliament

JAPAN. Date of Elections: December 27, 1969. Characteristics of Parliament Date of Elections: December 27, 1969 Characteristics of Parliament JAPAN The Japanese Parliament (The Diet) is bicameral, consisting of two Houses: The House of Representatives, composed of members, elected

More information

2014 Midterm Elections: Voter Dissatisfaction with the President and Washington October 23-27, 2014

2014 Midterm Elections: Voter Dissatisfaction with the President and Washington October 23-27, 2014 CBS NEWS POLL For release: Wednesday, October 29, 2014 6:30 pm EDT 2014 Midterm Elections: Voter Dissatisfaction with the President and Washington October 23-27, 2014 51% of voters expect the Republicans

More information

NATIONAL: TRUMP WIDENS NATIONAL LEAD

NATIONAL: TRUMP WIDENS NATIONAL LEAD Please attribute this information to: Monmouth University Poll West Long Branch, NJ 07764 www.monmouth.edu/polling Follow on Twitter: @MonmouthPoll Released: Monday, December 14, 2015 Contact: PATRICK

More information

The Election of 1860 By Ron Miller - Jewett Academy

The Election of 1860 By Ron Miller - Jewett Academy The Election of 1860 By Ron Miller - Jewett Academy I. Lesson Summary Summary The Election of 1860 demonstrated the divisions within the United States just before the Civil War. The election was unusual

More information

Political Science 111 Current Problems and Controversies in United States Politics: Shaping Policy Fall 2009

Political Science 111 Current Problems and Controversies in United States Politics: Shaping Policy Fall 2009 Political Science 111 Current Problems and Controversies in United States Politics: Shaping Policy Fall 2009 Time: T/Th; 9:30AM -10:45AM Contact Information: Location: 1115 2BSB 1122 2BSB Professor Michael

More information

Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly

Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly Warranty Designs and Brand Reputation Analysis in a Duopoly Kunpeng Li * Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, TX, U.S.A. Qin Geng Kutztown University of Pennsylvania, Kutztown, PA, U.S.A. Bin Shao

More information

Survey of Nevada Casino Gaming Employees

Survey of Nevada Casino Gaming Employees Survey of Nevada Casino Gaming Employees American Gaming Association December 13, 2015 N = 320 current Nevada- based casino gaming industry employees Margin of error = +/- 5.5% Field Dates: Dec. 8 th 12

More information

The Road to the White House

The Road to the White House The President s Desk: Campaign Button Module The Road to the White House Topic: Presidential campaigns and elections Grades: 4-6 Time Required: 1-2 class periods Goals/Rationale: By exploring the primary

More information

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo and Mervin Field

THE FIELD POLL. By Mark DiCamillo and Mervin Field THE FIELD POLL THE INDEPENDENT AND NON-PARTISAN SURVEY OF PUBLIC OPINION ESTABLISHED IN 1947 AS THE CALIFORNIA POLL BY MERVIN FIELD Field Research Corporation 601 California Street, Suite 210 San Francisco,

More information

Increasing Voter Turnout: Is Democracy Day the Answer? by Henry S. Farber, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No.

Increasing Voter Turnout: Is Democracy Day the Answer? by Henry S. Farber, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. Increasing Voter Turnout: Is Democracy Day the Answer? by Henry S. Farber, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 181 February 2009 ABSTRACT It has often been argued that voter turnout in the United

More information

UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 5 of 8

UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 5 of 8 Center for Public Opinion Dr. Joshua J. Dyck and Dr. Francis Talty, co-directors http://www.uml.edu/polls @UML_CPO UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 5 of 8 Survey produced

More information

Voter Survey D.C. Democratic Primary for Mayor and Council Chairman August 2010

Voter Survey D.C. Democratic Primary for Mayor and Council Chairman August 2010 Voter Survey D.C. Democratic Primary for Mayor and Council Chairman August 2010 POLLING. FOCUS GROUPS. MARKET STUDIES. MEMBERSHIP SURVEYS. MESSAGE DEVELOPMENT AND TESTING. SURVEY INFORMATION AND METHODOLOGY

More information

Democratic Process and Social Media: A Study of Us Presidential Election 2012

Democratic Process and Social Media: A Study of Us Presidential Election 2012 Democratic Process and Social Media: A Study of Us Presidential Election 2012 Abstract Susanta Kumar Parida M.Phil Scholar Dept. of Political Science Utkal University, Vanivihar, Bhubaneswar, Odisha India

More information

5.120 Sign at polling station

5.120 Sign at polling station 5.120 Sign at polling station *Britain increased this to two years in 1842. Government voting rights in Newfoundland and Labrador have undergone several changes in the last two centuries. Today we have

More information

Sierra Powell. M.A., Political Science 2011 Areas of Concentration: American Politics and Political Theory

Sierra Powell. M.A., Political Science 2011 Areas of Concentration: American Politics and Political Theory Last updated September 2015 EDUCATION Sierra Powell Junior Fellow Social Sciences Research Network 3151 Social Science Plaza A. Irvine, California 92697 Website: https://sites.google.com/site/sierrapowell/

More information

UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 4 of 8

UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 4 of 8 Center for Public Opinion Dr. Joshua J. Dyck and Dr. Francis Talty, co-directors http://www.uml.edu/polls @UML_CPO UMass Lowell/7News Daily Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 4 of 8 Survey produced

More information

UMass Lowell/7News Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 3

UMass Lowell/7News Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 3 Center for Public Opinion Dr. Joshua J. Dyck and Dr. Francis Talty, co-directors http://www.uml.edu/polls @UML_CPO UMass Lowell/7News Tracking Poll of New Hampshire Voters Release 3 Survey produced by

More information

FOR RELEASE: MONDAY, SEPTEMBER 10 AT 4 PM

FOR RELEASE: MONDAY, SEPTEMBER 10 AT 4 PM Interviews with 1,022 adult Americans conducted by telephone by ORC International on September 7-9, 2012. The margin of sampling error for results based on the total sample is plus or minus 3 percentage

More information

Chapter 5 and 6 Study Guide

Chapter 5 and 6 Study Guide Chapter 5 and 6 Study Guide Matching a. not an answer b. political party c. major parties d. not an answer e. split-ticket voting f. precinct g. pluralistic society 1. the smallest unit of election administration

More information