Current Accounts and Demand Transmission in a Two-Country World Econ 182, 11/17/99 Marc Muendler



Similar documents
Chapter 16 Output and the Exchange Rate in the Short Run

= C + I + G + NX ECON 302. Lecture 4: Aggregate Expenditures/Keynesian Model: Equilibrium in the Goods Market/Loanable Funds Market

Real income (Y)

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

dr Bartłomiej Rokicki Chair of Macroeconomics and International Trade Theory Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Warsaw

Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market

These are some practice questions for CHAPTER 23. Each question should have a single answer. But be careful. There may be errors in the answer key!

The level of price and inflation Real GDP: the values of goods and services measured using a constant set of prices

e) Permanent changes in monetary and fiscal policies (assume now long run price flexibility)

International Macroeconommics

1) Explain why each of the following statements is true. Discuss the impact of monetary and fiscal policy in each of these special cases:

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Expenditure Changing and Expenditure Switching policies. In an open economy setting, policymakers need to achieve two goals of

1. a. Interest-bearing checking accounts make holding money more attractive. This increases the demand for money.

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

QUESTION 1: SHORT VERSUS MEDIUM RUN. 30 points

Practice Problems on Current Account

Keynesian Economics I. The Keynesian System (I): The Role of Aggregate Demand

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Multiplier Model

In this chapter we learn the potential causes of fluctuations in national income. We focus on demand shocks other than supply shocks.

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

13. If Y = AK 0.5 L 0.5 and A, K, and L are all 100, the marginal product of capital is: A) 50. B) 100. C) 200. D) 1,000.

Business Conditions Analysis Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 736

Practice Problems on the Capital Market

Econ Spring 2007 Homework 5

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

The Open Economy. Nominal Exchange Rates. Chapter 10. Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy

CHAPTER 15 EXCHANGE-RATE ADJUSTMENTS AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Econ 102 Aggregate Supply and Demand

M.A.PART - I ECONOMIC PAPER - I MACRO ECONOMICS

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 8

The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model. The Short-Run Macro Model

Econ 202 Final Exam. Douglas, Spring 2006 PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Thank You for Attention

CHAPTER 14 BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS ADJUSTMENTS UNDER FIXED EXCHANGE RATES

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

University of Lethbridge Department of Economics ECON 1012 Introduction to Macroeconomics Instructor: Michael G. Lanyi

EC2105, Professor Laury EXAM 2, FORM A (3/13/02)

Macroeconomics V: Aggregate Demand

Chapter 16 THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET AND TRADE ELASTICITIES

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

4 Macroeconomics LESSON 6

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS

chapter: Solution Fiscal Policy

3 Macroeconomics LESSON 8

International Economic Relations

Preparation course MSc Business & Econonomics- Macroeconomics: Introduction & Concepts

UNIT I NATIONAL INCOME AND MACROECONOMICS

Answers. Event: a tax cut 1. affects C, AD curve 2. shifts AD right 3. SR eq m at point B. P and Y higher, unemp lower 4.

1 Multiple Choice - 50 Points

ECON 4423: INTERNATIONAL FINANCE

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Refer to Figure 17-1

INTRODUCTION TO ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS Preliminary Exam with answers September 2014

BADM 527, Fall Midterm Exam 2. Multiple Choice: 3 points each. Answer the questions on the separate bubble sheet. NAME

Introductory Macroeconomics. Richard Povey

Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand

Chapter 11: Extending the Sticky-Price Model: IS- LM, International Side, and AS-AD

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

1. Various shocks on a small open economy

Practiced Questions. Chapter 20

Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Economic Fluctuations Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Preparation course Msc Business & Econonomics

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

IN some countries retail price indexes are used in the adjustment

The Aggregate Demand- Aggregate Supply (AD-AS) Model

CONCEPT OF MACROECONOMICS

Ch. 38 Practice MC 1. In international financial transactions, what are the only two things that individuals and firms can exchange? A.

MGEC61 International Economics: Finance

What you will learn: UNIT 3. Traditional Flow Model. Determinants of the Exchange Rate

8. Simultaneous Equilibrium in the Commodity and Money Markets

Problem Set #4: Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand Econ 100B: Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

How To Explain The Ism

QUIZ Principles of Macroeconomics May 19, I. True/False (30 points)

THE OPEN AGGREGATE DEMAND AGGREGATE SUPPLY MODEL.

Cosumnes River College Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 11 Will Not Be Collected

Lecture The Twin Deficits

(1) A reduction in the lump sum tax (2) A rise in the marginal propensity to import (3) A decrease in the marginal propensity to consume

The Specific-Factors Model: HO Model in the Short Run

How To Understand The Relationship Between A Country And The Rest Of The World

GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC OBJECTIVES AND POLICIES. Textbook, Chapter 26 [pg ]

The Keynesian Cross. A Fixed Price Level. The Simplest Keynesian-Cross Model: Autonomous Consumption Only

1. Firms react to unplanned inventory investment by increasing output.

Pre-Test Chapter 10 ed17

T1 Model Flow Diagrams

Formulas for the Current Account Balance

Long run v.s. short run. Introduction. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

14.02 PRINCIPLES OF MACROECONOMICS QUIZ 3

KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECON INTERNATIONAL TRADE

ECO209 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Chapter 11

Transcription:

Current Accounts and Demand Transmission in a Two-Country World Econ 182, 11/17/99 Marc Muendler The first thought in international economics usually is to consider a small open economy. When doing macroeconomics in this framework, we like to believe that domestic disposable income has an immediate effect on the current account. In fact, the assumption that the current account, CA, is determined solely by domestic disposable income and the real excchange rate lies at the heart of the classic Mundell-Fleming model: CA = CA(Q,Y GN T ) EX(Q) IM(Q,Y GN T )= = EX(Q) Q EX (Q,Y GN T ), where Q E istherealexchangerateand(y GN T ) denotes domestic disposable income. For our simplified economy the current account is roughly equal to net exports EX IM. In a demand-driven world à la Keynes, disposable income immediately affects demand for domestic goods, C, andforeign goods, IM. It does not, however, have any effect on exports, EX. Therefore, the current account worsens when disposable income rises, as domestic residents demand more imports. By our convention for the real exchange rate, a rise in Q means that the real exchange rate depreciates so that exports increase, imports fall, and the current account as a whole improves (as long as the Marshall-Lerner condition holds). 1 Many economies are not small. Why should a change in foreign disposable income not have any impact on our exports? After all, we were already willing to accept that our domestic income does have an immediate effect on the exports of the rest of the world to us. So, if we take this small economy current account one step further to a two-country world, we better write the current as a function of both domestic and foreign disposable income: CA = CA(Q EX(Q,Y GN T,Y GN, T ),Y GN, T ) IM(Q,Y GN T ). With this seemingly innocent assumption we have in fact catapulted our model to a new dimension. Any domestic policy that affects domestic output will now be transmitted abroad through a change in the current account. Whenever 1 The Marshall-Lerner condition states that the demand response of both exports and imports in sum exceeds the price effect. The pure price effect may, however, prevail in the very short run when quantities do not adjust. In fact, the pure price effect of a devaluation would worsen the current account because imports would become relatively more expensive in domestic terms (J-curve). However, in the short but not too short run, quantities will adjust and outweigh the price effect (Marshall-Lerner condition). 1

our domestic disposable income rises, foreign output will, so that the increase in foreign disposable income will spill back into our economy, raise domestic output and thus disposable income, and so forth. When the dust has finally settled, and if no other variable is counteracting, both countries will end up at a new short run equilibrium with higher output. 2 Since we are not trading with the inhabitants of mars or other extraterrestrials, the sum of all current accounts in the world must be equal to zero. Our entire world consists of only two countries. We can therefore be sure that the domestic current account balance must equal the negative of the foreign current account balance. There is one caveat, however: we need to adjust the current account balances with the right exchange rate beforehand. In a two country world there are also two commodity baskets, and two price levels and.by now we are used to the convention that this kind of baskets is a helpful simplification for a macroeconomist, no more and no less. Let the foreign current account CA be expressed in units of the foreign commodity basket, and the domestic current account CA in units of the domestic basket. Then, multiplying the domestic current account balance with the domestic price level, and the foreign current account balance with the foreign price level times the nominal exchange rate will make the two conform to each other in nominal terms: CA = E CA, or CA = CA Q. With these definitions of the current account as a starting point, let us now complete the model. Since good old Keynes is dear to our hearts, we don t hesitate to write domestic output by splitting it up into its least suspect components: Y = C(Y GN T ) I G CA(Q,Y GN T,Y GN, T ). (1) In equilibrium output must be equal to the income it creates Y Y GN. 3 Having said this, we are making the unfortunate discovery that there needs to 2 In fact, a domestic fiscal expansion works exactly in this way because the appreciation in the (domestic) real exchange rate Q will further push foreign output without contracting domestic output too much. In contrast, a domestic monetary expansion will only push up domestic output and contract foreign output. The reason is that the foreign economy will suffer more from the depreciation of the real exchange rate Q than it can benefit from the demand transmission. 3 This, again, is only roughly correct. To be entirely precise, we would have to say that Y = Y GD = C G I EX IM and Y GN = C G K W. Output is best described by gross domestic product Y GD, and national income is best captured by gross national product Y GN. Here investment I = K. W is an increase in a country s net wealth (its foreign asset holdings). 2

be an additional argument. Output is affected by national income both postively (through C( )) and negatively (through IM( ) and hence CA( )). Luckily, macroeconomists are allowed to make assumptions readily. We simply say that the marginal propensity to consume domestic goods C (c =1 s) is larger than the marginal propensity to buy imports IM (m) so that the positive effect of Y GN on Y prevails. Yet, do not sigh too early. Foreign output is even trickier to determine. Since the world s current accounts add up to zero, we can write Y = C(Y GN, T ) I G 1 Q CA(Q,Y GN T,Y GN, T ). (2) Again, foreign national income enters both negatively and positively. This is not the trickiest part yet. After having compared the marginal propensities to consume in the home country, we can simply state with similar confidence: When foreign national income rises, foreign output will increase. But what about the real exchange rate? The same mess once more, it both enters negatively and positively in the foreign output equation. This time we have to dig a little deeper in our bag of tricks. Not too deep, though. We just think back to an assumption that is, by now, an old friend of ours: Marshall Lerner takes care of the current account. When the Marshall-Lerner condition holds, we know that pure price effects have little impact. Therefore, we can simply ignore the 1 Q term in 2. Then foreign output depends negatively on the (domestic) real exchange rate. And this makes a lot of sense. A rising Q means that the real exchange rate is depreciating from a domestic perspective, thus it is appreciating from the foreign country s perspective. Their exports to the home country will decline and their imports from the home country will rise. We have come a long way, but we have still not arrived at a complete twocountry model. We would like to include the domestic money market, the foreign money market and the foreign exchange market, too. Don t worry, we just impose three painless equilibrium conditions that are well known to us and Since the production of Y GD creates income for all the factors that are employed domestically, especially labor L and capital K, wehave Y GD = R K w L, where w denotes the (domestic) wage rate and R the international interest rate (R = R ). In contrast, gross national income also includes income from foreign assets (the country s net wealth): Y GN = R W R K w L. Thus, the precise defintion of the current account is CA = R W EX IM. Since savings are equal to income less expenditure, S = Y GN C G, we can equivalently state that CA = S I = W. As cannot be stressed often enough, a current account surplus is equal to a capital outflow. And a capital outflow is nothing but an increase in a country s net wealth W. 3

then quickly exile them in the back of our minds. The following conditions take care of the three financial markets, respectively: M = L(Y, R) (3) states the requirement that domestic money supply and demand be equal in equilibrium, M = L (Y,R ) (4) states the same for foreign money supply and demand, and the Uncovered Interest arity Condition (UI) R = R Ee E (5) E finally closes the model. uh, five equations, 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5. They will make sure that our five endogenous variables Y, Y, R, R,andE are precisely determined. Still, we don t really want to carry them along. So, let s simplify life again without making it uninteresting. First of all, let s make sure that we keep all the rest of the variables exogenous. In particular, since we are looking at the short-run mainly, let s leave prices sticky. That is, and, the aggregate price levels, remain unchanged. This is neat because every move in the nominal exchange rate E will now directly translate into a change of the real exchange rate Q = E (just magnified or shrinked by a factor ). In addition, we will only make changes to the expected nominal exchange rate E e when it deams sensible, that is, when we are concerned with permanent shocks or permanent policy changes. All other variables are truely exogenous anyway: I and I (because interest rates don t affect them in our model), G and G, M and M, T and T. Then, in a second step, let s pretend that there is nothing special going on in the foreign money market 4. After all, we are living in a symmetric world, and any monetary policy measure abroad will have the same consequences as a monetary policy at home. We only need to change our costumes, relable home as foreign and vice versa. Finally, let s banish equations 3 and 5 to the back of our minds. By now we already know what fiscal and monetary policies do to our nominal exchange rate E in a small open economy. It is a simple exercise to use the Mundell-Fleming model and analyze the impact of autonomous changes in any other variable or functional relationship. The following overview summarizes the findings. 4

Temporary Change in G, T, C( ), CA( ) M,, L( ) ermanent Change in G, T, C( ), CA( ) M,, L( ) Effects on E, R, Q (sticky prices) E, R, Q (sticky prices) E e,e, R, Q (sticky prices) E e,e, R, Q (sticky prices) And that s it. We are down to one diagram if we so choose. If we label the x-axis Y and the y-axis Y, the two equations 1 and 2 undergo a metamorphosis into two curves. A steeper one, called HH and associated with equation 1, and a flatter one, called FF and associated with equation 2. From the little plus and minus signs in the two respective equations 1 and 2 we know where these curves shift when a variable is changed autonomously. And from the above table we know how we get the remaining three dimensions in to the two visible ones. We simply shift the two curves in the direction that the sign in the equation and the arrow in the table indicate. What more can an economist want? Make educated statements about the whole (two-country) world without ever touching more than two thin curves in a plane. 5