Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model



Similar documents
OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

DERIVATIVE SECURITIES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price

Lecture 5: Forwards, Futures, and Futures Options

Lecture 21 Options Pricing

BINOMIAL OPTIONS PRICING MODEL. Mark Ioffe. Abstract

Lecture 3: Put Options and Distribution-Free Results

Introduction to Options. Derivatives

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 4: Hedging Interest Rate Risk Exposure Traditional Methods

Chapter 11 Options. Main Issues. Introduction to Options. Use of Options. Properties of Option Prices. Valuation Models of Options.

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

Understanding N(d 1 ) and N(d 2 ): Risk-Adjusted Probabilities in the Black-Scholes Model 1

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

Four Derivations of the Black Scholes PDE by Fabrice Douglas Rouah

CS 522 Computational Tools and Methods in Finance Robert Jarrow Lecture 1: Equity Options

Lecture 12: The Black-Scholes Model Steven Skiena. skiena

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Friday, September 14, 12

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber

The Black-Scholes Formula

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

Hedging Illiquid FX Options: An Empirical Analysis of Alternative Hedging Strategies

Stock. Call. Put. Bond. Option Fundamentals

Invesco Great Wall Fund Management Co. Shenzhen: June 14, 2008

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING

Journal of Financial and Economic Practice

Fundamentals of Futures and Options (a summary)

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

Financial Options: Pricing and Hedging

where N is the standard normal distribution function,

On Market-Making and Delta-Hedging

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

Options/1. Prof. Ian Giddy

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

Chapter 8 Financial Options and Applications in Corporate Finance ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Option Pricing Beyond Black-Scholes Dan O Rourke

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas Words: 3441

CHAPTER 5 OPTION PRICING THEORY AND MODELS

Convenient Conventions

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

Chapter 21 Valuing Options

Consider a European call option maturing at time T

Overview. Option Basics. Options and Derivatives. Professor Lasse H. Pedersen. Option basics and option strategies

Option Values. Determinants of Call Option Values. CHAPTER 16 Option Valuation. Figure 16.1 Call Option Value Before Expiration

EXP Capital Markets Option Pricing. Options: Definitions. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices 1) C > 0

VALUATION IN DERIVATIVES MARKETS

Part V: Option Pricing Basics

Lecture 17/18/19 Options II

ECMC49F Options Practice Questions Suggested Solution Date: Nov 14, 2005

A Comparison of Option Pricing Models

a. What is the portfolio of the stock and the bond that replicates the option?

Lecture 11: The Greeks and Risk Management

The Intuition Behind Option Valuation: A Teaching Note

Summary of Interview Questions. 1. Does it matter if a company uses forwards, futures or other derivatives when hedging FX risk?

10 Binomial Trees One-step model. 1. Model structure. ECG590I Asset Pricing. Lecture 10: Binomial Trees 1

Black-Scholes Equation for Option Pricing

Option Payoffs. Problems 11 through 16: Describe (as I have in 1-10) the strategy depicted by each payoff diagram. #11 #12 #13 #14 #15 #16

Option Portfolio Modeling

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III

Chapter 21: Options and Corporate Finance

Introduction to Binomial Trees

Pricing Options: Pricing Options: The Binomial Way FINC 456. The important slide. Pricing options really boils down to three key concepts

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

An Introduction to Exotic Options

Conn Valuation Services Ltd.

OPTIONS, FUTURES, & OTHER DERIVATI

Model-Free Boundaries of Option Time Value and Early Exercise Premium

Mathematical Finance

Lecture 7: Bounds on Options Prices Steven Skiena. skiena

American and European. Put Option

Lectures. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. No tutorials in the first week

Lecture 12. Options Strategies

FIN Investments Option Pricing. Options: Definitions. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices. Arbitrage Restrictions on Call Prices

Pricing American Options on Leveraged Exchange. Traded Funds in the Binomial Pricing Model

Other variables as arguments besides S. Want those other variables to be observables.

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Does Black-Scholes framework for Option Pricing use Constant Volatilities and Interest Rates? New Solution for a New Problem

Simplified Option Selection Method

THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL AND EXTENSIONS

Use the option quote information shown below to answer the following questions. The underlying stock is currently selling for $83.

Quantitative Strategies Research Notes

Lecture 15. Sergei Fedotov Introduction to Financial Mathematics. Sergei Fedotov (University of Manchester) / 6

Two-State Option Pricing

Research on Option Trading Strategies

Notes on Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula

Option Values. Option Valuation. Call Option Value before Expiration. Determinants of Call Option Values

1 Introduction to Option Pricing

Risk/Arbitrage Strategies: An Application to Stock Option Portfolio Management

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Introduction to Equity Derivatives

Transcription:

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Black-Scholes option pricing model Lognormal price process Call price Put price Using Black-Scholes Copyright c Philip H. Dybvig 2004

Continuous-Time Option Pricing We have been using the binomial option pricing model of Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein [1979]. In this lecture, we go back to the original modern option pricing model of Black and Scholes [1973]. The mathematical underpinnings of the Black-Scholes model would take a couple of semesters to develop in any formal way, but we can discuss the intuition by viewing it as the limit of the binomial model as the time between trades becomes small. Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes (1973) The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities Journal of Political Economy 81, 637 654 Cox, John C., Stephen A. Ross, and Mark Rubinstein (1979) Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach Journal of Financial Economics 7, 229 263 2

Lognormal stock price process The stock price process in the Black-Scholes model is lognormal, that is, given the price at any time, the logarithm of the price at a later time is normally distributed. (Recall that the normal distribution is the familiar bell curve from statistics.) It is also known how to do option pricing for a continuous-time model with normally distributed prices, but the lognormal model is more reasonable because stocks have limited liability and cannot go negative. In the basic Black-Scholes model there are no dividends. Over a short period of time, the mean rate of return is µ per unit time and the variance is σ 2 per unit time. For s < t, the expected return over the time interval [s, t] is approximately µ(t s): S t S s E µ(t s) S s and the variance is approximately σ 2 (t s): E S t S s µ(t s) S s 2 σ 2 (t s). (Note: µ(t s) is not exactly the correct mean. However, this does not matter since the squared mean is much smaller than the variance over small time intervals. In fact, it would not matter if we didn t subtract the mean at all.) 3

Binomial approximates lognormal when time increment is small probability density stock price 4

Black-Scholes call option pricing formula The Black-Scholes call price is C(S, T ) = SN(x 1 ) BN(x 2 ), where N( ) is the cumulative normal distribution function, T is time-to-maturity, B is the bond price Xe r ft, x 1 = log(s/b) σ + 1 T 2 σ T, and x 2 = log(s/b) σ 1 T 2 σ T. Note that the Black-Scholes option price does not depend on the mean return of the stock. This is because the change to risk-neutral probabilities changes the mean but not the variance. Note that these prices are for European options on stocks paying no dividends. 5

Black Scholes Call Price call option price T=0.00 T=0.25 T=0.50 T=1.00 stock price 6

Intuition: gambler s rule When a call option ends in the money at maturity T periods from now, its value is S T X T, which has value S Xe r ft = S B in the notation above. If the probability of exercise were π and chosen independent of everything in the economy, the option value would be Sπ Bπ. However, we can skew the odds in our favor if we pick and choose when to exercise, which skews the probabilities: SN(x 1 ) BN(x 2 ) where x 1 > x 2. As maturity approaches, both probabilities tend to 1 if the option is in the money or 0 if the option is out of the money. In particular, if we look at x 1 and x 2, they both go to + as the moneyness S/B of the option increases or goes down to as the moneyness decreases. The difference between x 1 and x 2 is the greatest when volatility and time-to-maturity are greatest. *fanciful description due to Stephen Brown 7

Where does Black-Scholes come from? The Black-Scholes formula can be derived as the limit of the binomial pricing formula as the time between trades shrinks, or directly in the continuous time model using an arbitrage argument. The option value is a function of the stock price and time, and the local movement in the stock price can be computed using a result called Itô s lemma, which is an extension of the chain rule from calculus. The standard version of the chain rule does not work, because the stock price in the lognormal model is not differentiable (and cannot be or else stock price would be locally predictable implying the existence of an arbitrage). Even if a function of the stock has zero derivative at a point, its expected rate of increase can be positive due to the volatility of local price movements. Once Itô s lemma is used to calculate the local change in the option value in term of derivatives of the function of stock price and time, absence of arbitrage implies a restriction on the derivatives of the function (in economic terms, risk premium is proportional to risk exposure), essentially similar to the per-period hedge in the binomial model. The absence of arbitrage implies a differential equation that is solved subject to the boundary condition of the known option value at the end. 8

What are the two terms? I am not sure it widely known, but the two terms in Black-Scholes call formula are prices of digital options. The first term SN(x 1 ) is the price of a digital option that pays one share of stock at maturity when the stock price exceeds X: this is a digital option if we measure payoffs in terms of the stock price (this is called using the stock as numeraire and is like a currency conversion). The second term XN(x 2 ) is the price of a short position in a digital option that pays X at maturity when the stock price exceeds X. There is a slightly mystical result that the two terms also represent the portfolio we hold to replicate the option if we want to perform an arb. We can create the call option payoff at the end by holding SN(x 1 ) long in stocks and BN(x 2 ) short in bonds (with trading to vary this continuously as time passes and the stock price evolves). 9

In-class exercise: Black-Scholes put price Derive the Black-Scholes put price. hint: Use the known form of the Black-Scholes call price (SN(x 1 ) BN(x 2 )) and put-call parity (C + B = P + S). 10

Black Scholes Put Price put option price T=0.00 T=0.25 T=0.50 T=1.00 stock price 11

Using the Black-Scholes formula The Black-Scholes model is usually the model of choice when working with a plain vanilla European option pricing application. The binomial model is more flexible and is a better choice for inclusion of a nontrivial American feature, realistic dividends, and other complications. The simplest way to obtain the Black-Scholes call price is to use available tables, a spreadsheet, or a financial calculator. Or, compute the value directly using the formula. The value of N( ) is available in tables or from the approximation in the next slide. Be sure to use the natural logarithm function to compute log(s/b). 12

Cumulative Normal Distribution Function If you want to calculate the formula yourself, there are lots of good approximations to the cumulative normal distribution function. For example, you can use the following procedure for x 0. For x 0, use the procedure on x and the formula N(x) = 1 N( x). First compute t, defined by t 1/(1 0.33267x). Then use t and x to compute N(x) (0.4361836t 0.1201676t 2 + 0.937298t 3 ) exp( x 2 /2)/ 2Π, where Π 3.1415926535 is the familiar numerical constant. If x very close to zero (say.25 < x <.25), as it will be for near-the-money options at short maturities, N(x).5+x/ 2Π.5+0.39894x. Consequently, near-the-money call options are worth about S B 2 +.4 S+B 2 σ T. This is a handy approximation for a meeting or job interview where a quick approximate answer is useful. 13

What interest rate to use The original Black-Scholes derivation assumes that the interest rate is always constant and is the same for all maturities. Of course, the riskless interest rate is not constant, and bonds of different maturities have different yields. In the Black-Scholes formula, the interest rate always appears in e r fτ, which is the price of a riskless pure discount bond with a face value of 1 and a maturity τ periods from now. The generalizations of Black-Scholes suggest that we should use the price of a discount bond maturing with the option and a face equal to the strike price. Traditionally, prices of Treasury securities were used, but now most practitioners use LIBOR instead as Treasuries are viewed as less liquid. 14

What variance to use The choice of variance estimate is even more important than the choice of interest rate in most option pricing applications. Getting the variance wrong can have a big impact on the computed price, and an equally big impact on the effectiveness of a hedge. The two most common methods of determining the appropriate variance are historical estimation and implied variance. In the historical estimation approach, simply look at the variance of historical returns and then adjust for the length of the time horizon. For technical reasons, it is best to use log returns (that is, to compute the sample variance of log(1+ return)). Be sure that your returns are computed correctly, and that you have adjusted properly for any dividends or stock splits. Weekly returns seem like an ideal choice: longer returns give less accurate estimates and are more subject to changes in variance over time, while shorter returns are more contaminated by the bid-ask spread, liquidity distortions, and non-trading effects. After the variance is computed, do the proper adjustment to convert to annual terms. For example, a weekly variance of returns of.0032 corresponds to an annual variance of 52 0.0032 0.16 or an annual standard deviation of 0.16 = 40%. 15

What Variance to Use (continued) The implied variance approach to computing variance is a way of reading market participants assessment of variance. It requires there to be quoted prices available for options on the stock on which the option is written, or for options on a related instrument. The idea is to look at what variance (the implied variance) would be consistent with the option prices you see in the market. In doing so, it is important to get option and stock prices that are as nearly contemporaneous as possible, which is particularly difficult if the stock or its options are thinly traded. This approach is used mostly in active markets (for example, for stock index futures). Practitioners often use implied variances as an indicator of the state of these markets. Of course, individual judgment also enters the equation. For example, if you believe that historical variances were estimated on a particularly turbulent period and that we are in a quieter period, then you should adjust the estimate downward. Or, if you obtain an implied variance that doesn t seem sensible, you should obviously consider whether the price quotes (and your calculations) are reliable. 16

Warning: Black-Scholes is for underlying assets Do not just plug in an interest rate, vol, or other number where the stock price goes in Black-Scholes! If you make this common mistake, the result is nonsense and any decisions based on this mistake are likely to cost you money. The Black- Scholes model assumes in its derivation that we can set up a hedge by going long or short the stock to enforce the pricing. However, there is no asset we can buy today whose price today is the interest rate today and whose price tomorrow is the interest rate tomorrow! 17

Wrap-up Black-Scholes uses the same economics as the binomial model continuous time with a lognormal price process closed form solutions for European call and put prices for the interest rate, use LIBOR for the vol, used historical, implied vol, and/or your own judgment 18