HUMAN SETTLEMENT DEVELOPMENT Vol. IV - The Effects of the Transition in Hungary on the Urban Environment - Walter Hook

Similar documents
CITY CLIMATE LEADERSHIP AWARDS

Economic Development and the Risk of Global Climate Change

GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS INVENTORY

AP ENVIRONMENTAL SCIENCE 2012 SCORING GUIDELINES

REPUBLIC OF TURKEY INTENDED NATIONALLY DETERMINED CONTRIBUTION

GERMANY 1. THE CONTEXT... Part I REDUCING THE POLLUTION BURDEN

Transforming America s Energy Future. Kentucky. Energy Statistics. Developed by

Two miles per day may not seem like much, but do the math.

Renewable Choice Energy

Electricity Sources. Coal Fleet

A pound of coal supplies enough electricity to power ten 100-watt light bulbs for about an hour.

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): ENERGY 1

How Humans Impact the Environment. Jonathan M. Links, PhD Johns Hopkins University

This fact sheet provides an overview of options for managing solid

Revealing the costs of air pollution from industrial facilities in Europe a summary for policymakers

Multi-year Expert Meeting on Transport, Trade Logistics and Trade Facilitation

VEHICLE INSPECTION FOR REDUCING EMISSION

Maryland Nuclear Power Plant s Contribution to the State Economy

Natural Gas Vehicles. Fuel of the Future

Academic Reading sample task Identifying information

Annex 5A Trends in international carbon dioxide emissions

Democratic and Republican Positions on Environmental Issues. Edward H. Klevans, Professor and Department Head Emeritus of Nuclear Engineering

Communicating Your Commitment: Your Guide to Clean Energy Messaging

Details on the Carbon Tax (Tax for Climate Change Mitigation)

Dr. István ZÁDOR PhD: Rita MARKOVITS-SOMOGYI: Dr. Ádám TÖRÖK PhD: PhD, MSc in Transportation Engineering, KOGÁT Ltd.

New York s Upstate Nuclear Power Plants Contribution to the State Economy

Green Fleet Policy PURPOSE

HYDROLOGICAL CYCLE Vol. I - Anthropogenic Effects on the Hydrological Cycle - I.A. Shiklomanov ANTHROPOGENIC EFFECTS ON THE HYDROLOGICAL CYCLE

ELECTRIC VEHICLES: THE PORTLAND WAY

Costs of air pollution from European industrial facilities an updated assessment

NEW HAMPSHIRE PIPELINE INSTALLATION

Why Talk About Transport in Africa? SUSTAINABLE URBAN TRANSPORT IN AFRICA: ISSUES AND CHALLENGES. Urbanization and Motorization in Africa

Summary of the Impact assessment for a 2030 climate and energy policy framework

Multiple sources of energy will be available, giving the consumer choices. A Higher Percentage of Energy will come from renewable energy sources

EFFICIENT USE AND CONSERVATION OF ENERGY Vol. II - Energy Efficiency in Mass Transit Systems - Clark W. Gellings, Kelly E.

Green Growth Platform questionnaire Answers submitted by Rahm Emanuel. Chicago s Climate Change Solutions and Clean Energy Future

SEATTLE STEAM COMPANY FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS

Overview of the Heavy-Duty National Program. Need to Reduce Fuel Consumption and Greenhouse Gases from Vehicles

The Global Commission on the Economy and Climate. Major Economies Forum, Paris

Netherlands National Energy Outlook 2014

Carbon Management Plan

Birmingham City University / Students Union Aspects and Impacts Register. Waste. Impacts description

How to implement renewable energy and energy efficiency options

Unit 6: Homework Questions

ANALYSIS OF THE ADMINISTRATION S PROPOSED TAX INCENTIVES FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY AND THE ENVIRONMENT

Liquid Biofuels for Transport

Michigan Nuclear Power Plants Contribution to the State Economy

climate change is happening. This April produced the record for the first month in human history

Main trends in industry in 2014 and thoughts on future developments. (April 2015)

Policy measures for the prevention and minimization of hazardous wastes

Generating Current Electricity: Complete the following summary table for each way that electrical energy is generated. Pros:

Population, Health, and Human Well-Being-- Nigeria

Natural Gas Information Contents

A Green Idea. Reclaiming Urban Wood Waste And Urban Forest Debris. For Fuel/Combustion & Renewable Energy

Introduction to. Aalborg s Sustainability Strategy

Massachusetts Saving Electricity:

Fact Sheet on China s energy sector and Danish solutions

ACCOUNTING FOR ASIA S NATURAL CAPITAL

Environment Situation in Timor-Leste

Population, Health, and Human Well-Being-- Kuwait

POLICY ACTIONS INVESTING IN INNOVATION

POINT SOURCES OF POLLUTION: LOCAL EFFECTS AND IT S CONTROL Vol. I - Point Sources of Pollution: Local Effects and Control - Chen Jining and Qian Yi

World Energy Outlook 2007: China and India Insights. International Energy Agency

Goals Status Current Policies & Programmes GENERAL OVERVIEW

EXAMPLES OF SUCCESSFUL POLICY TOOLS FOR EMISSION REDUCTION

ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF ENERGY SOURCES. Prepared by Sandra Vasa-Sideris, PhD, Southern Polytechnic State University, for use by students

6. Cost Summary and Analysis This chapter summarizes and analyzes the cost estimates from previous chapters.

Critical Policy Options to Protect Industry Competitiveness

Why Some Fuel-Efficient Vehicles Are Not Sold Domestically

Biogas as transportation fuel

Intervention on behalf of Denmark, Norway and Ireland on the occasion of the Open Working Group on Sustainable Development Goals meeting on

Population and the Environment

IS ENERGY IN ESTONIA CHEAP OR EXPENSIVE?

4. Thinking on Uses for Tax Revenues How should revenues from Climate Change Tax be used?

AP Environmental Science 2010 Free-Response Questions

Economic Planning in China by Gregory C. Chow, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 219 June 2011

Energy Consumption Increases Slightly in Renewables Continue to Grow / Advantages Due to Weather, Economic Trend, and Immigration

Comparing Levels of Development

World Simulations with GEM-E3

From Carbon Subsidy to Carbon Tax: India s Green Actions 1

ERCOT Analysis of the Impacts of the Clean Power Plan Final Rule Update

The Economic Impacts of Reducing. Natural Gas and Electricity Use in Ontario

SUBMISSION BY THE UNITED ARAB EMIRATES

SECTOR ASSESSMENT (SUMMARY): BRICK 1

Sustainable city development through smart urban planning

Waste a source of energy. Regional Solid Waste Management Plan Review: Engaging solutions for tomorrow. Incineration. Incineration

rising Electricity Costs:

Economic Outcomes of a U.S. Carbon Tax. Executive Summary

Nuclear power is part of the solution for fighting climate change

CASE STUDY UNIT 3. The Case of the New Power Plant

Planning and Design for Sustainable Urban Mobility

Sustainable Resource Management Ltd

ELECTRICAL ENERGY REDUCTION IN REFRIGERATION AND AIR CONDITIONING Ken Landymore, Director of Operations, Smartcool Systems Inc.

A fuel efficient vehicle fleet for Victoria WHAT THE VICTORIAN GOVERNMENT CAN DO

The Green Road to Growth in South Korea: The Conditions for Success. Prof. Jae-Seung LEE Korea University

Speech at the High-Level Conference on World Food Security

Energy Prices, Climate Change Policy and U.S. Economic Growth

Energy Options in a Carbon Constrained World. Martin Sevior, School of Physics, University of Melbourne

Residential & Commercial Sectors Overview CLIMATE

Transcription:

THE EFFECTS OF THE TRANSITION IN HUNGARY ON THE URBAN ENVIRONMENT Institute for Transportation and Development Policy, USA Keywords: transportation, environment, Central Europe, transitional economies, urban environment, urban sprawl. Contents 1. Introduction 2. Hungary: A Case Study 2.1. Before the Transition 2.2. The Transition 3. Post Transition Changes in Transport Policy 3.1. Changes in Public Transit Policy 3.2. Changes in Road and Highway Sector Policy 3.3. Changes in Rail Policy 4. The Causes of Sprawl in Budapest 4.1. Sprawl, Housing, and Highways 4.2. Suburban and Exurban Commercial Sprawl 4.3. Foreign Investment and Sprawl 4.3.1. Sprawl and Sustainable Development: Push Factors 4.3.2. Sprawl and Sustainable Development: Pull Factors 5. Conclusion Glossary Bibliography Biographical Sketch Summary Hungary s transition from nondemocratic socialism to a democratic market economy is assessed in terms of its impact on the environment. This perspective provides insights into the relationship between these fundamentally different politicaleconomic systems and their environmental outcomes. Hungary before the transition had strict environmental regulations, but weak citizens rights and a weak legal system. As such, these laws were rarely enforced. The pricing system in the sphere of production was also dysfunctional. These two factors led to more polluting and less energyefficient production processes and consumer products than was found in democratic market economies at a similar level of economic development. However, constraints on household consumption in general, constraints on private sector land development, and greater state investment into public transportation and high density housing tended to depress aggregate emissions from the sphere of consumption, most clearly in the transport sector. 346

With the transition, the sources of environmental degradation in Hungary increasingly resemble those of other democratic market economies. In market economies in consumer sectors like transport, pricing and regulatory mechanisms to control pollution are difficult to implement and enforce. Individual consumers decisions about where to shop and live, and what mode of transportation to use respond to highly distorted price signals that encourage the overconsumption of scarce fossil fuels and the generation of socially dysfunctional levels of air and water pollution. However, in the transitional economies like Hungary, these emissions are rapidly surpassing levels in similar developed market economies because the legal and regulatory measures required to curtail them are slower to develop than the economic changes that generated them. 1. Introduction While the transition in Hungary has reduced most forms of environmental degradation, it has increased others; specifically transport sector emissions and the conversion of land to urban uses. It has been a transition from the environmental problems of a socialist, industrial economy to the environmental problems of a mature market economy. In general terms, this has been a transition from productiongenerated pollution to consumptiongenerated pollution. A similar, though not identical shift occurred in Western market economies as well, accompanying the process of deindustrialization, but this transformation occurred much later and much faster in Hungary. The environmental ramifications of the transition in Hungary are best seen in comparison to broader environmental trends. In developed market economies, environmental degradation results mainly because the social costs of polluting are not paid primarily by the polluter; they are paid by generations not yet born, by people too poor to live in neighborhoods free of pollution, and by society as a whole too disorganized to demand compensation or protection. The enforcement of environmental standards based on publichealth criteria, and emerging marketbased forms of environmental control are both mechanisms increasingly used in market economies to make the polluter pay the social costs of the problems they create, and to provide citizens legal protection against environmental degradation. In developed market economies, tightening environmental regulation and enforcement, along with deindustrialization, have gradually reduced industrial pollution. Rather, pollution is increasingly generated by those sectors like transport where the pricing and regulatory mechanisms to make the polluter pay are the most difficult to implement and enforce. The regulation of mobile source air emissions with adverse public health impacts is developing rapidly, but still lags behind the regulation of pointsource pollution. In the United States (US) and Europe, tightening tailpipe emission standards, fuel specifications, and ambient air standards are bringing down or stabilizing concentrations of most vehicular emissions in most major cities. By contrast, in the large cities of Central Europe, and in many developing country megacities, many forms of ambient air pollution are getting worse. Meanwhile, emissions such as greenhouse gases, which primarily pose a threat to future generations, have proven far more difficult to regulate. From 1970 to 1992, carbon 347

dioxide emissions increased from 15 billion tons per year to 22 billion tons, an increase of 28% in Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries and 82% in nonoecd countries. The share of carbon dioxide (CO 2) emissions coming from transport in OECD countries has risen from about 17% to about 31%, and this trend is rapidly repeating itself in developing countries. It is no accident that environmental problems are increasingly concentrating in those areas of the market economy where the pricing mechanism is the most dysfunctional. Oil prices vary from country to country by a factor of 1:100, compared to motor vehicle prices which vary by a factor of 1:2. In most market economies, the state continues to build roads and urban infrastructure with little regard for ensuring that users of the infrastructure bear the full social cost of their use. As a result, individual consumers decisions about where to purchase a home, where to shop, and how to travel are decisions responding to highly distorted price signals, encouraging the overconsumption of scarce fossil fuels and the generation of socially dysfunctional levels of pollution. 2. Hungary: A Case Study 2.1. Before the Transition In Hungary, as was typical in most nondemocratic, largely centrally planned economies of Central Europe (Hungary already had a vibrant private sector at the time of the transition), tight environmental regulations existed on the books, based on a scientific assessment of public health risks, but they were weakly enforced, and mechanisms for citizens to compel the government to enforce these regulations were weak. As the prices of energy were subsidized and much of the economy planned, there was no mechanism to encourage enterprises, housing estates, or individuals to use fuel efficiently, conserve energy, or modernize technology to reduce energy consumption. Hungary as a whole consumed about 25 mega joules of energy per dollar of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) compared to about 21 mega joules in the US, and about 12 in Japan and Western Germany. Factories, power plants, and district heating facilities also relied heavily on lignite, or brown coal, some of it laced with uranium and other heavy metals, and these toxic wastes were not disposed of securely. Industrial towns, like Tatabanya, were and remain some of the most polluted and heavily contaminated areas in Europe. Some 1.3 billion cubic meters of raw sewage were dumped into the Danube and other Hungarian rivers per year, and the water supply in a quarter of Hungarian towns was not potable due to contamination from pesticides and nitrate fertilizers. Thus, air and water pollution from industrial, district heating, and power sectors was worse than in market economies, particularly in the areas immediately adjacent to these facilities. Hungary s planned economy also delayed the transition from an industrial to a postindustrial economy. In 1990, more than half of Hungary's GDP still came from industry, compared to roughly a third in most Western market economies at that time. As a result, Hungary's ambient air quality tended to have higher concentrations of industrial pollutants like sulfur dioxide than market economies at similar levels of GDP. 348

On the other hand, Hungary s central planning system also tended to depress household consumption in order to drive up the rate of investment. The rigidities of the planned economy, after 1980, also tended to depress economic growth in general. Hungary's GDP was roughly 1/7 that of the US in 1990. These two factors reduced consumptionside environmental pollution. As a result, while pollution per vehicle, per factory, or per dollar of GDP were much higher in Hungary than in most OECD countries, aggregate and per capita greenhouse gas emissions, nitrogen oxides and particulate emissions were lower than most OECD countries. The process of the conversion of agricultural and forest land to urban and commercial uses, which also tends to increase greenhouse gases by removing sinks, was also slower. Consumerside emissions were also lower because of the specific ways in which the centrally planned economy affected the built environment. Before the transition, urban areas were fairly high density which tended to conserve energy and encourage public transit use. The public sector was the largest producer of housing, and most of this housing was built in high density housing estates outside the city center, creating the peculiarity of urban areas with higher density in the outer ring than in the center. Nonetheless, these housing estates were conveniently served by public transport, and public transport dominated the urban transport system. In Budapest, the only large city in Hungary with about 2 million people, 73% of trips were made by public transportation in 1989, compared to about 14% in major US cities the same year. Furthermore, just beyond these housing estates was mostly agricultural land, and it was difficult to get permission to convert this land to urban uses. Individual motor vehicles, many of them twostroke engines, were much more polluting in terms of particulates and hydrocarbons, though they generated fewer nitrogen oxides because they had small engines. However, because the motor vehicle fleets were far smaller (about 170 motor vehicles per 1 000 people in Hungary compared to around 700 motor vehicles per 1 000 people in the US in 1990), transport sector air emissions were much lower, with the exception of lead which had not yet been phased out. People did not have as many household electronics, though the ones they did have used energy inefficiently, and electric power was generated by burning brown coal. The housing estates were heated by large centrally controlled district heating centers. On the one hand, the colocation of apartments into large buildings tends to reduce heating fuel consumption per unit. On the other hand, the design of the facilities did not allow residents to adjust temperatures in their apartments and provided no incentives to conserve energy. As a result, aggregate power and heating sector emissions were lower in nitrogen oxide but higher in sulfur dioxide than in most advanced capitalist countries. Ironically, the transportation system in Hungary s planned economy may have more closely mirrored a system where passengers paid the full social costs of their travel than the transportation system in the US. After the New Deal, the US government poured investments and tax expenditures into roads, urban infrastructure, and singlefamily suburban housing with little regard for the fact that these subsidies were greatly distorting the transportation and location decisions of families and investors. As a result, an urban form emerged which consumed more fossil fuels for transportation per capita than any other market economy at a similar level of GDP. United States policy since the New Deal was more concerned with stimulating domestic consumption for the purposes of global macroeconomic stability than getting the prices right. This had fairly 349

profound environmental consequences, making the US the highest producer of CO 2 emissions per capita. Bibliography TO ACCESS ALL THE 17 PAGES OF THIS CHAPTER, Visit: http://www.eolss.net/eolsssampleallchapter.aspx French, Hilary F. (1991). Restoring the East European and Soviet Environments. State of the World 1991. Washington D.C.: Worldwatch Institute. [This article gives a good overview of the environmental situation in Hungary leading up to the transition]. Hook. W. (1999). The Political Economy of PostTransition Transportation Policy in Hungary. Transport Policy 6. 207224. [A journal article by this author covering the transportation issues dealt with in this article in greater detail]. Lucaks, A. and Karoly, K. (1997). Forced March. Budapest: Clean Air Action Group. [This is a collection of essays in English on transport and environment issues in Hungary edited by Hungary s foremost environmental advocate working on transportation issues]. Biographical Sketch is the Executive Director of the Institute for Transportation and Development Policy (ITDP), an international NGO incorporated in the USA to promote environmentally sustainable and equitable transportation policy and projects in developing countries and economies in transition. ITDP gives technical assistance to municipalities in nonmotorized transport, bus rapid transit, traffic demand management, and the reuse of derelict urban land. Mr. Hook received his PhD in Urban Planning at Columbia University in 1996. For more information about ITDP, see www.itdp.org. 350