Why Long Term Forward Interest Rates (Almost) Always Slope Downwards

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Why Long Term Forward Interest Rates (Almost) Always Slope Downwards"

Transcription

1 Why Long Term Forward Interest Rates (Almost) Always Slope Downwards Roger H. Brown Warburg Dillon Read Stephen M. Schaefer London Business School, May 1, 2000 Corresponding author: Stephen M. Schaefer, London Business School, Sussex Place, Regents Park, London NW1 4SA, UK.

2 Abstract The paper documents a persistent and thus far largely overlooked empirical regularity in the yield curve: the tendency for the term structure of long term forward rates to slope downwards. The persistence of this feature is demonstrated using data on US and UK Government conventional (nominal) bonds and UK Government index-linked bonds. We show that the downward slope is the result of interest rate volatility. Using a two factor Gaussian model we show that the long term forward rate curve will be downward sloping whenever the volatility of the long term zero coupon yield is sufficiently high. Using data on US Treasury STRIPs, the paper further shows that the slope of the forward rate curve predicts the volatility of long term rates and that the implied volatility from bond futures options explains the slope of the forward rate curve. 2

3 Why Long Term Forward Interest Rates (Almost) Always Slope Downwards 1 1. Introduction The term structure of long term forward interest rates is persistently downward sloping. In nearly ten years of daily data on US Treasury STRIPs from 1985 to 1994, the implied two year forward rate spanning years 24 to 26 is lower than the forward rate for years 14 to 16 on 98.4% of occasions. The average difference in these rates is 138 basis points. A similar downward tilt also appears in estimates of forward rates derived from the prices of coupon bonds in the US Treasury market and in the UK market for both real and nominal government bonds 2. We show that this feature of the term structure is not anomalous; nor do we need to turn to institutional features of the market for an explanation. Rather, it arises as a consequence of the combined effect of the term structure of volatility of long term interest rates and the greater convexity of long term bonds. Explaining the relation between the yields on default-free bonds and their maturity, the term structure, is a classical problem in financial economics and the subject of extensive research over many years. The shape of the yield curve varies substantially over time: sometimes upward sloping, sometimes downward and sometimes hump-shaped. Thus it is interesting to find one part of the curve long term forward rates whose shape appears to be always the same, irrespective of the pattern of rates for shorter maturities. It may well be the single most predictable feature of the term structure of interest rates. It is also interesting to note that, even though term structure theory has focussed mainly on expectations of future rates and risk premia to explain the shape, we find that this particular highly persistent feature is the result of interest rate volatility alone. Most term structure theories (e.g., Vasicek (1977), Cox, Ingersoll and Ross 1 The authors gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments and suggestions from Andrea Berardi, Mark Britten-Jones, Antii Ilmanen and Davide Menini, from seminar participants at the universities of Barcelona, Imperial College, Louvain, Lancaster, Toulouse and Verona and from participants at the Workshop on Mathematical Finance, Strobl, Austria The authors are also very grateful to Mark Fisher, Douglas Nychka and David Zervos for allowing us to use their estimates of zero coupon yields. The usual disclaimer applies. 2 The estimates for the US were obtained by Fisher M.E., Nychka D. & Zervos D (1994) and McCulloch and Kwon (1993). Those for the UK are the authors own calculations. 3

4 (1985) and Longstaff and Schwartz (1992)) predict that the term structure of long term forward rates is flat. Indeed, ever since Durand (1942) constructed his famous series of yields by drawing a curve (freehand) through the lower envelope of yields-to-maturity on high grade corporate bonds, the available data has seemed to suggest that actual yield curves are also flat for long maturities 3.Inthecaseof yields-to-maturity on coupon bearing bonds this is merely a matter of arithmetic since the yields on all such bonds approach the yield on a perpetuity as maturity becomes infinite. However, the shape of the zero-coupon yield curve (or the forward rate curve) is not constrained in this way, apart from the no-arbitrage condition that (nominal) forward rates are non-negative. What our results show is that under empirically relevant conditions - essentially, when long term zero coupon rates experience parallel shifts - the term structure of long term forward rates is always downward sloping. The consistent downward slope in long term forward rates has a number of practical implications. First, our results have implications for attempts to extract market expectations from the yield curve 4. Abstracting from considerations of risk premia, classical term structure theory identifies the market s expectation of a future interest rate as the forward rate. In models which make use of contingent claims analysis (i.e., Merton (1970), Vasicek (1977) and followers) forward rates and the expected path of the short rate will diverge even when risk premia are zero. The difference is accounted for by convexity effects; our results show that, for long maturities, these effects can be substantial. Second, some approaches which have been proposed for estimating the term structure of zero coupon rates from the prices of coupon bonds use approximating functions which constrain the long term forward rate curve to be flat 5. Our results suggest that such methods may be mis-specified. Third, the relation which we derive between interest rate volatility and the shape of long term forward rates may be useful to practitioners facing the problem of pricing a new issue which has a longer maturity than any existing issue. Using a two-factor affine model [Brown and Schaefer (1994b), Duffie and Kan (1996)], we derive a simple relation between the term structure of long term forward rates in a cross section and the volatility of long term zero coupon rates. Here we follow a number of authors who have attempted to use term structure 3 Durand drew his curves by choosing one of five shapes, all of which were flat for long maturities. 4 See Deacon and Derry (1994). 5 For example, Vasicek and Fong (1982) and Nelson and Siegel (1987). 4

5 models to estimate the level of interest rate volatility implied by the term structure. For example, Brown & Dybvig (1986), Barone, Cuoco & Zautzik (1991) and Brown & Schaefer (1994a) have all used the Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985) (CIR) model to impute interest rate volatility from cross sections of bond prices. While all three studies find that implied volatility corresponds quite well to time series estimates, the volatility parameter in term structure studies is estimated jointly with the other parameters of the model and it is correspondingly difficult to identify the influence on the shape of the term structure alone. Litterman, Scheinkman & Weiss (1991) (LSW) adopt a simpler approach and estimate the relation between the implied volatility of options on US Treasury bond futures and the level of short, medium and long term zero coupon yields. They find that the 1 month, 3-year and 10-year zero coupon yields together explain around 70% of the variation in implied volatility. The present study can be regarded as being in the spirit of LSW, namely to identify some easily observable feature of the yield curve which reflects the impact of interest rate volatility but todosointhecontextofamodel.thuswederiveasimplerelationbetweenthe term structure of interest rate volatility and the term structure of forward interest rates. Our relation is also easily inverted: in other words it is straightforward to obtain an estimate of implied interest rate volatility from the pattern of long term forward rates. Caverhill (1998) has also recently investigated the relation between the forward curve and interest rate volatility. The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 uses a highly simplified model of the yield curve to provide an intuitive explanation of the relation between forward rates and the volatility of zero coupon yields. The main prediction of the model is that the spread between longer and shorter term forward rates should be negative and proportional to the variance of long term zero coupon rates. Section 3 then shows that the same relation may be derived as an approximation within a more realistic two-factor affine model. Section 4 describes our data and Section 5 presents summary statistics on estimates of forward rate spreads for three markets: US Treasury bonds, UK conventional (nominal) gilts and UK index-linked gilts. We find, as the model predicts, that forward rate spreads - particularly since the early 1980 s - are strongly and persistently negative. Section 6 contains our main empirical results. Here we show that (a) the shape of the term structure of forward rates predicts the volatility of zero coupon yields and (b) that the forward rate spread is itself predictable using the implied volatility of bond futures options. Section 7 concludes. 5

6 2. The Informal Argument The term structure of long term forward rates depends on two key features of the empirical behaviour of the yield curve: the tendency of long term zero coupon rates (a) to be highly correlated and (b) to have volatilities which decline relatively slowly with maturity. 6 To understand this simple relation between forward rates and interest rate volatility, consider a zero coupon bond with time-to-maturity τ and yield at time t of y(t, τ). We assume that the yields on bonds with sufficiently long maturities are perfectly correlated with a common variance σ 2 y whichisconstantovertime and over (long) maturities. The price of such a bond is given by: and its rate of return from t to t + t by: P (y(t, τ)) = e y(t,τ)τ, (2.1) P P = 1 P [ 1 2 P 2 y 2 y2 + P ] y y + 1 P t. (2.2) P t where y denotes the change in yield from t to t + t. If the process generating y is time homogeneous it is straightforward to show that f(t, τ, y), the time t instantaneous forward rate for maturity τ, is given by: Equation (2.1) implies: f(t, τ, y) = P t P. (2.3) 1 P P y = τ and 1 2 P P y = τ 2, (2.4) 2 and, substituting into equation (2.2) and taking expectations (assuming that, for small t, E( y 2 ) σ 2 y t) the risk premium on the bond becomes: 6 Section 5 presents evidence on the term structure of volatility for long term zero coupon rates. 6

7 [ ] [ ] P 1 E r t t = P 2 σ2 yτ 2 τµ y + f(t, τ, y) r t t, (2.5) where r t is the short term (riskless) interest rate and E( y) µ y t. However, no arbitrage considerations imply that the risk premium on the bond is also proportional to its elasticity with respect to y, i.e.: [ ] P E r t t = τλ y t, (2.6) P where λ y is a risk premium parameter 7. Equating equations (2.5) and (2.6) we have that the forward rate is given by: f(t, τ, y) =r t + τ ( µ y λ y ) 1 2 σ2 y τ 2. (2.7) If we assume that the long end of the term structure experiences parallel shifts, i.e., that the term structure of zero coupon yield volatility is flat, then, for a given reference yield y, 1 P P y = τ and 1 P 2 P y 2 = τ 2 hold for all long maturities, then equation (2.7) shows that the shape of the long term forward rate curve depends on two terms. The first is linear in maturity and, depending on the sign of ( µ y λ y ), may be increasing or decreasing with τ. The second, however, is (a) always decreasing in maturity and (b) because it is proportional to τ 2 rather than τ, always dominates the first term for sufficiently large τ. Thus, when the term structure of yield volatility is constant for long maturities the term structure of forward rates is always downward sloping and, for long maturities neglecting the linear term we have that the difference in forward rates between two maturities τ 1 and τ 2, the forward rate spread, is given approximately by: f(t, τ 1,τ 2 ) f(t, τ 2,y) f(t, τ 1,y) (2.8) 1 [ ] 2 σ2 l τ 2 2 τ This model is essentially identical to Merton (1970) with a zero rate of mean reversion. 7

8 The only significant difference between the analysis in this section and a standard single factor model, e.g., Vasicek (1977) is the (implicit) assumption of zero mean reversion which supports the assumption of a flat term structure of volatility for long term rates. With non-zero mean reversion the yield volatility σ y declines with maturity and consequently equation (2.7) would not describe the term structure of long term forward rates. It is important to note, however, that in this case the yields on long bonds converge to a constant. In the next section we derive an expression for the forward rate spread using a less restrictive, i.e., more realistic, two-factor model and show that, even in the presence of non-zero mean reversion in one factor, equation (2.8) still holds as an approximation to the forward rate spread. 3. A Model of Forward Rate Spreads We consider a two factor time homogeneous affine Gaussian model of the term structure [Langetieg(1980), Brown & Schaefer (1994b), Duffie and Kan (1996)] where the state variables x and y are assumed to follow: dx = κ x (µ x x) dt + σ x dz x, (3.1) ( dy = κ y µy y ) dt + σ y dz y, where κ x, µ x, σ x, κ y, µ y and σ y are parameters and dz x and dz y are increments of standard Brownian motions with E(dz x dz y )=ρdt. Within the class of twofactor time-homogeneous Gaussian affine models Dai and Singleton (1998) show that the dynamics given in equation (3.1) are completely general. The Gaussian specification means that the probability of the short rate becoming negative in any finite interval is non-zero. Despite this the model is adequate for our purposes and, in particular, fits the term structure of yield volatility well. Since the model is affine (i.e., both the drift and diffusion coefficients are affine in x and y) thepriceofazerocouponbondwithmaturityτ is exponential affine and given by [Duffie and Kan (1996)]: P (x, y, t, τ) =exp {A(τ)+B x (τ)x(t)+b y (τ)y(t)} (3.2) where, because the model is time homogeneous, the functions A(.), B x (.) and B y (.) are functions of the parameters and time-to-maturity, τ, alone. The formulae for 8

9 B x (.) and B y (.) are given below; the formula for A(.) is also well know (Langetieg (1980), for example) but is not required here. The corresponding zero coupon yield, R(.), isgivenby: R(x, y, t, τ) 1 ln [P (x, y, t, τ)] (3.3) τ = A(τ) + B x(τ) x(t)+ B y(τ) y(t). (3.4) τ τ τ In equation (3.4) the functions B x (τ)/τ and B y (τ)/τ represent the sensitivities of the τ-period zero coupon yield to, respectively, x and y. For the Gaussian case giveninequation(3.1),thefunctionsb x (τ) and B y (τ) are given by: B x (τ) = 1 exp( κ xτ) κ x and B y (τ) = 1 exp( κ yτ) κ y. (3.5) We do not present detailed estimates of the parameters κ x and κ y in this paper since our result merely requires that one of the mean reversion coefficients κ x,say, is close to zero while the other is not. Appendix A describes the method we use to estimate the mean reversion parameters κ x and κ y from the covariance matrix of changes in zero coupon yields. Using data on US Treasury STRIPs for the period , we find an estimated value for one of the mean reversion coefficients is close to zero (in the range 0.02 to 0.04) while the other is between five and ten times larger [Table A2] 8. We now turn to the implications of these mean reversion coefficients for the behaviour of long term forward rates. The valuation equation, to which equation (3.2) is the solution, is: κ x (µ x x) P x P 2 σ2 x x + κ y(µ 2 y y) P y P 2 σ2 y y + P 2 t + 2 P σ xy r(x, y)p =0. (3.6) x y 8 The US Treasury STRIP prices in the first part of our dataset, from 1985 to 1988, are noticeably noisier than in the second half. In estimating the mean reversion coefficients κ x and κ y wehavethereforeuseddatafromtheendof1998totheendofdatain

10 Since the model is time homogeneous, the time t instantaneous forward rate for date t + τ is given, as before, by: f(x, y, t, τ) = 1 P Furthermore, from (3.2) we have that: P t. (3.7) 1 P P x = B x(τ), 1 P 1 P P y 2 P x 2 = B y (τ) and 1 P = B2 x (τ), 1 P 2 P y 2 = B2 y (τ). Substituting for P t, P x, P y etc. in (3.6) we have: 2 P x y = B x(τ)b y (τ) (3.8) f(x, y, t, τ) = r(x, y)+κ x (µ x x)b x (τ)+κ y (µ y y)b y (τ) 1 2 σ2 x B2 x 1 2 σ2 y B2 y ρσ xσ y B x B y. (3.9) Using (3.4) the variance of the τ-period zero coupon yield is: Var[R(x, y, t, τ)] = σ 2 x ( Bx (τ) τ ) 2 + σ 2 y +2ρσ x σ y ( Bx (τ)b y (τ) τ 2 and equation (3.9) for the forward rate therefore becomes 9 : ( By (τ) ) 2 τ ), (3.10) f(x, y, t, τ) = r(x, y)+κ x (µ x x)b x (τ)+κ y (µ y y)b y (τ) 1 2 Var[R(x, y, t, t + τ)] τ 2. (3.11) 9 Even though our analysis uses a Gaussian model, notice that an equation very similar to eq. (3.11) will hold for any affine model. The only difference is that, with n state variables there will be n terms which are linear in the drifts rather than two. The short rate and the term involving the variance of the τ-period zero coupon rate will be unchanged. 10

11 Finally, computing equation (3.11) at maturities τ 2 and τ 1 (τ 2 >τ 1 ) and taking the difference we obtain an expression for the forward rate spread: f(x, y, t, τ 1,τ 2 ) f(x, y, t, t + τ 2 ) f(x, y, t, t + τ 1 ) = κ x (µ x x)[b x (τ 2 ) B x (τ 1 )] + κ y (µ y y)[b y (τ 2 ) B y (τ 1 )] 1 ( Var[R(x, y, t, t + τ 2 )] τ Var[R(x, y, t, t + τ ) 1)] τ 2 1. (3.12) As mentioned earlier, our estimates of κ x and κ y indicate that κ x 0 and κ y 0 and we now show that this implies that the terms in (3.12) which are linear in B x (τ) and B y (τ) are close to zero. If κ x 0 then B x (τ) is approximately equal to τ and therefore finite and, since it is multiplied by κ x it follows that the entire term which is linear B x (τ) is also close to zero. Similarly, if κ y 0 then, since Lt B y(τ) = 1, τ κ y B y (τ 2 ) B y (τ 1 ) is close to zero for long maturities and, as before, the entire term which is linear B y (τ) is close to zero. Under these conditions, the forward rate spread for long maturities is dominated by the last term in equation (3.12), i.e., that: f(x, y, t, τ 1,τ 2 ) 1 2 ( ) Var[R(x, y, t, t + τ 2 )] τ 2 2 Var[R(x, y, t, t + τ 1 )] τ 2 1. (3.13) Table 1 shows the term structure of zero-coupon yield volatility for the data on US Treasury STRIPs used in Appendix A 10. The table shows that, for maturities beyond ten years, the volatility of long term yields attenuates only slowly. If, to a first approximation, we assume that zero coupon yields at maturities τ 1 and τ 2 have the same volatility (σ l )thentherighthandsideofequation(3.13)becomes further simplified to: f(x, y, t, τ 1,τ 2 ) 1 2 σ2 l 10 Once again, we describe our data in more detail below. [ ] τ 2 2 τ 2 1. (3.14) 11

12 This expression predicts that the shape of the long term forward rate curve will be quadratic and downward sloping and that the degree of concavity will be directly related to the volatility of long term zero-coupon yields. The critical condition for equation (3.14) to provide a good characterisation of the shape of the long term forward curve beyond the assumption of affine dynamics is that the term structure of volatility for long term zero-coupon yields is flat. How significant is the forward rate spread predicted by equation (3.14)? Suppose that τ 1 and τ 2 are 15 and 25 years respectively. If the volatility of long term yields is, say, 70basis points per year (consistent with the volatility given in table 1 of the 20-year zero coupon yield in the US Treasury market over the period ) then the forward rate spread predicted by the expression above is just under 100 basis points. With a volatility of 100 basis points p.a., the predicted spread rises to 200 basis points. Of course this may be offset to some extent by the first two terms in equation (3.12) which capture the effects of expectations and risk premia. Empirically, however, we find that (a) forward rate spreads are almost always negative and that (b) the size of the spread appears to be well explained by equation (3.14). 4. The Data We present data on the behaviour of forward rate spreads in three major bond markets: those for US Treasury Notes and Bonds, Conventional (i.e., fixed nominal payments) UK Government Bonds and Index-Linked UK Government Bonds 11. We have chosen to use (a) data from a variety of markets and (b) zero-coupon yields estimated via a number of different methods in order to minimise the possibility that our findings are the result of a feature of one particular market or one particular method of measuring the term structure. This section describes our data US Treasury Market McCulloch & Kwon (1993) (MK) estimate end-month term structures from December 1947 through to February They use the procedure described in McCulloch (1975) to estimate a tax-adjusted zero coupon yield curve from US Treasury bills, notes and bonds. This method approximates the discount function using cubic splines, accommodating non-symmetric taxation of capital gains 11 For a full description of the UK Index Linked Bond Market, see Bootle (1991). 12

13 and losses, and identifies for each month implicit income and capital gains tax rates which best explain observed prices. MK have modified McCulloch s original technique, which assumed coupons arrived continuously, to recognise discrete semi-annual coupon payments. The data represent the longest available time series of forward rates of which we are aware. However, during certain periods there were no long term Treasuries in issue and, at these times, we were unable to obtain yields for the long maturities which are the focus of our study. One problem faced by MK is that until August 1985 callable bonds constituted the majority of long term issues 12. MK s estimation procedure ignores the value of this option and uses the market s simple par rule to determine maturity dates 13. After August 1985 MK exclude all callable bonds. A second set of US Treasury curves comes from Fisher, Nychka and Zervos (1994) (FNZ) who use the closing bid prices of US Treasury securities collected at 3.30pm by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York s Domestic Open Market desk. The data are daily covering the period 1 December 1987 to 23 August FNZ exclude Treasury bills, callable bonds and flower bonds. They also exclude all securities issued prior to 1 January 1980in order to control for the illiquidity of older issues. Furthermore, they remove the two most recently issued securities to prevent any liquidity premium in these issues from biasing their estimates. The term structure is estimated by approximating the forward rate curve with a cubic basis spline. Unlike McCulloch (1975) or Schaefer (1981) their approach ignores potential tax effects, although it might be argued that, at least for the estimates covering the post-1988 period when income and capital gains have been taxed at equal rates, tax effects will be less pronounced. Our third source of US forward rates is US Treasury STRIP 14 prices obtained from Street Software (who also provide the Wall Street Journal with US STRIP data). The dataset we use is essentially an electronic version of the STRIP prices appearing in the US Treasury Issues table in the Wall Street Journal. Because STRIP prices are direct observations of the discount factors, no estimation is required to obtain spot or forward rates. As a result estimates of forward rates obtained from STRIPs are free from the effects of any a priori restrictions on the functional form of the yield curve which are present when approximating functions, such as splines, are used. With STRIPs, forward rates are computed 12 This problem also arises in the case of the UK Goverment conventional bonds. 13 The par rule assumes that a bond will be called at the earliest possible date if its current price is above par and at the latest possbile date if the current price is below par. 14 STRIP is an acronym for the Separate Trading of Registered Interest and Principal. 13

14 directly from the ratio of prices. The STRIP data is daily and covers the period 22 April 1985 to 5 October For the years 1985 through to 1989 the prices of only the thirty most liquid STRIPs are recorded. From 1 June 1990onwards all prices are recorded, resulting in around 160observations of discount factors on a typical day. Both bid and offer quotes are available. It is, of course, not possible to measure instantaneous forward rates - such as those appearing in equation (3.14) - directly from STRIP prices. As a proxy for the instantaneous forward rate for maturity τ, we therefore use the average forward rate between maturities τ τ and τ + τ, where τ is,say,oneyear. Thus, to obtain an estimate of the instantaneous forward rate at 25-years, for example, we extract for each trading day the bid prices and maturity dates of STRIPs maturing closest to dates 24 and 26-years from the trade date. Then, taking account of each STRIP s exact maturity date, we approximate the 25-year forward rate as F 25,where: F 25 = 365 τ 26 τ 24 ln ( P24 P 26 ) 100, (4.1) P 24 (P 26 ) is the bid price of the STRIP closest in maturity to 24 (26) years and τ 24 (τ 26 ) is the exact time to maturity of the 24 (26) year STRIP. We do not discriminate between coupon and principal payments though there are clear price discrepancies between the two types of STRIP having the same maturity date UK Nominal Government Securities Prior to 1994, there were insufficient non-callable conventional (nominal) UK Government Bonds ( gilts ) to allow reliable estimates of long term zero-coupon rates and forward rates and, for this reason, we have restricted our attention to the period from 1994 onwards. Even so, for conventional gilts, the maturity of the longest forward rate we are able to estimate consistently is just over 20-years 15. To accommodate tax effects in the market for UK gilts we use Schaefer s (1981) tax-specific approach to estimate weekly term structures from gilts for the period April 1994 to November This method utilises a linear program to identify tax efficient bonds for an investor with a pre-specified tax rate on income and capital gains. The term structure depends only on those bonds in the 15 Actually, 21.5 years. 14

15 efficient set, with the discount function approximated by cubic basis splines. We do not include Treasury bills but base the estimates on every gilt in issue at each cross section, excluding only callable bonds and undated bonds (e.g. Consols 2.5%) 16. The estimates we quote are for a tax-exempt investor UK Index-linked Government Securities Here we estimate the real term structure from UK Government inflation-linked bonds using an adaptation of Schaefer s LP procedure and Bernstein polynomials to approximate the discount function. Coupon payments and the repayment of principal for index-linked gilts are not indexed for approximately 8-months prior to the payment date; in other words the indexation in imperfect. To accommodate this feature we use an ARIMA model to forecast inflation over these 8-month periods and adjust the real cash flows accordingly. We then assume that the real cash flows are known with certainty and proceed as before. The presence of longer (non-callable) issues in the index-linked market makes it easier to generate reliable estimates of long-term forward rates than is the case in the nominal market. We use weekly cross-sections of index-linked gilts over the period January 1984 to November For more details see Brown & Schaefer (1994a). Once again, the estimates are calculated for a tax-exempt investor. The different data sources are summarised in table The Behaviour of Forward Rate Spreads: Empirical Evidence Forward Rate Spreads: Summary Statistics The simplest way to illustrate that long-term forward rates are indeed downward sloping is to look at the average difference or spread, between rates for two maturities. Table 5 gives summary statistics for estimates of the mean spread between forward rates at long maturities for the US Treasury market (for all three data sources), the UK nominal gilt market and the UK index-linked gilt market (one data source each). Each data set covers some part of the period between January 1966 and November Depending on the data source, these rates are either 16 Presently there are six such gilts which are often erroneously referred to as irredeemable. They are, in fact, all redeemable at the governments option and a sinking fund operates in one stock: Conversion 3.5%. 15

16 2-year forward rates (e.g., between 24 and 26 years) or estimated instantaneous forward rates. 17 If forward rates are downward sloping the spread will be negative. Results are shown for eight sub-periods, each five years in length except for the first and last periods. From January 1986 to December 1994 two estimates are available for the US market: the FNZ estimates and those from STRIP prices. In panel (a) of table 3 callable bonds are excluded from all the estimates. These data should be the more reliable. McCulloch and Kwon s earlier estimates (up to August 1985) in panel (b) include callable Treasuries The results are striking: thirteen of the fifteen five-year mean spreads are negative. Arguably the most reliable data are those taken directly from STRIP prices: here the means are negative for each of the three sub-periods. The mean spreads are also negative in the case of the FNZ data for the US Treasury market; indeed here every single daily estimate of the spread in the sample 1673 days is negative. The downward tilt is not only persistent but it is also of a significant size. For the FNZ and STRIP estimates, the average downward tilt in each sub-period is between 100 and 200 basis points. Figures 1a to 1e show the time series of forward rates spreads, for all five data sources, used in deriving table For the McCulloch & Kwon data (Figure 1a) the estimated spreads are sometimes positive in the early part of the period. However, as we have pointed out earlier, the estimates prior to August 1985 are potentially biased because they are based in part on the prices of callable bonds and the option premium component of the price is ignored. After August 1985 the estimates use only non-callable bonds and here all the spreads are negative. Breaks in the series occur when there were no long bonds in issue and no estimates of long term yields are provided by MK. Figure 1b shows the corresponding spread for the US Treasury market estimated by Fisher, Nychka and Zervos. Here, as reported above, the spread is negative on each of the 1673 days in the sample. All our estimates of forward rate spreads, apart from one, are derived from term structure estimates obtained using splines, or some other form of curve fitting technique. It is therefore possible that the behaviour of the forward rates in these 17 Apart from the case of UK nominal gilts where, because few long term bonds were in issue over the period, we compute the difference between the forward rates at 20 years and at 10 years. 18 As mentioned earlier, in the case of UK conventional gilts (Figure 1e) the spread shown is the 20-year minus the 10-year forward rate. For all other data sources the figures show the spread between forward rates at 25 years and 15 years. 16

17 cases is, to a greater or lesser extent, dependent on the estimation methodology used. After all, long term discount factors will usually be the most difficult to estimate because they depend on the prices of a relatively small number of the longest bonds in the sample and the forward rate spread then depends on the ratio of these discount factors. The forward rate spreads we obtain from STRIP prices are, therefore, particularly significant because these are obtained directly from prices. Figure 1c shows all the daily estimates of the spread obtained from STRIP prices. The figure shows that they are negative almost all the time (only 37 out of 2363 observations, or 1.2%, are positive) and that the size of the spread is quite substantial, around -100 basis points to -200 basis points for much of the time. Figure 1d shows the 20-year minus 10-year forward rate spread for the UK conventional gilts over the period April 1994 to December Of the 243 weekly observations, only 8 are positive and the largest of these is 14 basis points. Finally, figure 1e gives estimates of the spread for the UK index-linked market. Here, the spread is often positive for the first few months of However, from the beginning of 1985 the estimated spread is also mainly negative. The spread is negative for every week between November 1984 and October 1992 and, between October 1992 and July 1998 fluctuates around zero. Table 3 and Figures 1a-1e use forward rates at two particular maturities, in most cases at 15 and 25 years. This raises the question of whether this choice of maturities is special in some sense: perhaps the term structure of forward rates at other long maturities behaves differently. In Figure 2 we show the average oneyear forward rate curve, derived from STRIP prices, for maturities between 13 years and 26. Each of the ten charts shows the term structure of average forward rates for a calendar year and, while these are not always monotonic, the shape of the curve is, in each case, clearly downward sloping. Overall, the evidence shows that the term structure of long term forward rates is persistently downward sloping. This is true not only in the US market but also in the UK market for both conventional and index-linked bonds. The next section examines whether, as we have suggested in Section 3, the downward tilt can be explained in terms of interest rate volatility. 17

18 6. Forward Rate Spreads and Yield Volatility: Empirical Analysis 6.1. Do Forward Rate Spreads Predict Interest Rate Volatility? In this section we use equation (3.14) to investigate the relation between the volatility of zero coupon rates and the spread in long term forward rates. Our analysis is restricted to the data on US Treasury STRIPs since these allow us to observe forward rates directly; the other estimates (McCulloch and Kwon, Fisher, Nychka and Zervos and our own calculations for UK gilts) are all potentially subject to the influence of the estimation methodology. Equation (3.14) predicts that the shape of the long term forward rate curve is quadratic in maturity and this suggests the following cross sectional regression to obtain an estimate of volatility from the shape of the forward rate curve: f(t, τ j )=β 0 + β 1 τ 2 j + ε j τ j τ 0 (6.1) where τ 0 is a long maturity, e.g., 15 years and ε j is an error term capturing the effects of the missing terms in equation (3.14) and also estimation error in the forward rates. In equation (6.1) the predicted value of the coefficient β 1 is negative and equal to 1/2σ 2 l. In this section we give the results of estimating the implied zero coupon yield volatility, σ l, from equation (6.1) and then using this estimate as a predictor of time series volatility. Estimates of β 1 obtained from individual term structures are likely to be imprecise as a result of observation error in the forward rates and this will lead to bias in subsequent regressions of time series volatility on implied volatility. There are a number of approaches which could be pursued at this point but the one we have chosen to adopt is simply to average equation (6.1) over periods of between two to four months and then to regress average forward rates on squared maturity 19. Figure 3 shows the results of estimating equation (6.1) in this manner. We use estimates of forward rates for annual maturities of between 15 and 26 years, derived from daily STRIP prices using equation (4.1). We then form averages of the forward rates over three month intervals and estimate equation (6.1) using 19 Because the regressors are the same for each cross section, we would obtain exactly the same results if the regressions were carried out on individual cross-sections of forward rates and the regression coefficients averaged over time. 18

19 OLS. The figure shows the time series of estimates of the volatility parameter, σ l, derived from the estimate of the slope coefficient in (6.1) using: σ l = 2 β 1. (6.2) By way of comparison, the figure also shows the time series of the volatility of two-day changes in the 20-year zero coupon rate, also derived from STRIPs data, for the same three month intervals. The estimated value of β 1 was negative in each of the 37 three month intervals and the mean value of the implied volatility was 83 basis points compared with the mean time series estimate for the 20year zero-coupon rate of 93 basis points. As with implied volatilities from option prices, the implied volatility derived from the cross sectional regression (6.1) can be regarded as a predictor of time series volatility. Accordingly we have regressed the time series volatility for the k th M-month interval on the implied volatility for the (k 1) st interval. The results are shown in Table 4 which also includes, for purposes of comparison, regressions of period k time series volatility on contemporaneous (period k) implied volatility. In the table the first column gives M, the number of months data used in computing both the time series volatility and average forward rates. Panel (a) gives results for the entire sample period (April 1985 to October 1994). The third row, for example, shows the results, for M =3, of regressing period-k time series volatility on period-k implied volatility. The difference between the coefficient on implied volatility, 0.929, and unity is small and not statistically significant and, although these observations are derived from the same period in calendar time, it should be noted that the estimate of volatility derived from cross sections of forward rates is independent of the temporal sequence of the data. The regression reported in the fourth row of Table 4 examines the predictive power of volatility estimates derived from forward rates for future volatility. Here the time series volatility for period k is regressed on the implied volatility for period k 1. The coefficient on implied volatility is lower (0.825) but still less than one standard error from unity 20. The remaining regressions in panel (a) examine the effect of averaging the forward rates over shorter (2 months) and longer (4 month) periods. Overall this does not make a substantial difference to the coefficients (although the problems 20 The table shows Newey-West corrected standard errors with one lag. 19

20 of serial correlation appear somewhat less severe with a four month estimation period). Close examination of the data shows that (a) the STRIP data appear much noisier in the early part of the sample (possibly as a result of limited liquidity in the earlier years of the market) and (b) that the period including the crash gives rise to a large outlier in many of the regressions. We were concerned that the results in panel (a) might have been affected by these factors and we have therefore re-estimated the results presented in panel (a) excluding the data up to and including the crash. However, the results, shown in panel (b), are little changed. For the three regressions on lagged implied volatility, the coefficient is closer to unity for M =2months and a little further away for M =3months and M =4months Does Interest Rate Volatility Explain the Forward Rate Spread? The previous section looked at the question of whether the shape of the term structure - implied volatility derived from forward rates - predicts the volatility of long term zero coupon yields. Here we reverse the question and ask whether a prediction of volatility can explain the shape of the forward curve. It would be possible to use a time series estimate of volatility (e.g., a conventional standard deviation or, perhaps an ARCH/GARCH, estimate) as our forecast. But it seems preferable to use a forward looking estimate which reflects agents expectations and we have therefore used the implied volatility on bond futures options. The implied volatilities are those on a near-maturity at-the-money option. As the time-to-maturity becomes short the option for which the implied volatility is calculated switches to the next shortest option. The implied standard deviation (ISD) is computed using a Black-Scholes-like formula and, ignoring features such as delivery options and so forth, may be regarded as the anticipated volatility of proportional price changes of the cheapestto-deliver (CTD) bond. This is to be contrasted with the arithmetic yield changes required by equation (3.14). If the CTD bond underlying the futures contract has modified duration D, then we may compute the volatility of arithmetic changes in the yield-to-maturity of the CTD bond as: σ y = 1 D σ p. (6.3) In fact our data do not allow us to determine the modified duration of the CTD 20

21 bond and we therefore assume that this is constant; in other words, we simply use the futures options ISD as an index of anticipated bond market volatility 21. We proceed in two stages. First, we regress time-series volatility in period k on futures options ISD in period k 1 to derive a forecasting rule for yield volatility. Next, we use this rule to generate a time series of forecasts of yield volatility and, using equation (3.14), the expected spread between forward rates at 25 years and forward rates at 15 years. Finally, we regress the actual average forward rate spread for period k on the period k-1 forecasts of the spread. Table 5 gives the estimated prediction rule for yield volatility: the option ISD is always significant and, overall, explains around 15 to 20percent of the variability in next period s volatility. When we regress time series volatility on option ISD for the same period (not reported), the R-bar squared is almost 70%. Thus it appears that option ISD is strongly related to realised volatility but that with a forecast horizon of three months much of the variability of volatility is unpredictable. In Table 6 we regress the period k average forward rate spread between 25 and 15 years on the expected spread. The latter variable is computed as follows. We use the forecast for volatility given by the second row of Table 5, i.e., we set M to three months and, using the average ISD for the last ten days of period k 1, we compute the expected volatility of the 20-year zero coupon rate for period k. We then use equation (3.14) to compute the expected forward rate spread for period k. In the Table 6 the coefficient on the expected spread is with a standard error of 0.14 and, although over two standard errors below the expected value of one, nonetheless much different from zero. The R-bar squared in this case is When a dummy for the crash is included, the coefficient moves closer to unity (0.68) and the R-bar squared rises marginally. 7. Conclusion It has long been known that, in models which (a) admit uncertainty in future interest rates and (b) are consistent with the no-arbitrage condition, the term structure of yields depends on the anticipated level of volatility even in the absence of risk premia. 22 After all, one has only to look at the pricing formulae in models such as Vasicek (1977) and Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (1985). What has, perhaps not 21 Evenifwedidknow the duration of the CTD bond, we could not safely assume that the volatility of its yield to maturity is equal to the volatility of long term zero coupon yields. 22 Or, equivaliently, under risk-neutral dynamics. 21

22 been properly appreciated before, is that (a) the effects of interest rate volatility are to be found most strongly in the yields on long term bonds, (b) these effects result in a strong regularity in the term structure of forward rates, the downward tilt and (c) that estimates of implied zero coupon yield volatility can be easily obtained from the size of the tilt. In this paper we have first attempted to document the persistence of the downward tilt in long term forward rates. A number of data sources on both US and UK bond markets show that forward spreads are habitually negative. Using a simple two-factor Gaussian model we have derived a simple relation between the difference in long term forward rates at two maturities (the forward rate spread ). Finally, we have tested this theory by looking both at the ability of forward rate spreads to predict interest rate volatility and at the extent to which the forward rate may be predicted using a measure of agents expectations of volatility. Both tests broadly support the theory. 22

23 References 1. Barone E., Cuoco D. & Zautzik E. (1991). Term structure estimation using the Cox, Ingersoll and Ross model: The case of Italian Treasury bonds, Journal of Fixed Income 1, pp Bootle R. (1991). Index-linked Gilts: a practical investment guide, second edition, (Woodhead-Faulkner, Cambridge, UK). 3. Brown R.H. & Schaefer S.M. (1994a). The term structure of real interest rates and the Cox, Ingersoll and Ross model, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 35, pp Brown R.H. & Schaefer S.M. (1994b). Interest rate volatility and the shape of the term structure, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A, Vol. 347, pp Brown S.J. & Dybvig P.H. (1986). The empirical implications of the Cox, Ingersoll, Ross theory of the term structure of interest rates, Journal of Finance, Vol. 41, pp Caverhill, Andrew (1998), Modelling Long Term Forward Rates via the Kalman Filter, Working Paper, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology. 7. Cox J.C., Ingersoll J.E. & Ross S.A. (1985). A theory of the term structure of interest rates, Econometrica, Vol. 53, pp Dia, Q. and Singleton K., (1998). Specification Analysis of Affine Term Structure Models, Working Paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. 9. Deacon, M. & Derry A., (1994). Deriving EStimates of Inflation Expectations from the Prices of UK Government Bonds. Bank of England working paper no. 23. (July) 10. Duffie D. & Kan R. (1996). A yield-factor model of interest rates, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 6, Fisher M.E., Nychka D. & Zervos D (1994). Fitting the term structure of interest rates with smoothing splines, unpublished working paper Federal Reserve Board, January. 23

24 12. Langetieg, T A Multivariate Model of the Term Structure, Journal of Finance, 35, Litterman R., Scheinkman J. & Weiss L. (1991) Volatility and the yield curve, Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 1, No. 1, June, pp Litterman R. & Scheinkman J. (1991). Common factors affecting bond returns, Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 1, No. 1, June, pp Longstaff F.A. & Schwartz E.S. (1992). Interest rate volatility and the term structure: a two-factor general equilibrium model, Journal of Finance, Vol. 47, No. 4, pp McCulloch J. Huston, (1975). The tax adjusted yield curve Journal of Finance, Vol. 30, pp McCulloch, J. Huston & Heon-Chul Kwon (1993). U.S. term structure data, , unpublished working paper 93-6, Ohio State University. 18. Merton, R.C. (1970) A Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of the Asset Market and its Application to the Pricing of the Capital Structure of the Firm, Working Paper No , A.P. Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, MA. 19. Nelson, C.R. and A.F. Siegel (1987), Parsimonious Modeling of Yield Curves, Journal of Business, Vol. 60, pp Schaefer S. M. (1981). Measuring a tax-specific term structure of interest rates in the market for British government securities, The Economic Journal, Vol. 91, pp Vasicek O. (1977). An equilibrium characterization of the term structure, Journal of Financial Economics 5, pp Vasicek, O.A. and H.G. Fong (1982), Term Structure Modeling Using Exponential Splines, Journal of Finance, Vol. 37, pp

25 Appendices A. Estimation of Mean Reversion Parameters This appendix describes our method of estimating the mean reversion parameters κ x and κ y. Since ours is a two-factor linear model the covariance matrix of zero-coupon yields has rank two. It is simple to show that the two eigenvectors associated with the covariance matrix of zero coupon yields are linearly related to the functions B x (τ) and B y (τ). The latter depend only on the mean reversion coefficients, the correlation coefficient and maturity and our method estimates the mean reversion coefficients, and the correlation coefficient, from the eigenvectors. We have carried out a principal components analysis on weekly changes in zero coupon rates, derived from the prices of US Treasury STRIPs, with annual maturities between 2 years and 26 years using data for the period December 1988 to October Table A1 shows the eigenvalues and the percentage of total variance explained by the first eight principal components. Around 86% of total variance is accounted for by the first principal component and 95.5% by the first two. Thus the assumption of that prices are determined by two factors seems reasonable and we use the first two eigenvectors to infer the mean reversion coefficients κ x and κ y. Using the notation used above, the vector of innovations in zero coupon yields, R t, is related to the innovations in the state variables x and y by: R t = [ B x /τ B y /τ ] ( x y ), (A.1) where { } B x(y) = B j x(y)(τ j ). Denoting the eigenvectors of the covariance matrix of R t as EV 1 and EV 2 we may also write R t in terms of the principal components p: R t = [ EV 1 EV 2 ] p. (A.2) The state variables {x, y} and the principal components are linearly related (the principal components are simply the state variables of the same model rewritten in terms of orthogonal state variables) and so, for some (2 by 2) weighting matrix, W,wemaywrite: 25

UNITED KINGDOM DEBT MANAGEMENT OFFICE. The DMO's Yield Curve Model

UNITED KINGDOM DEBT MANAGEMENT OFFICE. The DMO's Yield Curve Model United Kingdom Debt Management Office Cheapside House 138 Cheapside London EC2V 6BB UNITED KINGDOM DEBT MANAGEMENT OFFICE The DMO's Yield Curve Model July 2000 The DMO s yield curve model Introduction

More information

CREATING A CORPORATE BOND SPOT YIELD CURVE FOR PENSION DISCOUNTING DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF ECONOMIC POLICY WHITE PAPER FEBRUARY 7, 2005

CREATING A CORPORATE BOND SPOT YIELD CURVE FOR PENSION DISCOUNTING DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF ECONOMIC POLICY WHITE PAPER FEBRUARY 7, 2005 CREATING A CORPORATE BOND SPOT YIELD CURVE FOR PENSION DISCOUNTING I. Introduction DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF ECONOMIC POLICY WHITE PAPER FEBRUARY 7, 2005 Plan sponsors, plan participants and

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

the term structure of interest rates

the term structure of interest rates Exposure Draft A framework Yield for Curve Extrapolation estimating and long term nominal and interest extrapolating rate target settingv Yield Curve Extrapolation and long term nominal interest rate target

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES Chapter - The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models 780 w Interest Rate Models The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates Before discussing how a bond market-maker would delta-hedge, we first need to specify how bonds behave. Suppose we try to model a zero-coupon

More information

Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds)

Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds) Zero-Coupon Bonds (Pure Discount Bonds) The price of a zero-coupon bond that pays F dollars in n periods is F/(1 + r) n, where r is the interest rate per period. Can meet future obligations without reinvestment

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES 1. Expectations hypothesis. The yields on long-term bonds are geometric averages of present and expected future short rates. An upward sloping curve is

More information

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts

10. Fixed-Income Securities. Basic Concepts 0. Fixed-Income Securities Fixed-income securities (FIS) are bonds that have no default risk and their payments are fully determined in advance. Sometimes corporate bonds that do not necessarily have certain

More information

The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER 13

The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER 13 The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER 13 Chapter Summary Objective: To explore the pattern of interest rates for different-term assets. The term structure under certainty Forward rates Theories

More information

Investments Analysis

Investments Analysis Investments Analysis Last 2 Lectures: Fixed Income Securities Bond Prices and Yields Term Structure of Interest Rates This Lecture (#7): Fixed Income Securities Term Structure of Interest Rates Interest

More information

Chapter 3 Fixed Income Securities

Chapter 3 Fixed Income Securities Chapter 3 Fixed Income Securities Road Map Part A Introduction to finance. Part B Valuation of assets, given discount rates. Fixed-income securities. Stocks. Real assets (capital budgeting). Part C Determination

More information

LOS 56.a: Explain steps in the bond valuation process.

LOS 56.a: Explain steps in the bond valuation process. The following is a review of the Analysis of Fixed Income Investments principles designed to address the learning outcome statements set forth by CFA Institute. This topic is also covered in: Introduction

More information

Global Financial Management

Global Financial Management Global Financial Management Bond Valuation Copyright 999 by Alon Brav, Campbell R. Harvey, Stephen Gray and Ernst Maug. All rights reserved. No part of this lecture may be reproduced without the permission

More information

Introduction. example of a AA curve appears at the end of this presentation.

Introduction. example of a AA curve appears at the end of this presentation. 1 Introduction The High Quality Market (HQM) Corporate Bond Yield Curve for the Pension Protection Act (PPA) uses a methodology developed at Treasury to construct yield curves from extended regressions

More information

Estimating Risk free Rates. Aswath Damodaran. Stern School of Business. 44 West Fourth Street. New York, NY 10012. Adamodar@stern.nyu.

Estimating Risk free Rates. Aswath Damodaran. Stern School of Business. 44 West Fourth Street. New York, NY 10012. Adamodar@stern.nyu. Estimating Risk free Rates Aswath Damodaran Stern School of Business 44 West Fourth Street New York, NY 10012 Adamodar@stern.nyu.edu Estimating Risk free Rates Models of risk and return in finance start

More information

Bond valuation and bond yields

Bond valuation and bond yields RELEVANT TO ACCA QUALIFICATION PAPER P4 AND PERFORMANCE OBJECTIVES 15 AND 16 Bond valuation and bond yields Bonds and their variants such as loan notes, debentures and loan stock, are IOUs issued by governments

More information

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Cointegration The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Economic theory, however, often implies equilibrium

More information

M.I.T. Spring 1999 Sloan School of Management 15.415. First Half Summary

M.I.T. Spring 1999 Sloan School of Management 15.415. First Half Summary M.I.T. Spring 1999 Sloan School of Management 15.415 First Half Summary Present Values Basic Idea: We should discount future cash flows. The appropriate discount rate is the opportunity cost of capital.

More information

Volatility Models for Commodity Markets. by Paul L. Fackler and Yanjun Tian

Volatility Models for Commodity Markets. by Paul L. Fackler and Yanjun Tian Volatility Models for Commodity Markets by Paul L. Fackler and Yanjun Tian Suggested citation format: Fackler, P. L., and Y. Tian. 1999. Volatility Models for Commodity Markets. Proceedings of the NCR-134

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

The term structure of Russian interest rates

The term structure of Russian interest rates The term structure of Russian interest rates Stanislav Anatolyev New Economic School, Moscow Sergey Korepanov EvrazHolding, Moscow Corresponding author. Address: Stanislav Anatolyev, New Economic School,

More information

Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model

Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Black-Scholes option pricing model Lognormal price process Call price Put price Using Black-Scholes

More information

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS

NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS 1 NOTES ON THE BANK OF ENGLAND OPTION-IMPLIED PROBABILITY DENSITY FUNCTIONS Options are contracts used to insure against or speculate/take a view on uncertainty about the future prices of a wide range

More information

Pricing Interest-Rate- Derivative Securities

Pricing Interest-Rate- Derivative Securities Pricing Interest-Rate- Derivative Securities John Hull Alan White University of Toronto This article shows that the one-state-variable interest-rate models of Vasicek (1977) and Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross

More information

Alliance Consulting BOND YIELDS & DURATION ANALYSIS. Bond Yields & Duration Analysis Page 1

Alliance Consulting BOND YIELDS & DURATION ANALYSIS. Bond Yields & Duration Analysis Page 1 BOND YIELDS & DURATION ANALYSIS Bond Yields & Duration Analysis Page 1 COMPUTING BOND YIELDS Sources of returns on bond investments The returns from investment in bonds come from the following: 1. Periodic

More information

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 4: Hedging Interest Rate Risk Exposure Traditional Methods

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 4: Hedging Interest Rate Risk Exposure Traditional Methods Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 4: Hedging Interest Rate Risk Exposure Traditional Methods Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Matching maturities Duration Effective duration Multiple

More information

The actual financing costs of English higher education student loans

The actual financing costs of English higher education student loans The actual financing costs of English higher education student loans Neil Shephard, Nuffield College, Oxford & Economics Department, University of Oxford 8/5/2013 Background There has been extensive discussion

More information

Fixed Income: Practice Problems with Solutions

Fixed Income: Practice Problems with Solutions Fixed Income: Practice Problems with Solutions Directions: Unless otherwise stated, assume semi-annual payment on bonds.. A 6.0 percent bond matures in exactly 8 years and has a par value of 000 dollars.

More information

FNCE 301, Financial Management H Guy Williams, 2006

FNCE 301, Financial Management H Guy Williams, 2006 REVIEW We ve used the DCF method to find present value. We also know shortcut methods to solve these problems such as perpetuity present value = C/r. These tools allow us to value any cash flow including

More information

Lecture 12/13 Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Lecture 12/13 Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 1 Lecture 1/13 Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates Alexander K. Koch Department of Economics, Royal Holloway, University of London January 14 and 1, 008 In addition to learning the material

More information

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity Chapter 5 How to Value Bonds and Stocks 5A-1 Appendix 5A The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity In the main body of this chapter, we have assumed that the interest rate

More information

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER NAME: IOANNA KOULLOUROU REG. NUMBER: 1004216 1 Term Paper Title: Explain what is meant by the term structure of interest rates. Critically evaluate

More information

Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds

Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LVI, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2001 Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds EDWIN J. ELTON, MARTIN J. GRUBER, DEEPAK AGRAWAL, and CHRISTOPHER MANN* ABSTRACT The purpose of this article

More information

Constructing Portfolios of Constant-Maturity Fixed- Income ETFs

Constructing Portfolios of Constant-Maturity Fixed- Income ETFs Constructing Portfolios of Constant-Maturity Fixed- Income ETFs Newfound Research LLC December 2013 For more information about Newfound Research call us at +1-617-531-9773, visit us at www.thinknewfound.com

More information

CHAPTER 16: MANAGING BOND PORTFOLIOS

CHAPTER 16: MANAGING BOND PORTFOLIOS CHAPTER 16: MANAGING BOND PORTFOLIOS PROBLEM SETS 1. While it is true that short-term rates are more volatile than long-term rates, the longer duration of the longer-term bonds makes their prices and their

More information

Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román. No. 463

Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román. No. 463 Does the Spot Curve Contain Information on Future Monetary Policy in Colombia? Por : Juan Manuel Julio Román No. 463 2007 tá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá - Colombia - Bogotá

More information

I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems. II. Risks Associated with Default-Free Bonds

I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems. II. Risks Associated with Default-Free Bonds Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 13 Bond Portfolio Management I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. Risks Associated with Default-Free Bonds III. Duration: Details and Examples IV. Immunization

More information

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely Long-Term Interest Rates and Inflation: A Fisherian Approach Peter N. Ireland In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely on long-term bond yields to measure the public s long-term

More information

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS

SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS SAMPLE MID-TERM QUESTIONS William L. Silber HOW TO PREPARE FOR THE MID- TERM: 1. Study in a group 2. Review the concept questions in the Before and After book 3. When you review the questions listed below,

More information

Chapter 8. Step 2: Find prices of the bonds today: n i PV FV PMT Result Coupon = 4% 29.5 5? 100 4 84.74 Zero coupon 29.5 5? 100 0 23.

Chapter 8. Step 2: Find prices of the bonds today: n i PV FV PMT Result Coupon = 4% 29.5 5? 100 4 84.74 Zero coupon 29.5 5? 100 0 23. Chapter 8 Bond Valuation with a Flat Term Structure 1. Suppose you want to know the price of a 10-year 7% coupon Treasury bond that pays interest annually. a. You have been told that the yield to maturity

More information

Answer Key to Midterm

Answer Key to Midterm Econ 121 Money and Banking Instructor: Chao Wei Answer Key to Midterm Provide a brief and concise answer to each question. Clearly label each answer. There are 50 points on the exam. 1. (10 points, 3 points

More information

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies Drazen Pesjak Supervised by A.A. Tsvetkov 1, D. Posthuma 2 and S.A. Borovkova 3 MSc. Thesis Finance HONOURS TRACK Quantitative

More information

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis binomial model replicating portfolio single period artificial (risk-neutral)

More information

MBA Finance Part-Time Present Value

MBA Finance Part-Time Present Value MBA Finance Part-Time Present Value Professor Hugues Pirotte Spéder Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Fall 2002 1 1 Present Value Objectives for this session : 1. Introduce present value

More information

IS THERE A RISK PREMIUM IN CORPORATE BONDS?

IS THERE A RISK PREMIUM IN CORPORATE BONDS? IS THERE A RISK PREMIUM IN CORPORATE BONDS? by Edwin J. Elton,* Martin J. Gruber,* Deepak Agrawal** and Christopher Mann** * Nomura Professors of Finance, Stern School of Business, New York University

More information

Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt

Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt Ian A Cooper and Kjell G Nyborg October 2004 Abstract This paper derives tax-adjusted discount rate formulas with Miles-Ezzell leverage policy,

More information

Bond valuation. Present value of a bond = present value of interest payments + present value of maturity value

Bond valuation. Present value of a bond = present value of interest payments + present value of maturity value Bond valuation A reading prepared by Pamela Peterson Drake O U T L I N E 1. Valuation of long-term debt securities 2. Issues 3. Summary 1. Valuation of long-term debt securities Debt securities are obligations

More information

Chapter 11. Bond Pricing - 1. Bond Valuation: Part I. Several Assumptions: To simplify the analysis, we make the following assumptions.

Chapter 11. Bond Pricing - 1. Bond Valuation: Part I. Several Assumptions: To simplify the analysis, we make the following assumptions. Bond Pricing - 1 Chapter 11 Several Assumptions: To simplify the analysis, we make the following assumptions. 1. The coupon payments are made every six months. 2. The next coupon payment for the bond is

More information

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity

Fixed Income Portfolio Management. Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity Fixed Income ortfolio Management Interest rate sensitivity, duration, and convexity assive bond portfolio management Active bond portfolio management Interest rate swaps 1 Interest rate sensitivity, duration,

More information

CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS

CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS PROBLEM SETS 1. The bond callable at 105 should sell at a lower price because the call provision is more valuable to the firm. Therefore, its yield to maturity should

More information

LIFE INSURANCE AND WEALTH MANAGEMENT PRACTICE COMMITTEE AND GENERAL INSURANCE PRACTICE COMMITTEE

LIFE INSURANCE AND WEALTH MANAGEMENT PRACTICE COMMITTEE AND GENERAL INSURANCE PRACTICE COMMITTEE LIFE INSURANCE AND WEALTH MANAGEMENT PRACTICE COMMITTEE AND GENERAL INSURANCE PRACTICE COMMITTEE Information Note: Discount Rates for APRA Capital Standards Contents 1. Status of Information Note 3 2.

More information

The information content of lagged equity and bond yields

The information content of lagged equity and bond yields Economics Letters 68 (2000) 179 184 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase The information content of lagged equity and bond yields Richard D.F. Harris *, Rene Sanchez-Valle School of Business and Economics,

More information

Term Structure of Interest Rates

Term Structure of Interest Rates Appendix 8B Term Structure of Interest Rates To explain the process of estimating the impact of an unexpected shock in short-term interest rates on the entire term structure of interest rates, FIs use

More information

6. Debt Valuation and the Cost of Capital

6. Debt Valuation and the Cost of Capital 6. Debt Valuation and the Cost of Capital Introduction Firms rarely finance capital projects by equity alone. They utilise long and short term funds from a variety of sources at a variety of costs. No

More information

Bond Price Arithmetic

Bond Price Arithmetic 1 Bond Price Arithmetic The purpose of this chapter is: To review the basics of the time value of money. This involves reviewing discounting guaranteed future cash flows at annual, semiannual and continuously

More information

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13 Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 8th Ed, Ch 13, Copyright John C. Hull 2013 1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Random Walk Assumption

More information

WORKING PAPER CENTRAL BANK OF ICELAND. A Variance Decomposition of Index-Linked Bond Returns. No. 57. By Francis Breedon

WORKING PAPER CENTRAL BANK OF ICELAND. A Variance Decomposition of Index-Linked Bond Returns. No. 57. By Francis Breedon WORKING PAPER CENTRAL BANK OF ICELAND No. 57 A Variance Decomposition of Index-Linked Bond Returns By Francis Breedon January 2012 Central Bank of Iceland Working Papers are published by the Economics

More information

Duration and convexity

Duration and convexity Duration and convexity Prepared by Pamela Peterson Drake, Ph.D., CFA Contents 1. Overview... 1 A. Calculating the yield on a bond... 4 B. The yield curve... 6 C. Option-like features... 8 D. Bond ratings...

More information

The US Municipal Bond Risk Model. Oren Cheyette

The US Municipal Bond Risk Model. Oren Cheyette The US Municipal Bond Risk Model Oren Cheyette THE US MUNICIPAL BOND RISK MODEL Overview Barra s integrated risk model includes coverage of municipal bonds accounting for marketwide and issuer-specific

More information

Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry

Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry Learning Curve Using Bond Futures Contracts for Trading and Hedging Moorad Choudhry YieldCurve.com 2004 Page 1 A widely used risk management instrument in the debt capital markets is the government bond

More information

9 Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio UNCORRECTED PROOFS. Carol Alexander 9.1 MAPPING PORTFOLIOS TO CONSTANT MATURITY FUTURES 12 T 1)

9 Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio UNCORRECTED PROOFS. Carol Alexander 9.1 MAPPING PORTFOLIOS TO CONSTANT MATURITY FUTURES 12 T 1) Helyette Geman c0.tex V - 0//0 :00 P.M. Page Hedging the Risk of an Energy Futures Portfolio Carol Alexander This chapter considers a hedging problem for a trader in futures on crude oil, heating oil and

More information

When to Refinance Mortgage Loans in a Stochastic Interest Rate Environment

When to Refinance Mortgage Loans in a Stochastic Interest Rate Environment When to Refinance Mortgage Loans in a Stochastic Interest Rate Environment Siwei Gan, Jin Zheng, Xiaoxia Feng, and Dejun Xie Abstract Refinancing refers to the replacement of an existing debt obligation

More information

Explaining the Lehman Brothers Option Adjusted Spread of a Corporate Bond

Explaining the Lehman Brothers Option Adjusted Spread of a Corporate Bond Fixed Income Quantitative Credit Research February 27, 2006 Explaining the Lehman Brothers Option Adjusted Spread of a Corporate Bond Claus M. Pedersen Explaining the Lehman Brothers Option Adjusted Spread

More information

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study

A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study A Review of Cross Sectional Regression for Financial Data You should already know this material from previous study But I will offer a review, with a focus on issues which arise in finance 1 TYPES OF FINANCIAL

More information

Understanding duration and convexity of fixed income securities. Vinod Kothari

Understanding duration and convexity of fixed income securities. Vinod Kothari Understanding duration and convexity of fixed income securities Vinod Kothari Notation y : yield p: price of the bond T: total maturity of the bond t: any given time during T C t : D m : Cashflow from

More information

Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt

Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt Tax-adjusted discount rates with investor taxes and risky debt Ian A Cooper and Kjell G Nyborg October 2005, first version October 2004 Abstract This paper derives tax-adjusted discount rate formulas with

More information

Variance Reduction. Pricing American Options. Monte Carlo Option Pricing. Delta and Common Random Numbers

Variance Reduction. Pricing American Options. Monte Carlo Option Pricing. Delta and Common Random Numbers Variance Reduction The statistical efficiency of Monte Carlo simulation can be measured by the variance of its output If this variance can be lowered without changing the expected value, fewer replications

More information

YIELD CURVE GENERATION

YIELD CURVE GENERATION 1 YIELD CURVE GENERATION Dr Philip Symes Agenda 2 I. INTRODUCTION II. YIELD CURVES III. TYPES OF YIELD CURVES IV. USES OF YIELD CURVES V. YIELD TO MATURITY VI. BOND PRICING & VALUATION Introduction 3 A

More information

Forward Contracts and Forward Rates

Forward Contracts and Forward Rates Forward Contracts and Forward Rates Outline and Readings Outline Forward Contracts Forward Prices Forward Rates Information in Forward Rates Reading Veronesi, Chapters 5 and 7 Tuckman, Chapters 2 and 16

More information

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach

Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach Valuation of Razorback Executive Stock Options: A Simulation Approach Joe Cheung Charles J. Corrado Department of Accounting & Finance The University of Auckland Private Bag 92019 Auckland, New Zealand.

More information

CHAPTER 10 BOND PRICES AND YIELDS

CHAPTER 10 BOND PRICES AND YIELDS CHAPTER 10 BOND PRICES AND YIELDS 1. a. Catastrophe bond. Typically issued by an insurance company. They are similar to an insurance policy in that the investor receives coupons and par value, but takes

More information

Estimating Volatility

Estimating Volatility Estimating Volatility Daniel Abrams Managing Partner FAS123 Solutions, LLC Copyright 2005 FAS123 Solutions, LLC Definition of Volatility Historical Volatility as a Forecast of the Future Definition of

More information

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING OPTION PRICING Options are contingency contracts that specify payoffs if stock prices reach specified levels. A call option is the right to buy a stock at a specified price, X, called the strike price.

More information

15.062 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review

15.062 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review .6 Data Mining: Algorithms and Applications Matrix Math Review The purpose of this document is to give a brief review of selected linear algebra concepts that will be useful for the course and to develop

More information

Financial Mathematics for Actuaries. Chapter 8 Bond Management

Financial Mathematics for Actuaries. Chapter 8 Bond Management Financial Mathematics for Actuaries Chapter 8 Bond Management Learning Objectives 1. Macaulay duration and modified duration 2. Duration and interest-rate sensitivity 3. Convexity 4. Some rules for duration

More information

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models 1 Asset Pricing Model a logical extension of portfolio selection theory is to consider the equilibrium asset pricing consequences of investors individually

More information

The Central Tendency: A Second Factor in Bond Yields

The Central Tendency: A Second Factor in Bond Yields The Central Tendency: A Second Factor in Bond Yields by Pierluigi Balduzzi New York University Sanjiv Ranjan Das Harvard University Silverio Foresi New York University May 1994. This revision, July 1996.

More information

CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS

CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS CHAPTER 14: BOND PRICES AND YIELDS 1. a. Effective annual rate on 3-month T-bill: ( 100,000 97,645 )4 1 = 1.02412 4 1 =.10 or 10% b. Effective annual interest rate on coupon bond paying 5% semiannually:

More information

Bonds and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: Pricing, Yields, and (No) Arbitrage

Bonds and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: Pricing, Yields, and (No) Arbitrage Prof. Alex Shapiro Lecture Notes 12 Bonds and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: Pricing, Yields, and (No) Arbitrage I. Readings and Suggested Practice Problems II. Bonds Prices and Yields (Revisited)

More information

EURODOLLAR FUTURES PRICING. Robert T. Daigler. Florida International University. and. Visiting Scholar. Graduate School of Business

EURODOLLAR FUTURES PRICING. Robert T. Daigler. Florida International University. and. Visiting Scholar. Graduate School of Business EURODOLLAR FUTURES PRICING Robert T. Daigler Florida International University and Visiting Scholar Graduate School of Business Stanford University 1990-91 Jumiaty Nurawan Jakarta, Indonesia The Financial

More information

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing

Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Stocks paying discrete dividends: modelling and option pricing Ralf Korn 1 and L. C. G. Rogers 2 Abstract In the Black-Scholes model, any dividends on stocks are paid continuously, but in reality dividends

More information

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002 DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS 1. Background Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002 It is now becoming increasingly accepted that companies

More information

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology March 24, 2005 1 Introduction The purchase of an options contract gives the buyer the right to buy call options contract or sell put options contract some

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY

LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/calloptionpricinoofisc

More information

Risk and Return in the Canadian Bond Market

Risk and Return in the Canadian Bond Market Risk and Return in the Canadian Bond Market Beyond yield and duration. Ronald N. Kahn and Deepak Gulrajani (Reprinted with permission from The Journal of Portfolio Management ) RONALD N. KAHN is Director

More information

Interest Rate and Credit Risk Derivatives

Interest Rate and Credit Risk Derivatives Interest Rate and Credit Risk Derivatives Interest Rate and Credit Risk Derivatives Peter Ritchken Kenneth Walter Haber Professor of Finance Weatherhead School of Management Case Western Reserve University

More information

ON THE VALUATION OF CORPORATE BONDS

ON THE VALUATION OF CORPORATE BONDS ON THE VALUATION OF CORPORATE BONDS by Edwin J. Elton,* Martin J. Gruber,* Deepak Agrawal** and Christopher Mann** * Nomura Professors, New York University ** Doctoral students, New York University 43

More information

Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number

Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) If during the past decade the average rate of monetary growth

More information

http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded on Tue, 19 Feb 2013 17:28:43 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded on Tue, 19 Feb 2013 17:28:43 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions A Significance Test for Time Series Analysis Author(s): W. Allen Wallis and Geoffrey H. Moore Reviewed work(s): Source: Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 36, No. 215 (Sep., 1941), pp.

More information

Problems and Solutions

Problems and Solutions 1 CHAPTER 1 Problems 1.1 Problems on Bonds Exercise 1.1 On 12/04/01, consider a fixed-coupon bond whose features are the following: face value: $1,000 coupon rate: 8% coupon frequency: semiannual maturity:

More information

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida

ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS. Denis Bell. University of North Florida ARBITRAGE-FREE OPTION PRICING MODELS Denis Bell University of North Florida Modelling Stock Prices Example American Express In mathematical finance, it is customary to model a stock price by an (Ito) stochatic

More information

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates

IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011. Top down approaches to discount rates IASB/FASB Meeting Week beginning 11 April 2011 IASB Agenda reference 5A FASB Agenda Staff Paper reference 63A Contacts Matthias Zeitler mzeitler@iasb.org +44 (0)20 7246 6453 Shayne Kuhaneck skuhaneck@fasb.org

More information

(Arbitrage-Free, Practical) Modeling of Term Structures of Government Bond Yields

(Arbitrage-Free, Practical) Modeling of Term Structures of Government Bond Yields (Arbitrage-Free, Practical) Modeling of Term Structures of Government Bond Yields Background Diebold and Li (2006), Forecasting the Term Structure of Government Bond Yields, J. Econometrics. Diebold, Rudebusch

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

Coupon Bonds and Zeroes

Coupon Bonds and Zeroes Coupon Bonds and Zeroes Concepts and Buzzwords Coupon bonds Zero-coupon bonds Bond replication No-arbitrage price relationships Zero rates Zeroes STRIPS Dedication Implied zeroes Semi-annual compounding

More information

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging 1 Market Makers 2 Market-Making and Bond-Pricing On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging 1 Market Makers 2 Market-Making and Bond-Pricing What to market makers do? Provide

More information