UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) ) ) COMMENTS OF THE INDEPENDENT MARKET MONITOR FOR PJM

Similar documents
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) ) ) ) ) )

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) ) ) PROTEST OF THE INDEPENDENT MARKET MONITOR FOR PJM

In the Supreme Court of the United States

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. ) Southwest Power Pool, Inc. ) Docket No. ER )

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. Rock Island Clean Line LLC ) Docket No. ER

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

131 FERC 61,148 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER ON COMPLIANCE FILING. (Issued May 20, 2010)

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. PJM Interconnection, LLC ) Docket No. ER

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. California Independent System ) Docket No. ER Operator Corporation )

111 FERC 61,205 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

135 FERC 61,197 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER GRANTING AUTHORIZATION TO MAKE AFFILIATE SALES

Midcontinent Independent System Operator, Inc. FERC Docket No. ER Notice of Termination of Generator Interconnection Agreement

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. PJM INTERCONNECTION, L.L.C. ) Docket Nos. ER ) ER

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) ) ) )

131 FERC 61,157 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER GRANTING WAIVER. (Issued May 25, 2010)

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

132 FERC 61,083 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER DENYING REHEARING AND INSTITUTING SECTION 206 PROCEEDING

San Diego Gas & Electric Company ) Docket No. ER MOTION TO INTERVENE AND PROTEST OF THE CALIFORNIA INDEPENDENT SYSTEM OPERATOR CORPORATION

151 FERC 61,046 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

December 30, Deseret Generation & Transmission Co-operative, Inc.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 151 FERC 62,146 FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER AUTHORIZING DISPOSITION OF JURISDICTIONAL FACILITIES

How To Get A Refund From The Utilities Commission

MISO Schedule 41 Charge to Recover Costs of Entergy Storm Securitization SCHEDULES SCHEDULE 41

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. Columbia Gas Transmission Corporation ) Docket No.

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ) )

Southern LNG Company, L.L.C. ( SLNG ) submits for filing the following section to its FERC Gas Tariff, First Revised Volume No.

151 FERC 61,274 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

141 FERC 61,267 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

NYISO Tariffs: MST Section 5 Control Area Services: Rights and Obligations. NYISO Tariffs. New York Independent System Operator, Inc.

/s/ Sidney Mannheim Davies Sidney Mannheim Davies Assistant General Counsel Counsel for the California Independent System Operator Corporation

Florida Gas Transmission Company, LLC Docket No. RP

SINGLE MARKET-BASED RATE TARIFF

Informational Report of the California Independent System Operator Corporation

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 151 FERC 62,147 FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER AUTHORIZING DISPOSITION OF JURISDICTIONAL FACILITIES

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

104 FERC 61,128 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

DUQUESNE LIGHT COMPANY ELECTRIC GENERATION SUPPLIER COORDINATION TARIFF. Issued By. DUQUESNE LIGHT COMPANY 411 Seventh Avenue Pittsburgh, PA 15219

153 FERC 61,309 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA Federal Energy Regulatory Commission. 18 CFR Part 35. Docket No. RM

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

121 FERC 61,143 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

151 FERC 62,145 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

Midcontinent Independent System Operator, Inc. FERC Docket No. ER Notice of Termination of Multi-Party Facilities Construction Agreement

March 25, Ms. Kimberly D. Bose, Secretary Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 888 First Street, N.E. Washington, D.C

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Virginia Electric and Power Company Subsection A 4 Rate Adjustment Clause. Direct Testimony and Exhibits

April 29, The ISO sent its proposed tariff amendment to the Commission via overnight delivery on December 23, 2009.

1. Briefly explain what an indifference curve is and how it can be graphically derived.

149 FERC 61,012 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER AUTHORIZING ISSUANCES OF SECURITIES. (Issued October 3, 2014)

STATEMENT OF NATURE, REASONS AND BASIS

Case 5:07-cv JKG Document Filed 05/15/13 Page 1 of 19 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA

May 20, Submitted Electronically. Kimberly D. Bose Secretary Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 888 First Street, N.E. Washington, D.C.

SCHEDULE 1. Scheduling, System Control and Dispatch Service

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION. Greater Detroit Resource Recovery Project. ) Docket No.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

140 FERC 62,085 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER AUTHORIZING DISPOSITION OF JURISDICTIONAL FACILITIES

KERMIT Study Report. To determine the effectiveness of the AGC in controlling fast and conventional resources in the PJM frequency regulation market

ALCOA POWER GENERATING INC. Long Sault Division. Open Access Transmission Tariff

Principles of Economics: Micro: Exam #2: Chapters 1-10 Page 1 of 9

Cincinnati Gas & Electric Corporation

135 FERC 61,202 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

An Experience Curve Based Model for the Projection of PV Module Costs and Its Policy Implications

Renewal of Fund s Investment Advisory Agreement

139 FERC 61,088 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER GRANTING MARKET-BASED RATE AUTHORIZATION AND REQUEST FOR WAIVERS

The fundamental question in economics is 2. Consumer Preferences

ECON 103, ANSWERS TO HOME WORK ASSIGNMENTS

142 FERC 62,199 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER AUTHORIZING DISPOSITION OF JURISDICTIONAL FACILITIES

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

ARIZONA PUBLIC SERVICE COMPANY ORDER NO. EA-134

144 FERC 61,245 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

152 FERC 61,028 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

Market Monitoring Services Agreement By And Between PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. And Monitoring Analytics, LLC

Closing the Gap Between Wholesale and Retail

FINANCIAL ANALYSIS GUIDE

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

N.J.A.C. 14:8-4 NET METERING FOR CLASS I RENEWABLE ENERGY SYSTEMS

California Independent System Operator Corporation - A Case Study

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

Ms. Kimberly D. Bose, Secretary Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 888 First Street, NE Washington, DC Compliance Filing Docket No.

154 FERC 61,020 FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION WASHINGTON, DC January 19, 2016

8. Average product reaches a maximum when labor equals A) 100 B) 200 C) 300 D) 400

How To Answer The Six Cities' Protest Against The Power Line Project

CHAPTER 7: CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

High Penetration of Distributed Solar PV Generation

134 FERC 61,226 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER ON COMPLIANCE FILING. (Issued March 24, 2011)

LIMITED LIABILITY COMPANY OPERATING AGREEMENT FOR

Chapter 03 The Concept of Elasticity and Consumer and

138 FERC 61,135 UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION ORDER DENYING CONTINUATION OF STANDARDS OF CONDUCT WAIVER

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Appendix G Process For Protection of Proposal Information For

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M. School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 13 Consumer Behaviour (Contd )

c. Given your answer in part (b), what do you anticipate will happen in this market in the long-run?

A new direction for Delta Pacific: A case study

Study Questions for Chapter 9 (Answer Sheet)

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

August 31, Ms. Kimberly D. Bose, Secretary Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 888 First Street, NE Washington, DC 20426

Transcription:

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION PJM Interconnection, L.L.C. ) ) ) Docket No. ER12-2391-001 COMMENTS OF THE INDEPENDENT MARKET MONITOR FOR PJM Pursuant to Rule 211 of the Commission s Rules and Regulations, 1 Monitoring Analytics, LLC, acting in its capacity as the Independent Market Monitor for PJM 2 ( Market Monitor ), submits these comments on PJM s response to the Commission s deficiency notice ( Deficiency Letter ) filed by PJM on September 17, 2012 ( September 17 th Answer ). The September 17 th Answer provides additional supporting arguments and information regarding the use of the benefits factor in the Regulation Market clearing and settlement process that PJM proposed on August 2, 2012 ( August 2 nd Filing ). With these comments, the Market Monitor seeks to supplement the record concerning Commission Requests Nos. 1B, 3 2A 4 and 2B, 5 which address the use and meaning of PJM s benefits factor. 1 18 CFR 385.211 (2012). 2 PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., a Regional Transmission Organization. Capitalized terms used herein and not otherwise defined have the meaning used in the PJM Open Access Transmission Tariff ( OATT ). 3 Request 1B: If the marginal benefits factor can go below one, please include an explanation and a numerical example where the marginal benefits factor is less than one but greater than zero. 4 Request 2A: Please provide a range of benefits factors that can be assigned to a resource following the dynamic regulation signal. Please provide a detailed explanation and a graphical illustration. - 1 -

There are two types of benefits factor, a unit specific benefits factor and a system or marginal benefits factor. In its August 2 nd Filing, PJM proposes to retain the unit specific benefits factor, which is determined on the basis of the unit s relative position in the total regulation resource supply stack and the proportion of quick response ( fast ) and traditional ( slow ) resources that would clear at that relative position. The unit specific benefits factor allows PJM to rank fast resources relative to slow resources in the regulation supply stack used in the resource selection and optimization. More importantly, PJM proposes that the marginal benefits factor, which is based on the cleared proportion of fast to slow resources in the market solution, determine the optimal resource mix and settlement. In light of the results of PJM s commissioned engineering study from KEMA ( KEMA Study ) on using combinations of regulation resources to meet its regulation requirements, the Market Monitor agrees that this approach to the use of the marginal benefits factor is appropriate and reasonable and is the only correct way to clear the market. 6 5 Request 2B: If the marginal benefits factor for resources following the dynamic regulation signal can go below one, please explain and provide a numerical example of how such resources will be appropriately compensated for the work performed given that the benefits factor for the last dynamic regulation signal megawatt selected will be used to adjust the compensation for all resources following the dynamic regulation signal. Please explain if under certain scenarios it is possible for dynamic resources to be compensated less than traditional resources and if so, why such a result would be appropriate. 6 See KEMA Inc., KERMIT Study Report: To Determine the Effectiveness of the AGC in Controlling Fast and Conventional Resources in the PJM Frequency Regulation Market, <http://www.pjm.com/committees-and-groups/task-forces/~/media/committees-groups/taskforces/rpstf/postings/pjm-kema-final-study-report.ashx>. - 2 -

I. COMMENTS The August 2 nd Filing clarified that PJM s use of a unit specific benefits factor was limited to rank ordering resources in the supply stack in the total regulation resource supply stack. The August 2 nd Filing clarified that the unit specific benefits factor of the last fast resource cleared, the marginal benefits factor, would be used for the purposes of optimization and settlement. The Market Monitor agrees that this is an appropriate application of the marginal benefits factor. As defined by PJM, the benefits factor represents the rate of substitution between fast and slow regulation resources for the provision of regulation service at varying ratios of cleared, effective MW of fast and slow regulation. A. Regulation Is a Single Product with Two Inputs, Fast and Slow, That Require a Defined Rate of Substitution, the Benefits Factor Due to their varying characteristics, fast and slow resources are not perfect substitutes for one another for purposes of providing regulation as defined in PJM s market. But because regulation is a single product in PJM s market design, the clearing rules must account for and optimize the selection of fast and slow resources included in the market clearing. Fast and slow resources, depending on technology type, have different cost structures, different sources, and different capabilities. Fast resources, for example, tend to be non-generation resources. Fast resources have quick response times but limited total response capability in one direction relative to slow resources. PJM has historically met its regulation requirements via the use of slow resources following a single regulation signal (RegA) designed to reflect the characteristics of slow resources in meeting ACE and frequency control requirements. Although fast resources can respond quickly to changes in RegA, they cannot always successfully track the RegA signal. When RegA is negative or - 3 -

positive for a significant period of time, non-generator, fast response units, such as fly wheels and batteries, quickly exhaust their capability to follow the signal. When RegA has many small displacements and crosses zero often, non-generator fast response units can more closely track RegA than traditional slow resources. Generally speaking, fast response units are better suited to follow a signal that makes frequent changes from negative to positive and slow resources are better suited to follow a signal that makes less frequent changes from negative to positive. Regulation service defined around only one signal cannot take full advantage of the capability that either fast or slow resources can provide. A signal designed to take advantage of a particular resource type (fast or slow), will tend to diminish the ability of the other resource type to contribute to ACE and frequency control. Due to the nature of the Regulation Market in PJM it is possible to meet PJM s regulation requirements (the regulation performance target) entirely with slow resources following RegA. PJM cannot, however, meet its regulation requirements (regulation performance target) using only fast resources, even with a fast resource specific regulation signal (RegD). Although PJM cannot replace its slow regulation fleet with a fast regulation fleet, the KEMA Study indicated that a combination of fast and slow resources, following separate fast (RegD) and slow (RegA) regulation signals, could do a more effective job of meeting PJM s regulation requirement (regulation performance target) than slow resources alone. According to the study, the smaller the proportion of fast regulation MW and the greater the proportion of slow regulation used, the more benefit there is to substituting fast regulation MW for slow regulation MW. In other words, the smaller the proportion of fast regulation used, the more slow regulation each MW of fast regulation can replace. - 4 -

Conversely, as the proportion of fast resources increases, the benefit of substituting fast capability for slow capability in meeting a specific regulation performance target decreases. In other words, the larger the proportion of fast regulation used, the less slow regulation each MW of fast regulation can replace. This is not surprising and follows a normal diminishing returns pattern. This relationship is the benefits factor, or rate of substitution, between fast and slow resources. The benefits factor decreases as the amount of fast resources increases. The KEMA Study indicated that, for a given regulation performance target, there is a limit to this ability to substitute fast for slow regulation MW and reduce total combined regulation MW when trying to achieve a specific regulation performance target. This is why PJM cannot entirely replace its slow regulation fleet following a RegA signal with a fast regulation fleet following a RegD signal. Although the rate of substitution is greater than 1.0 when the level of fast regulation is low (one MW of fast can replace more than one MW of slow while holding regulation performance target constant), the rate of substitution falls as more fast regulation MW are added. The rate of substitution is the marginal benefits factor. Eventually, the addition of another MW of fast capability actually requires adding rather than replacing MW of slow capability to maintain a regulation performance target. At this point the rate of substitution is negative (less than zero) and the addition of fast resources makes it harder to maintain a regulation performance target. A flaw in the PJM proposal is that PJM proposes to arbitrarily prevent the rate of substitution (the benefits - 5 -

factor) from falling below zero. 7 While this is incorrect, it is unlikely to have any practical effect as the price of fast resources is likely to be very high under those conditions. B. Defining a Market Solution with Two Inputs and One Product The KEMA study indicated that, depending on the relative costs of fast and slow resources, a mix of fast and slow resources could provide regulation service at a lower cost than using slow resources alone. PJM s objective is to minimize the total cost to meet a specific regulation performance target given two types of regulation capability. The rate of substitution is a key component of any optimized solution to this problem. Given a defined relationship between the two inputs (the production model that defines the rate of substitution), and the objective of minimizing costs, the market design solution to this optimization problem can be achieved in one of two ways: two input markets or one market for normalized input units. 1. Two Input Market Solution The direct approach is to recognize a single service (regulation) that can be met with a combination of two inputs through a defined production model (the source of the rate of substitution), with each input type purchased in a separate market, one market for fast capability and the other for slow capability. The least cost combination of fast and slow regulation resources to meet a specific regulation performance target occurs where the marginal cost of fast (the clearing price for fast in the market for fast regulation MW), divided by the marginal contribution to the regulation performance target equals the 7 See September 17 th Answer at 4 5. PJM limits the range of benefits factors from 2.9 to 0.00001. - 6 -

marginal cost for slow (the clearing price for slow in the market for slow regulation MW), divided by the marginal contribution to the regulation performance target of slow. 2. One Market for Normalized Input Units The Commission required a single market clearing approach, which required PJM to procure two input types in a single market, with a single supply curve including two types of regulation, with a single clearing price. 8 For this approach to work effectively, the two input types must be defined in common units in the production model. This is done by defining the market in terms of one of the two input types (either fast or slow capability), which becomes the base unit of measure, and using the rate of substitution (the marginal benefits factor) from the production model to convert the other input into equivalent units of the base units of measure. a. Using the Marginal Benefits Factor to Convert to Common Input Units In the PJM proposal, slow resource capacity is the base unit of measure. The conversion factor for any given regulation performance target for any given ratio of fast to slow is the rate of substitution, or the marginal benefits factor. This approach defines the supply curve for regulation in terms of slow regulation capability and dollars per unit of slow regulation capability, with fast resources offers represented in the supply stack in terms of equivalent slow regulation capability and prices. The conversion rate is the benefits factor defined at any point along the common supply curve. 9 8 Frequency Regulation Compensation in the Organized Wholesale Power Markets, Order No. 755, 137 FERC 61,064 at P 99 (2011); order on reh g, Order No. 755-A, 138 FERC 61,123 (2012). 9 September 17 th Answer at 4 5. - 7 -

Take an example where, at the current ratio of fast to slow found at a defined point in the supply stack, the benefits factor (rate of substitution) is 2.0. This means that if the market clears at this point of combined supply, the resulting resource mix has a marginal rate of substitution between fast and slow capability of 2.0. This means that at this point in the supply curve, 1 MW of fast is providing as much regulation capability as 2 MW of slow. If a unit cost $2 per MW of fast, it would cost $1 per MW when translated into equivalent slow MW ($2/2 MW = $1/MW). If the unit were marginal, the marginal benefits factor at the clearing point would be 2.0, and the unit would set the price in terms of slow units at a price of $1 per MW of slow capability. It would be paid $1 for each MW of slow capability it provided. Since it is providing 2 MW of slow capability for every 1 MW of fast capability, it is paid $2 per MW of fast capability. It supplied 1 MW of fast at a cost of $2. The price received per unit is equal to its offer per unit, which is consistent with the treatment of a marginal resource in any market. Any unit that is inframarginal, in this example, would have an offer that is less than the marginal unit, i.e., it would have to have an effective price of less than $1/MW of slow. If this resource has a cost of $1 per MW of fast, its offer in terms of slow would be $0.50 per MW in terms of slow at the clearing point of the market. It would be paid the $1/MW of slow capability clearing price (the clearing price), or $2 per MW of fast ($1 x Marginal Benefit Factor of 2). It would earn a margin of $1 ($2 - $1) per MW of fast supplied. Take an example where, at the current ratio of fast to slow found at a defined point in the supply stack, the benefits factor (rate of substitution) is 0.5. This means that if the market clears at this point of combined supply, the resulting resource mix has a marginal rate of substitution between fast and slow capability of 0.5. This means that at the resource mix at this point in combined supply, 1 MW of fast is providing as much regulation - 8 -

capability as 0.5 MW of slow. If a unit cost $2 per MW of fast, it would appear to cost $4 MW when translated into equivalent slow MW ($2/0.5 MW = $4/MW). If the unit was marginal, the marginal benefit factor would be 0.5, and the unit would set the price in terms of slow units at a price of $4/MW of slow capability. It would be paid $4 for each MW of slow capability it provided. Since it is providing 0.5 MW of slow capability for every 1 MW of fast capability, it is paid $2 per MW of fast capability. It supplied 1 MW of fast at a cost of $2. The price received per unit is equal to its offer per unit, which is consistent with a marginal resource. Any unit that is inframarginal, in this example, would have an offer that was less, in slow equivalent capability $/MW, than $4 per MW of slow capability. Assuming another fast resource cleared, it would have to have an effective price of less than $4/MW of slow. If this resource has a cost of $1 per MW of fast, its offer in terms of slow would be $2 per MW in terms of slow at the clearing point of the market ($1/ marginal benefit factor of 0.5). It would be paid the $4/MW of slow capability clearing price (the clearing price), or $2 per MW of fast ($4 x Marginal Benefit Factor of 0.5). It would earn a margin of $1 ($2 - $1) per MW of fast supplied. b. Settlement Should Be Based on the Marginal Benefits Factor As noted in the Market Monitor s March 26 th Protest and the March 5 th Proposal, the KEMA study, which provides the theoretical engineering basis for PJM s approach to its regulation market design, showed decreasing rates of substitution between fast and slow resources as the proportion of fast resources increases. This means that the marginal benefits factor (rate of substitution) decreases as the amount of fast resources used increases. This means that the benefit of every fast resource being used, not just the last one, is declining as more fast resources are added to the regulation commitment. The correct - 9 -

way to include this result in the settlement solution is to reflect the marginal rate of substitution when determining the relative substitutability of fast and slow resources and therefore the correct market equilibrium. The correct approach results in a uniform price in a common unit of measure (slow resource MW and price per MW of slow) that reflects the marginal value of the resources used. II. CONCLUSION The Market Monitor respectfully requests that the Commission afford due consideration to these comments as the Commission resolves the issues raised in this proceeding. Respectfully submitted, Joseph E. Bowring Independent Market Monitor for PJM President Monitoring Analytics, LLC 2621 Van Buren Avenue, Suite 160 Valley Forge Corporate Center Eagleville, Pennsylvania 19403 (610) 271 8051 joseph.bowring@monitoringanalytics.com Jeffrey W. Mayes General Counsel Monitoring Analytics, LLC 2621 Van Buren Avenue, Suite 160 Valley Forge Corporate Center Eagleville, Pennsylvania 19403 (610) 271 8053 jeffrey.mayes@monitoringanalytics.com Howard J. Haas Chief Economist Monitoring Analytics, LLC 2621 Van Buren Avenue, Suite 160 Valley Forge Corporate Center Eagleville, Pennsylvania 19403 (610) 271 8054 howard.haas@monitoringanalytics.com - 10 -

Dated: October 9, 2012-11 -

CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE I hereby certify that I have this day served the foregoing document upon each person designated on the official service list compiled by the Secretary in this proceeding. Dated at Eagleville, Pennsylvania, this 9 th day of October, 2012. Jeffrey W. Mayes General Counsel Monitoring Analytics, LLC 2621 Van Buren Avenue, Suite 160 Valley Forge Corporate Center Eagleville, Pennsylvania 19403 (610) 271 8053 jeffrey.mayes@monitoringanalytics.com