DOES THE TRUST GAME MEASURE TRUST?

Similar documents
MULTIPLE REGRESSION AND ISSUES IN REGRESSION ANALYSIS

Abstract. Individuals frequently transfer commodities without an explicit contract

Do Supplemental Online Recorded Lectures Help Students Learn Microeconomics?*

RISK MANAGEMENT IN THE INVESTMENT PROCESS

Charity as a Signal of Trustworthiness

Introduction to Quantitative Methods

Association Between Variables

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Chapter 7: Multiple regression analysis with qualitative information: Binary (or dummy) variables

CONTENTS OF DAY 2. II. Why Random Sampling is Important 9 A myth, an urban legend, and the real reason NOTES FOR SUMMER STATISTICS INSTITUTE COURSE

Work incentives and household insurance: Sequential contracting with altruistic individuals and moral hazard

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

NCSS Statistical Software Principal Components Regression. In ordinary least squares, the regression coefficients are estimated using the formula ( )

Research Methods & Experimental Design

AP: LAB 8: THE CHI-SQUARE TEST. Probability, Random Chance, and Genetics

Working Paper Series

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Multivariate Analysis of Variance. The general purpose of multivariate analysis of variance (MANOVA) is to determine

ECON 142 SKETCH OF SOLUTIONS FOR APPLIED EXERCISE #2

Economics 1011a: Intermediate Microeconomics

Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting Ù

Testing Research and Statistical Hypotheses

UNDERSTANDING THE TWO-WAY ANOVA

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

WORKING PAPER SERIES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Prices versus Exams as Strategic Instruments for Competing Universities

Institute for Empirical Research in Economics University of Zurich. Working Paper Series ISSN Working Paper No. 229

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

Section 14 Simple Linear Regression: Introduction to Least Squares Regression

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 15: Repeated Games and Cooperation

Basic Concepts in Research and Data Analysis

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

CHAPTER 13 SIMPLE LINEAR REGRESSION. Opening Example. Simple Regression. Linear Regression

An Exploration into the Relationship of MLB Player Salary and Performance

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 2: Strategic Form Games

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors

Summary of Doctoral Dissertation: Voluntary Participation Games in Public Good Mechanisms: Coalitional Deviations and Efficiency

HARVARD JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS

Discrimination and In-Group Favoritism in a Citywide Trust Experiment

Do R&D or Capital Expenditures Impact Wage Inequality? Evidence from the IT Industry in Taiwan ROC

Statistical tests for SPSS

Do testosterone levels in females have influence on the distrust game, the beauty contest game, and risk-aversion?

STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF UBC FACULTY SALARIES: INVESTIGATION OF

Descriptive Methods Ch. 6 and 7

II. DISTRIBUTIONS distribution normal distribution. standard scores

Peer Effects on Charitable Giving: How Can Social Ties Increase Charitable Giving Through Cognitive Dissonance?

A POPULATION MEAN, CONFIDENCE INTERVALS AND HYPOTHESIS TESTING

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

Online Appendix to Stochastic Imitative Game Dynamics with Committed Agents

Market Power and Efficiency in Card Payment Systems: A Comment on Rochet and Tirole

Online Appendix: Thar SHE blows? Gender, Competition, and Bubbles in Experimental Asset Markets, by Catherine C. Eckel and Sascha C.

Frictional Matching: Evidence from Law School Admission

interpretation and implication of Keogh, Barnes, Joiner, and Littleton s paper Gender,

H. The Study Design. William S. Cash and Abigail J. Moss National Center for Health Statistics

Step 6: Writing Your Hypotheses Written and Compiled by Amanda J. Rockinson-Szapkiw

MULTIPLE REGRESSION WITH CATEGORICAL DATA

A Portfolio Model of Insurance Demand. April Kalamazoo, MI East Lansing, MI 48824

Overcoming moral hazard with social networks in the workplace: An experimental approach

Incentives for Motivated Agents - An Experiment with Employees from a Non-profit Organization

From the help desk: Bootstrapped standard errors

Online Appendix. for. Female Leadership and Gender Equity: Evidence from Plant Closure

Penalized regression: Introduction

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Causes of Inflation in the Iranian Economy

Multiple Linear Regression in Data Mining

Predicting the Performance of a First Year Graduate Student

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 5 Dec 2011

Sensitivity Analysis 3.1 AN EXAMPLE FOR ANALYSIS

Chapter 5: Analysis of The National Education Longitudinal Study (NELS:88)

Ch. 13.2: Mathematical Expectation

MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS OF MAIN ECONOMIC INDICATORS IN TOURISM. R, analysis of variance, Student test, multivariate analysis

Volume Title: The Channels of Monetary Effects on Interest Rates. Volume URL:

ECO 199 B GAMES OF STRATEGY Spring Term 2004 PROBLEM SET 4 B DRAFT ANSWER KEY

Sample Size and Power in Clinical Trials

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models

The Impact of the Medicare Rural Hospital Flexibility Program on Patient Choice

Decision & Risk Analysis Lecture 6. Risk and Utility

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

CHAPTER 2 Estimating Probabilities

Social Preferences. Socially Responsible Investments: Financial Returns. Return Expectations or Social Preferences? 25/06/13. Arno Riedl Paul Smeets

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1

Fairfield Public Schools

The Impact of Interest Rate Shocks on the Performance of the Banking Sector

LAB : THE CHI-SQUARE TEST. Probability, Random Chance, and Genetics

How To Check For Differences In The One Way Anova

Online Appendix to Are Risk Preferences Stable Across Contexts? Evidence from Insurance Data

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 10: Extensive Games: Critiques and Extensions

UNDERSTANDING ANALYSIS OF COVARIANCE (ANCOVA)

Econometrics Simple Linear Regression

COMPARISONS OF CUSTOMER LOYALTY: PUBLIC & PRIVATE INSURANCE COMPANIES.

Schooling, Political Participation, and the Economy. (Online Supplementary Appendix: Not for Publication)

Tests for Two Survival Curves Using Cox s Proportional Hazards Model

Fixed odds bookmaking with stochastic betting demands

Working Paper Series No. 12

Linear Models in STATA and ANOVA

Transcription:

DOES THE TRUST GAME MEASURE TRUST? MARIUS BRÜLHART University of Lausanne & CEPR JEAN-CLAUDE USUNIER University of Lausanne February 2010 Abstract We test whether altruism is a significant confound of observed choices in the standard trust game. We allow for rich and poor trustees and examine whether, consistent with dominant altruism, trustors give more to the poor, or whether, consistent with dominant trust motives, trustors give no more to the poor than to the rich. This test is based on within-treatment and within-subject comparisons. Our results support trust as the dominant motivation for trust like decisions. JEL classification: Keywords: Correspondence address: C91, D63, D64 trust game, altruism, experimental error Ecole des HEC, University of Lausanne, CH 1015 Lausanne, Switzerland. (Marius.Brulhart@unil.ch, Jean-Claude.Usunier@unil.ch) Acknowledgements: Hansueli Bacher, Gregory Cleusix, Tea Danelutti, Jerôme Lathion and David Viña have provided excellent research assistance. We thank the Institute of Research in Management of the University of Lausanne (IRM), and the Swiss National Science Foundation for financial support.

1. INTRODUCTION The trust game of Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (1995) has become the standard laboratory experiment for measuring trust. In the trust game, a first mover is randomly and anonymously paired with a second mover, both are given a monetary endowment, the first mover may transfer some or all of his endowment to the second mover, this transfer is tripled by the experimenter and handed to the second mover, and finally the second mover may return some or all of the received transfer. First-mover transfers are interpreted as a manifestation of trust, and second-mover transfers as a manifestation of trustworthiness. We propose an amended protocol as a way to investigate the claim that altruism might play a significant role in trust like first-mover transfers (Smith, 2003; Cox, 2004). Our central idea is a simple twist to this game: we produce rich and poor second movers by giving them different experimental endowments, and we examine whether, consistent with dominant altruism, trustors give more to the poor, or whether, consistent with dominant reciprocity motives, trustors give no more to the poor than to the rich. A further potential complication is that there may be idiosyncrasies in individual preferences and, more importantly, biases induced by the structure, framing and practical implementation of experiments. The mere fact that a game is based on a single decision node (such as the dictator game) or on a sequence of nodes (such as the trust game) may influence transfers, and difficult-to-control details of practical implementation can introduce treatment-specific biases. By differentiating second movers by their experimental endowment, we can run our discriminatory test within treatments and even within subjects (when we let each first mover play simultaneously with a poor and a rich second mover). Thus, we can control for potential individual-specific biases as well as for treatment-specific bias. 1 1 For a between-subject and between-treatment test of trust versus altruism, see Cox (2004). 2

2. THE EXPERIMENT The trust game can be formally described as follows. First movers i start the game with a money holding of y i. Second movers j have an initial money holding of y j. At the first stage of the game, first movers can send any amount s i, 0 s i y i, to their paired second movers. 2 The experimenter triples the amount sent, so that second movers receive 3s i. At the second stage of the game, second movers can return any amount r j, 0 r j (y j + 3s i ), to their paired first movers. 3 We call rate of return the ratio r / s ; j j i and we denote holdings at the end of the game by Y i and Y j, for first and second movers respectively. Hence, Y i = y i - s i + r j = y i + s i ( j - 1), and Y j = y j + 3s i - r j = y j + s i (3 - j ). We write first movers expected rate of return from second movers as ˆ j. In the original interpretation of trust-game choices, first-mover transfers are a manifestation of trust. Trust, in turn, has two components. One component is due to intrinsic reciprocity (Sobel, 2005): irrespective of final outcomes, agents utility increases if they feel treated kindly and if they can reciprocate kindly (vice-versa for unkind actions). The other component is due to selfishness and the expectation of positive reciprocation. Hence, trusting behavior could either be motivated entirely by intrinsic reciprocity (a desire to elicit kindness through kindness), or by a combination of own-payoff maximization (selfishness) and expected intrinsic reciprocity on the part of the other agent. In a longer version of this paper, we develop an explicit model of subject motivations in such an experimental setting (Brülhart and Usunier, 2008). 4 This allows us to derive testable hypotheses 2 We abstract here from the fact that amounts sent in experiments must take discrete values. 3 In the Berg et al. (1995) trust game, second movers were not allowed to use their initial money holding y j as part of their transfer r j. We relax this constraint by allowing r j to include y j. 4 The main assumptions of that model are (i) that selfish, altruistic, reciprocal and random motivations enter agents utility in additively separable fashion, (ii) that utility over own income is concave with nonincreasing absolute risk aversion, (iii) that altruism incorporates an element of inequality aversion, and (iv) that first movers expected rate of return and the variance thereof are independent of the amount sent ( balanced reciprocation in the terminology of Greig and Bohnet, 2008). 3

formally from a precisely specified utility function. Given their intuitive plausibility, we concentrate on verbal statements of our central propositions here. We vary second movers initial wealth y j and then examine the relationship between s i and y j. Given the double-anonymous experimental protocol, y j constitutes the only element of information that first movers have about their paired second movers. First movers will expect richer second movers to return d ˆ j no less than poorer second movers ( 0 ), as richer second movers are able to afford a higher j. dy j If, except for randomness, altruism is first-movers sole motivation, they will give more to poor second movers than to rich ones. Conversely, first-mover transfers in the absence of own altruistic motives will be non-negatively related to second-mover wealth in line with the original interpretation of trust-game results. We can therefore formulate the following discriminating hypothesis, based entirely on observable variables. Proposition 1: First movers who are motivated only by altruism send more to poor second movers than to rich second movers. First movers who are not motivated by altruism either send less to poor second movers than to rich second movers, or they send equal amounts to both. We have played the trust game with first-year undergraduate students at the University of Lausanne. First movers were all endowed with y i = 10 Swiss francs per second mover they were paired with. 5 Second movers were differentiated by the size of their show-up fee y j, some starting the experiment with nothing, some with 10 francs and some with 20 francs. First movers knew the size of y j of their paired second movers, and second movers knew their paired first movers endowment y i. 5 One Swiss franc was worth approximately 0.73 and 0.85 US dollars at the time of the experiments. 4

We played this game in four sessions, using standard double-anonymous procedures. 6 The four sessions were organized such as to offer variation in two methodological dimensions: manual game (Sessions A and B) versus internet-based game (Sessions C and D); and between-subject design (Sessions A and C) versus within-subject design (Sessions B and D). 3. RESULTS Summary statistics of observed transfers are reported in Table 1 and illustrated in Figure 1. We find that both first movers and second movers made large transfers in all three sessions. First movers on average sent 7.04 of their 10 francs to second movers, and second movers on average returned 11.02 francs. Furthermore, our experiments confirm the finding that only a small fraction of players conform to the subgame perfect equilibrium with pure selfishness, by giving nothing (11% of first movers and 20% of second movers across the four sessions). In line with most of the existing comparable experimental evidence, our results therefore appear incompatible with universal selfishness as the sole, or even dominant, motivation in trust-game settings. We test Proposition 1 by regressing s i on y j using ordinary least squares. 7 The results are given in column I of Table 2. We find a coefficient on y j of 0.01 which has the wrong sign and is statistically insignificant. Virtually the same result obtains when we restrict the estimation to the within-subject protocols of Sessions B and D, controlling for first-mover fixed effects (column II): y j does not significantly affect s i even in this most propitious of experimental designs. The null hypothesis of no altruism cannot therefore be rejected. 6 The texts of the recruitment email, experimental instruction sheets and the post-experiment questionnaire can be obtained from the authors on request. Further details are given in Brülhart and Usunier (2008). 7 To account for the two-sided censoring of s i implied by the trust game, we have also estimated the four equations using the two-sided Tobit estimator. The results are qualitatively unchanged from the OLS runs. 5

Next, we estimate a multi-group version of Proposition 1 by controlling for group-specific attributes that might affect mean transfers. We consider five attributes: gender, nationality, native tongue, subject of study, and experimental session. Estimation results are given in column III of Table 2. The coefficient on y j is unaffected, and the altruism hypothesis is therefore again not supported. Gender, nationality and mother tongue have no statistically significant impact on first-mover transfers either. We find, however, that non-economics students send significantly more than economics and business majors. Finally, Sessions B and D have yielded significantly lower mean first-mover transfers than Session A (the omitted category). There is no ready explanation for these differences. This highlights the potential biases that would affect the between-treatment comparisons our study approach is designed to eschew. In a third step, we extend the multi-group specification to allow also for different altruism according to group attributes, by adding interaction effects. The last column of Table 2 reports our estimates. We now find that the coefficient on y j has the correct negative sign, but it continues to be statistically insignificant. 8 More importantly, we find none of the interaction effects to be statistically significant. It is particularly revealing that not even the interaction terms for Sessions B and D are significant, recalling that those were the sessions featuring the within-subject protocol, and any impact of y j on s i could be expected to be particularly strong there. In sum, our results suggest that altruism is not a statistically significant motivating force in determining trust-like behavior, both across all subjects and for specific groups of players. 8 F tests on the joint significance of interactions with all group attributes or subsets thereof all fail to reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients are jointly zero. 6

4. CONCLUSIONS We propose a discriminatory criterion to identify altruism and trust as determinants of first-mover transfers in trust games. The test is based on within-treatment and within-subject comparisons and should therefore be immune to the experimental bias problem associated with the random component in the choices of laboratory subjects. Using data gathered in experiments with undergraduate university students, we do not find evidence of a significant negative relation between first-mover transfers and second-mover wealth. This result rejects the hypothesis of altruistic motives as a dominant determinant of trust-like decisions. A potentially worthwhile modification would be to use higher monetary stakes, to test whether our rejection of the altruism hypothesis is robust to a compression of the variance of the disturbance term. 9 BIBLIOGRAPHY Berg, J.; Dickhaut, J. and McCabe, K. (1995) Trust, Reciprocity and Social History, Games and Economic Behavior, 10: 122-142. Brülhart, M. and Usunier, J.-C. (2008) Verified Trust: Reciprocity, Altruism, and Randomness in Trust Games. IRM Working Paper #0809, Institute of Research in Management, University of Lausanne. Cox, J.C. (2004) How to Identify Trust and Reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46: 260-281. Greig, F. and Bohnet, I. (2008) Is There Reciprocity in a Reciprocal-Exchange Economy? Evidence from a Slum in Nairobi, Kenya. Economic Inquiry, 46: 77-83. Johansson-Stenman, O.; Mahmud, M. and Martinsson, P. (2005) Does Stake Size Matter in Trust Games? Economics Letters, 88: 365-369. Smith, V.L. (2003) Constructivist and Ecological Rationality in Economics. American Economic Review, 93: 465-508. Sobel, Joel (2005) Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, 43: 392-436. 9 Johansson-Stenman et al. (2005) find that stake size may affect not just the dispersion but also the mean of trustgame transfers. 7

Table 1: Data Description Session A Session B Session C Session D TOTAL No. of observations 38 36 # 31 64 # 169 s i ## 7.76 (2.63) 6.44 (3.49) 6.77 (4.31) 7.08 (3.35) 7.04 (3.44) occurrences of s i = 0 0 (0%) 4 (11%) 7 (23%) 7 (11%) 18 (11%) r j ## 12.37 (10.93) 8.06 (8.19) 10.45 (13.93) 12.17 (10.25) 11.02 (10.82) occurrences of r j = 0 4 (11%) 7 (19%) 12 (39%) 10 (16%) 33 (20%) y j ### 13 * 0 12 * 10 13 *20 18 * 0 18 * 20 16 * 0 15 * 20 32 * 0 32 * 20 79 * 0 12 * 10 78 * 20 y i ## 10 (0) 10 (0) 10 (0) 10 (0) 10 (0) # In Session B(D), 36(64) observations correspond to 18(32) players 1, each matched with two players 2. ## Mean values (standard deviations in parentheses) ### (number of observations * y) 8

Table 2: Regression Results (OLS, dependent variable = s i ) # (I) (II) ## (III) (IV) 0.01 0.003 0.01-0.02 y j (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.11) Female -0.16 0.32 (0.58) (0.86) Female y j -0.04 (0.06) Nat_Swiss -0.05-0.41 (0.91) (1.25) 0.04 Nat_Swiss y j (0.10) Lang_French 0.39 0.71 (0.81) (1.18) Lang_French y j -0.03 (0.08) Lang_German 0.83 1.39 (1.04) (1.38) Lang_German y j -0.05 (0.10) Non-economist 1.61 1.37 (0.75) ** (1.10) 0.02 Non-economist y j (0.08) Session_B -1.39-1.94 (0.74) * (1.16) * 0.05 Session_B y j (0.09) Session_C -0.90-1.72 (0.90) (1.33) Session_C y j 0.08 Session_D (0.10) -1.62-1.81 (0.81) ** (1.22) Session_D y j 0.01 (0.09) Dummies for 1 st -movers No Yes No No R-squared 0.001 0.0003 0.046 0.057 F statistic 0.12 0.02 1.08 0.67 Observations 169 100 169 169 # heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors in brackets: * : 90% confidence level, ** : 95%, *** : 99%; constant term included but not reported ## fixed-effects panel data model; regression includes only observations from Sessions B and D; R- squared and F statistic only on within variation 9

Figure 1: First-Mover Transfers and Second-Mover Returns Swiss francs 0 10 20 30 40 50 yj=0 yj=10 yj=20 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 subject pair (ordered by yj and si) si rj 10