Department of Economics The Ohio State University Econ 805 Homework #1 Answers

Similar documents
Chapter 6: Pure Exchange

Walrasian Demand. u(x) where B(p, w) = {x R n + : p x w}.

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem

CONSUMER PREFERENCES THE THEORY OF THE CONSUMER

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2011 Here are some remarks to help you with answering the questions.

Insurance. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Problem Set #5-Key. Economics 305-Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

Homework #5: Answers. b. How can land rents as well as total wages be shown in such a diagram?

Preferences. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Preferences 1 / 20

U = x x x 1 4. What are the equilibrium relative prices of the three goods? traders has members who are best off?

Consumer Theory: The Mathematical Core

Economics 200B Part 1 UCSD Winter 2015 Prof. R. Starr, Mr. John Rehbeck Final Exam 1

Theory of Demand. ECON 212 Lecture 7. Tianyi Wang. Winter Queen s Univerisity. Tianyi Wang (Queen s Univerisity) Lecture 7 Winter / 46

Chapter 4 Online Appendix: The Mathematics of Utility Functions

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

Gains from Trade. Christopher P. Chambers and Takashi Hayashi. March 25, Abstract

Prot Maximization and Cost Minimization

ECON Game Theory Exam 1 - Answer Key. 4) All exams must be turned in by 1:45 pm. No extensions will be granted.

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

CITY AND REGIONAL PLANNING Consumer Behavior. Philip A. Viton. March 4, Introduction 2

A public good is often defined to be a good that is both nonrivalrous and nonexcludable in consumption.

2. Information Economics

Advanced Microeconomics

Lecture Note 7: Revealed Preference and Consumer Welfare

Choice under Uncertainty

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

Problem Set #3 Answer Key

Chapter 25: Exchange in Insurance Markets

To give it a definition, an implicit function of x and y is simply any relationship that takes the form:

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Lecture 2. Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and Constrained Optimization

Labor Demand The Labor Market

PART II THEORY OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOR AND DEMAND

Sample Midterm Solutions

Production Possibilities Frontier and Output Market Efficiency. 1 Production Possibilities Frontier

Lecture 2: Consumer Theory

Multi-variable Calculus and Optimization

No-Betting Pareto Dominance

CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function

REVIEW OF MICROECONOMICS

Table of Contents MICRO ECONOMICS

The fundamental question in economics is 2. Consumer Preferences

POTENTIAL OUTPUT and LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Deriving Demand Functions - Examples 1

Introductory Notes on Demand Theory

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Problem Set 2 1/20/10

Chapter 4. Specific Factors and Income Distribution

TOPIC 4: DERIVATIVES

(First 6 problems from Caves, Frankel and Jones, 1990)

Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economic of Imperfect Information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Economics of Insurance

Chapter 27: Taxation. 27.1: Introduction. 27.2: The Two Prices with a Tax. 27.2: The Pre-Tax Position

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES

All these models were characterized by constant returns to scale technologies and perfectly competitive markets.

Lecture 1: OLG Models

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BEHAVIORAL INDIFFERENCE CURVES. John Komlos. Working Paper

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

Economics I. General equilibrium and microeconomic policy of the state

Econ 100A: Intermediate Microeconomics Notes on Consumer Theory

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

Constrained Optimisation

CHAPTER 4 Consumer Choice

Oligopoly and Strategic Pricing

Price Elasticity of Supply; Consumer Preferences

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

Section 12.6: Directional Derivatives and the Gradient Vector

Utility Maximization

Lesson 19: Equations for Tangent Lines to Circles

Security Pools and Efficiency

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370

How To Find Out How To Balance The Two-Country Economy

Definition and Properties of the Production Function: Lecture

Lecture 11 Uncertainty

On Lexicographic (Dictionary) Preference

Notes V General Equilibrium: Positive Theory. 1 Walrasian Equilibrium and Excess Demand

AK 4 SLUTSKY COMPENSATION

Optimal Nonlinear Income Taxation with a Finite Population

Pre-Test Chapter 23 ed17

Profit and Revenue Maximization

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Constrained optimization.

Choices. Preferences. Indifference Curves. Preference Relations. ECON 370: Microeconomic Theory Summer 2004 Rice University Stanley Gilbert

Adverse Selection and the Market for Health Insurance in the U.S. James Marton

Theoretical Tools of Public Economics. Part-2

Natural Resources and International Trade

Envelope Theorem. Kevin Wainwright. Mar 22, 2004

The Greater the Differences, the Greater the Gains?

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

A Detailed Price Discrimination Example

PPA 723, Fall 2006 Professor John McPeak

Economic Appraisal 5: Performance Measures

SCREENING IN INSURANCE MARKETS WITH ADVERSE SELECTION AND BACKGROUND RISK. Keith J. Crocker

Second degree price discrimination

Transcription:

Prof James Peck Winter 009 Department of Economics The Ohio State University Econ 805 Homework #1 Answers 1. A consumer s offer curve is the locus of tangencies between the budget linesandindifference curves as relative prices change. (See Varian, pp. 316-317.) (i) For a two-person, Edgeworth Box economy, explain why any intersection of the two offer curves is a competitive equilibrium. (ii) What is the equation for the following consumer s offer curve? u(x 1,x )=log(x 1 )+log(x ), (ω 1,ω )=(1, 1). Answer: (i) The absolute value of the slope of the line connecting the endowment point and the offer curve is the price ratio for which the bundle demanded is the point on the offer curve. If two offer curves intersect in an Edgeworth Box diagram, then the intersection point represents a feasible allocation that is utility maximizing for the same price ratio. Thus, the allocation, along with the price ratio equal to the absolute value of the slope of the segment from the endowment to the offer curve, together forms a competitive equilibrium. (ii) Normalizing the price of good to be one and the price of good one to be p, the (necessary and sufficient) first order conditions of the utility maximization problem are x x 1 = p and (1) px 1 + x = p +1. () We want to determine from (1) and () an equation in consumption space, so we must eliminate p. Substituting (1) into (), we have which simplifies to x x 1 x1 + x = x x 1 +1, x = x1 x 1 1. Of course, since we are restricting ourselves to positive consumption, we must have x 1 > 1. In other words, this is a hyperbola, and we restrict ourselves to the curve contained in the nonnegative orthant. 1

. Using an Edgeworth box diagram, provide a counterexample to the second welfare theorem when utility functions are continuous and strictly monotonic, but not necessarily quasi-concave. That is, find an example of a Pareto optimal allocation that cannot be supported as a competitive equilibrium allocation (for any redistribution of initial endowments). Answer: The easiest way to construct a counterexample is to first draw a "typical" Pareto optimal allocation x in the Edgeworth box, with the utility functions nicely behaved, and a tangent line to x. In order to support this PO allocation as a CE, the price line must be this tangent line; any other slope will cut through the indifference curves and not be consistent with utility maximization at that allocation. Next, redraw consumer 1 s indifference curve, so that it now cuts through the budget line somewhere away from x,butdoes not intersect consumer s indifference curve a second time. This will ensure that x remains Pareto optimal, but cannot be supported as a CE allocation. (We will show you an example in recitation.) 3. Suppose there is no market for some commodity (say commodity K). Since consumers cannot trade commodity K, then everyone consumes his/her endowment of that good. A competitive equilibrium is a price vector for the K 1 tradable goods, p =(p 1,..., p K 1 ), and an allocation for all K commodities, satisfying market clearing and the following consumer optimization problem: max u i (x i ) subject to P K 1 j=1 pj x j i P K 1 j=1 pj ω j i x K i = ω K i x i 0. Assume that all utility functions are continuous and strictly monotonic. a) Will the competitive equilibrium be fully Pareto optimal, where dominating allocations can involve reallocations of commodity K as well as the other commodities? b) Will the C.E. be constrained Pareto optimal, where only the first K 1 commodities can be reallocated? Answer: (a) In general, the missing-market competitive equilibrium will not be Pareto optimal in the traditional sense, where dominating allocations can involve reallocations of commodity K as well as the other commodities, because reallocating all K goods can generally create gains from trade. For example, if all utility functions are differentiable, the competitive equilibrium will equate

the marginal rates of substitution for all pairs of goods not including good K. However, it would only be by coincidence that u i x j i u i x K i = u h x j h u h x K h holds for two consumers, i and h. (b) The missing-market competitive equilibrium is Pareto optimal in the constrained sense, where feasible dominating allocations must leave consumption of commodity K unchanged. To see this, consider a hypothetical economy with K 1 goods where consumer i has the endowment vector, eω i = (ω 1 i,..., ωk 1 i ), and the utility function, eu i = u i (x 1 i,..., xi K 1 ; ω K i ). In other words, we treat ω K i as a parameter of the utility function. A missingmarket C.E. of this economy is a C.E. of the hypothetical economy. Under the assumption that the original utility function is strictly monotonic, then eu i satisfies local nonsatiation. Therefore, by the FFTWE, a C.E. allocation of the hypothetical economy is Pareto optimal for the hypothetical economy: there is no way to reallocate the K 1 goods to make all consumers better off. Thus, the missing-market C.E. allocation is constrained Pareto optimal. 4. Consider a pure exchange economy with two consumers, i =1,, andtwo goods. The consumers utility functions are given by u i (x 1 i,x i )=(x1 i )(x i ) and endowments are given by ω i =(a i,b i ) for i =1,. Let p denote the relative price of good 1 in terms of good. (i) Compute the excess demand function for this economy. (ii) Define a competitive equilibrium for this economy. (iii) Find the equilibrium price ratio. (iv) Determine an equation for the contract curve (the set of Pareto optimal points). Answer: (i) Normalizing the price of good to be one and the price of good one to be p, the first order conditions of consumer i s utility maximization problem are x i x 1 i = p and (3) px 1 i + x i = pa i + b i. (4) 3

Solving (3) and (4) for the demand functions yields x 1 i = pa i + b i p and x i = pa i + b i. (5) From (5), the excess demand function is Z 1 (p) = pa 1 + b 1 p Z (p) = pa 1 + b 1 + pa + b p + pa + b a 1 a, (6) b 1 b. (7) (ii) A competitive equilibrium is a (normalized) price vector, (p, 1), and an allocation, (x 1 1,x 1,x 1,x ), suchthat: 1. for i =1,, (x 1 i,x i ) solves. markets clear max x 1 i x i subject to px 1 i + x i pa i + b i, x i 0, x 1 1 + x 1 a 1 + a x 1 + x b 1 + b. (iii) To find the C.E. price ratio, solve the market clearing equation, by setting either (6) or (7) equal to zero. Market clearing for good requires pa 1 + b 1 which can be solved for p, + pa + b b 1 b =0, p = b 1 + b a 1 + a. (8) (iv) Because the utility functions are nicely behaved, the set of Pareto optimal allocations are characterized by utilization of all resources and equal marginal rates of substitution. Thus, we have: x 1 x 1 = x 1 x 1 (9) x 1 = a 1 + a x 1 1 (10) x = b 1 + b x 1 (11) 4

Substituting (10) and (11) into (9), we have x 1 x 1 1 = b 1 + b x 1 a 1 + a x 1. (1) 1 Equation (1) implicitly relates x 1 to x 1 1, so it can be considered an equation for the contract curve. We can simplify (1) to derive the functional relationship, x b1 + b 1 = x 1 a 1 + a 1. (13) 5