Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity in Multifamily Property Markets

Similar documents
A Test Of The M&M Capital Structure Theories Richard H. Fosberg, William Paterson University, USA

Market Prices of Houses in Atlanta. Eric Slone, Haitian Sun, Po-Hsiang Wang. ECON 3161 Prof. Dhongde

Simple linear regression

Real Estate Agent Remarks: Help or Hype?

Course Objective This course is designed to give you a basic understanding of how to run regressions in SPSS.

Technical Efficiency Accounting for Environmental Influence in the Japanese Gas Market

WEBB COUNTY APPRAISAL DISTRICT. How is Residential Property Appraised. Revised 01/26/2016 RV

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 11 Number 1 Spring 1998

Earnings Announcement and Abnormal Return of S&P 500 Companies. Luke Qiu Washington University in St. Louis Economics Department Honors Thesis

Review of Fundamental Mathematics

Module 5: Multiple Regression Analysis

Glossary of Assessment Terms:

Session 7 Bivariate Data and Analysis

Gender Differences in Employed Job Search Lindsey Bowen and Jennifer Doyle, Furman University

Statistics courses often teach the two-sample t-test, linear regression, and analysis of variance

The impact of loan rates on direct real estate investment holding period return

Density, Design and Infrastructure Costs: Physical Survey of New Jersey Development

Analysis of School Finance Equity and Local Wealth Measures in Maryland

NCSS Statistical Software Principal Components Regression. In ordinary least squares, the regression coefficients are estimated using the formula ( )

Repair Expenses, Selling Contracts and

Introduction to Regression and Data Analysis

Rental Housing and the Natural Vacancy Rate

Branding and Search Engine Marketing

THE EFFECT OF FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE FOLLOWING MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS ON FIRM VALUE

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Fairfield Public Schools

Franchising in Residential Brokerage

ESTIMATING AN ECONOMIC MODEL OF CRIME USING PANEL DATA FROM NORTH CAROLINA BADI H. BALTAGI*

Basic Property Appraisal

Types of Value LEARNING OBJECTIVES KEY TERMS INTRODUCTION

Statistics 2014 Scoring Guidelines

Chapter 10. Key Ideas Correlation, Correlation Coefficient (r),

I-E Introduction to Sales Ratio Studies

X X X a) perfect linear correlation b) no correlation c) positive correlation (r = 1) (r = 0) (0 < r < 1)

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance

Property taxes: Are owners getting their money s worth?

INTERNATIONAL STANDARD ON AUDITING 540 AUDITING ACCOUNTING ESTIMATES, INCLUDING FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING ESTIMATES, AND RELATED DISCLOSURES CONTENTS

171:290 Model Selection Lecture II: The Akaike Information Criterion

The Impact of Contract Type on Broker Performance: Submarket Effects

Analysis of Economic Depreciation for

The Capitalization of Stricter Building Codes in Miami, Florida House Prices. by Randy E. Dumm G. Stacy Sirmans Greg Smersh

Physics Lab Report Guidelines

STOCK MARKET VOLATILITY AND REGIME SHIFTS IN RETURNS

The Property Tax Is a Bad Tax, but It Need Not Be

1. What is the critical value for this 95% confidence interval? CV = z.025 = invnorm(0.025) = 1.96

Benchmarking Residential Energy Use

CREATING A CORPORATE BOND SPOT YIELD CURVE FOR PENSION DISCOUNTING DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF ECONOMIC POLICY WHITE PAPER FEBRUARY 7, 2005

Internet Appendix for Taxes on Tax-Exempt Bonds

Investment Statistics: Definitions & Formulas

Descriptive statistics Statistical inference statistical inference, statistical induction and inferential statistics

A Panel Data Analysis of Corporate Attributes and Stock Prices for Indian Manufacturing Sector

Nonlinear Regression Functions. SW Ch 8 1/54/

POLK COUNTY, FLORIDA TAX COLLECTOR

MISSING DATA TECHNIQUES WITH SAS. IDRE Statistical Consulting Group

Journal of Business & Economics Research November, 2004 Volume 2, Number 11

METHODOLOGY GUIDE VALUING RESIDENTIAL PROPERTIES IN ONTARIO 2016 BASE YEAR

Considering Foreclosed Sales By: Michael Barnett

Indiana State Core Curriculum Standards updated 2009 Algebra I

Final Exam Practice Problem Answers

INFLATION, INTEREST RATE, AND EXCHANGE RATE: WHAT IS THE RELATIONSHIP?

Environmental Determinants of Housing Prices: The Impact of Flood Zone Status

NON-RESIDENTS PURCHASING REAL PROPERTY IN THE U.S.

An Empirical Analysis of Insider Rates vs. Outsider Rates in Bank Lending

Market Potential and Sales Forecasting

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 13 Number 1 Spring 2000 HISTORICAL RETURN DISTRIBUTIONS FOR CALLS, PUTS, AND COVERED CALLS

The Role of House Flippers in a Boom and Bust Real Estate Market

Active vs. Passive Money Management

Robust procedures for Canadian Test Day Model final report for the Holstein breed

Price-Earnings Ratios, Dividend Yields and Real Estate Stock Prices

Part 2: Analysis of Relationship Between Two Variables

2. Linear regression with multiple regressors

Lawyer Experience and IPO Pricing *

1. a. (iv) b. (ii) [6.75/(1.34) = 10.2] c. (i) Writing a call entails unlimited potential losses as the stock price rises.

International Review of Business Research Papers Vol.3 No.1. March 2007, Pp

Using R for Linear Regression

Multiple Regression Analysis A Case Study

Violent crime total. Problem Set 1

Part Three. Cost Behavior Analysis

Pearson s Correlation

MULTIPLE REGRESSION AND ISSUES IN REGRESSION ANALYSIS

WEB APPENDIX. Calculating Beta Coefficients. b Beta Rise Run Y X

Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions Volume 12 Number 2 Fall 1999

The performance of immigrants in the Norwegian labor market

Appendices with Supplementary Materials for CAPM for Estimating Cost of Equity Capital: Interpreting the Empirical Evidence

EVALUATION OF THE PAIRS TRADING STRATEGY IN THE CANADIAN MARKET

Simple Regression Theory II 2010 Samuel L. Baker

Discussion of The Role of Volatility in Forecasting

Agricultural Property Tax Equity in North Dakota

VALUING LAND IN DISPUTE RESOLUTION USING COEFFICIENT OF VARIATION TO DETERMINE UNIT OF MEASUREMENT BY BRYAN YOUNGE, MAI, ASA July 2016 Update

Rafal Borkowski, Hipoteczna 18/22 m. 8, Lodz, POLAND,

Solving Quadratic Equations

Are There Systematic Trade Cost Differences in Trading US Cross-Listed Shares Across Markets?

Firm characteristics. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

Dr. Pushpa Bhatt, Sumangala JK Department of Commerce, Bangalore University, India

Have the GSE Affordable Housing Goals Increased. the Supply of Mortgage Credit?

Mode and Patient-mix Adjustment of the CAHPS Hospital Survey (HCAHPS)

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

How Does the Stock Market React to Corporate Environmental News?

Rating Methodology. Alternative Investment Funds Open-Ended Real Estate Funds. June Contact

Interpretation of Financial Statements

Transcription:

Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity in Multifamily Property Markets Author Marcus T. Allen Abstract Vertical equity in property tax systems refers to the assessment of all properties in a taxing jurisdiction at the same proportion of their market values. This study considers alternative methods for measuring vertical inequity in multi-family property markets using sample data. The results indicate that vertical inequities do exist in this sample, with lower valued properties being assessed at a higher proportion of market value than higher valued properties. This study suggests that owners of properties in lower value ranges in this market should carefully monitor the assessment process to minimize their property tax expense. Introduction Property taxes are a significant expense item in most multi-family property markets around the United States. Nationwide survey data from the Institute for Real Estate Management (IREM) indicate that real estate taxes range from 5% to 10% of gross rents for various types of apartments. Given the magnitude of this expense item, prudent management of property tax exposure can be an effective strategy toward the goal of profit maximization for real estate portfolio managers and investors. The property tax system in most taxing jurisdictions is an ad valorem tax, meaning that the tax due on a particular property is determined by the value of the property and the tax levy rate. The value of the property typically is estimated by an assessment official based on market data and the tax levy rate is set by the taxing authority (city or county commissioners, school boards, etc.) based on the taxing authority s budget. The ad valorem system suggests that an owner who wishes to manage property tax exposure can do so by impacting either the political budgeting process that affects tax levy rates or the assessment process used to estimate value. A property owner could endeavor to manage property tax expenses through involvement in local politics with activities such as supporting candidates/parties for elected office who share the owner s fiscal leanings, lobbying existing elected officials for decisions that coincide with the owner s preferences, or, at the JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003

172 Allen extreme, personally pursuing elected positions that carry budget authority. More directly, however, property owners may attempt to affect property tax exposure by monitoring the assessment process used in the ad valorem system and challenging the assessment amount when an error is suspected. Monitoring the accuracy of the assessment process is certainly not a new concept. In the words of Denne (1977), for as long as there have been taxes there has been concern that they be administered equitably, and the equity of the ad valorem property tax has long been a controversial subject. An obvious criticism of the property tax focuses on perceived or real inequities stemming from the failure of assessing officials to assess all properties in a taxing jurisdiction fairly according to their market value. Giving assessing officials the benefit of the doubt regarding any intentional manipulation of the assessment process, this failure may be due in part to the inherent difficulties of accurately estimating property value. To the extent that such difficulties vary across property value ranges, properties in different value ranges may face different probabilities of being inequitably assessed. The purpose of this study is to demonstrate how to measure or detect systematic assessment inequities that may exist across value ranges in multi-family property markets. If the assessment process in a local market is biased in favor of higher or lower valued properties, property owners may be able to reduce their tax liability by challenging their assessments through established procedures and thus increase property profitability. The first section of this paper discusses various methods that have been proposed to measure inequity in property tax systems. While these methods were originally developed to consider inequity in single-family houses and condominium units, they can be readily adapted to measure inequity in multi-family properties. The second section demonstrates the application of the measurement methods to sample data consisting of recently sold, small-scale, multi-family properties in the Fort Lauderdale, Florida, metropolitan area. The final section is the conclusion. Methods for Measuring Inequity in the Property Tax Structure The ad valorem property tax system continues to serve as an essential element of the revenue source for local governments, despite the gradual decline in its importance over the preceding ninety-five years (see Smith, 2000). When it comes to defining equity, or fairness, in the context of ad valorem property taxes, the concept is commonly divided along two dimensions: horizontal equity and vertical equity. Horizontal equity refers to discrimination in the tax base between properties with similar market value (see Doering, 1977). In empirical studies of horizontal equity, some degree of variation in the assessment of properties with similar market values

Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 173 is always assumed to be present and is acceptable within limits. Some variation is acceptable because observed price is often relied on as a measure of unobservable true value, but transaction prices may reflect factors other than property value. For example, transaction prices may reflect reduced marketing times, the value of personal property items included in the transaction, unusual financing, atypical buyer and seller motivations, and information asymmetry (see Haurin, 1988; Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton, 1990; and Smith, 2000). Reinmuth (1977) claims that horizontal inequities are uncontrollable, random deviations of transaction prices from market values and can, therefore, be ignored. The second dimension of equity, vertical equity, refers to the degree of variation of assessed values from market values across various property value ranges. For a property tax system to be vertically equitable, all properties within a taxing jurisdiction must be assessed in equal proportion to their market value. A vertically inequitable tax system can be further classified as regressive if higher valued properties are taxed more favorably than lower valued properties and progressive if higher valued properties are taxed less favorably than lower valued properties. Following the arguments of Reinmuth (1977), the focus of this study is on vertical equity. The property tax equity research literature contains numerous methods for detecting vertical inequity, including those proposed by Paglin and Fogarty (1972), Cheng (1974), the International Association of Assessing Officers (IAAO) (1978), Kochin and Parks (1982), Bell (1984), Clapp (1990) and Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton (1990). In their 1991 study of vertical equity regarding single-family properties in Miami, Florida, Sirmans, Diskin and Friday (1995) review these methods in detail, but draw no firm conclusion about which method is the definitive choice for use in empirical studies such as this one (see Benson and Schwartz, 1997 and 2000, for more discussion of this issue). The appropriate choice depends on the source of error in the assessment process and the nature of the relationship between assessed values and sales prices across price ranges, as discussed below. The model developed by Paglin and Fogarty (1972) is widely regarded as the seminal work on the topic of vertical inequity. They propose that inequity can be detected when the intercept term in Equation (1) is significantly different from zero. AV a asp. (1) 0 1 In this equation, AV and SP represent assessed value and sales price for each property, respectively. AV is established by the assessing authority and SP is employed as a proxy for the unobservable market value of each property. If vertical equity is present, an estimated regression line for the above equation would JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003

174 Allen originate from the origin and would have a slope coefficient approximately equal to the AV /SP ratio for the sample. A significantly negative intercept term indicates a progressive tax structure, with lower value properties being taxed at a lower percentage of market value. Similarly, a significantly positive intercept term indicates a regressive tax structure. The Cheng (1974) model is a log-linear model defined as shown in Equation (2). The coefficient of interest in this model is a 1. If this slope coefficient is equal to one, there is no vertical inequity. A slope coefficient that is significantly greater (less) than one indicates a progressive (regressive) tax structure. ln AV a a ln SP. (2) 0 1 The IAAO (1978) model shown in Equation (3) relies on the assessment ratio (assessed value divided by sales price AV /SP) as the dependent variable. In this model, the coefficient on SP indicates the presence (and type) of detectable vertical inequity. If the coefficient is zero, there is no vertical inequity. If the coefficient is significantly greater (less) than zero, the tax structure is progressive (regressive). AV/SP a asp. (3) 0 1 The Bell (1984) model shown in Equation (4) includes a quadratic term to address potential non-linearity in the data. If the coefficient on the quadratic term is insignificantly different from zero, the model reduces to the Paglin and Fogarty (1972) model discussed above, and the assessment process is linear progressive if the intercept term is negative and linear regressive if the intercept term is positive. If, on the other hand, the coefficient on the quadratic term is significant and negative (positive), the tax system displays accelerating regressivity (progressivity). If neither the intercept nor the coefficient on the quadratic term is significant, there is no indication of inequity in the tax system of either kind. Significance of the coefficient on SP 2 would support the use of this functional form (as opposed to a linear model) in measuring vertical inequity. 2 AV a0 asp 1 asp. 2 (4) The Clapp (1990) model shown in Equation (5) introduces an instrumental variables method that incorporates information from both assessed value and sales price into the dependent variable using two-stage least squares regression. An instrumental variable, Z, is formed by ranking the data by sales price and by assessed value. Z takes the value 1 if the property has both a sales price rank and

Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 175 an assessed value rank in the highest one-third of the observations, 1 ifthe property has both a sales price rank and an assessed value rank in the lowest onethird of the observations, and 0 otherwise. This instrumental variable is first regressed on the natural log of AV, and the predicted values from this first stage regression are then regressed on the natural log of SP. The two-stage model takes the following form: ln AV a az(stage one) 0 1 ln SP B B ln AV (stage two). (5) 0 1 A coefficient estimate for B 1 greater than one indicates that lower valued properties are assessed at a higher proportion of value than are higher-valued properties (regressive), a value less than one indicates the opposite situation (progressive), and a value equal to one indicates an equitable situation. The potential presence of non-linearity in assessment data and the possibility that the functional relationship between sales price and assessed value may vary for some portions of some data sets led Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton (1990) to propose the use of spline regression modeling when analyzing assessment equity. Spline regression techniques are useful when different regions of a data set are explained by different functions, with unique intercept terms and slope coefficients for each region. The Sunderman et al. model is preferred when the relationship between assessed values and sales prices exhibit non-linearity that cannot be captured in a simple quadratic model. For data that display S-shaped relationships between assessed value and sales prices, Sunderman et al. suggest the use of the piecewise spline regression model as shown in Equation (6): AV a a SP a LOW a HIGH 00 10 01 02 a LOWSP a HIGHSP (6) 11 12 where: LOW Dummy variable equal to one if the property s sales price is lower than the first knot, otherwise zero; HIGH Dummy variable equal to one if the property s sales price is higher than the first knot, otherwise zero; LOWSP Sales price of the property if the sales price is lower than the first knot, otherwise zero; and HIGHSP Sales price of the property if the sales price is higher than the second knot, otherwise zero; and a 00 through a 12 are parameters to be estimated. JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003

176 Allen The piecewise spline model allows multiple relationships to exist among low-, average- and high-valued properties. The knots are subjectively selected to distinguish between data value range categories based on observed inflection points in the data. Inequity is indicated for different value ranges of properties in a data set by significance of the estimated intercept parameters a 00, a 01 and a 02. As argued by Smith (2000), the choice of which model to employ to test for vertical inequity is first contingent on the researcher s perception or a priori information on the source of error in the analysis. If the source of error is believed to be in the use of sales price as a proxy for market value, then Clapp s (1990) model is more appropriate. Otherwise, the final decision about which model is most appropriate depends, as discussed by Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton (1990), on whether the relationship between observed assessed values and sales prices is linear or nonlinear. Empirical Analysis of Vertical Inequity in the Property Tax Structure To apply the measures of vertical inequity discussed above, a sample of properties was drawn from the population of small-scale, multi-family properties in the Fort Lauderdale (Broward County), Florida, metropolitan area. (This population of properties was selected for analysis based on data availability.) Florida law requires the (elected) county property appraiser to certify the accuracy of the tax roll and the assessed value of all taxable properties in the county as of January 1 of each year. A search of the 2001 Broward County records identified 16,785 tax parcels containing two to ten residential units. Most of these properties appear to be owned by non-institutional, Mom & Pop investors. In 2001, slightly more than 8% (1,369) of these properties were transferred via warranty deed, with sales price being recording in public records. To the extent that the properties sold during the study period are representative of the population of such properties, this sample is unbiased. Screening the sold properties to eliminate those with missing data and those for which the sales price appears to be the result of other than arm s-length negotiations yields a final sample of 688 observations. In particular, properties were eliminated from the sample if the buyer and seller had the same family name, if either the buyer or the seller was a financial institution or government agency, if the transaction involved multiple tax parcels, or if the implied assessed value to sales price ratio for the property was less than 70% or greater than 1.25%. 1 The observations in the final sample are geographically distributed throughout the Fort Lauderdale metropolitan area. Descriptive statistics for sales price, assessed value, assessed value/sales price ratio, year built and number of residential units for the properties included in the final sample (by quartiles) are provided in Exhibit 1. Applying the various models for detecting vertical inequity to the sample data generates the results shown in Exhibit 2. With the exception of the Sunderman,

Exhibit 1 Descriptive Statistics for Multifamily Property Assessment Data Sample JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003 Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. Panel A: All Observations (N 688) Sales Price (SP) $150,755.02 $72,955.38 $20,000 $465,000 Assessed Value (AV ) $126,537.22 $61,106.67 $18,410 $502,660 AV / SP Ratio 0.85 0.13 0.70 1.24 Year Built 1968.67 10.03 1950 1999 Number of Residential Units 2.89 1.47 2 10 Panel B: First Quartile (N 172) Sales Price (SP) $77,772.09 $14,171.32 $20,000 $98,000 Assessed Value (AV ) $71,045.17 $16,387.60 $18,410 $115,670 AV / SP Ratio 0.92 0.15 0.70 1.24 Year Built 1964.99 9.74 1950 1993 Number of Residential Units 2.23 0.63 2 6 Panel C: Second Quartile (N 184) Sales Price (SP) $119,795.11 $10,598.22 $99,900 $135,000 Assessed Value (AV ) $100,120.92 $14,844.88 $70,370 $157,870 AV / SP Ratio 0.84 0.11 0.70 1.23 Year Built 1970.49 9.49 1950 1997 Number of Residential Units 2.29 0.64 2 7 Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 177

Exhibit 1 (continued) Descriptive Statistics for Multifamily Property Assessment Data Sample 178 Allen Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. Panel D: Third Quartile (N 172) Sales Price (SP) $157,213.04 $13,155.99 $136,300 $185,000 Assessed Value (AV ) $130,364.65 $19,655.56 $100,740 $198,620 AV / SP Ratio 0.83 0.11 0.70 1.24 Year Built 1970.23 9.38 1950 1999 Number of Residential Units 2.91 1.18 2 8 Panel E: Fourth Quartile (N 160) Sales Price (SP) $257,873.21 $63,268.79 $85,000 $465,000 Assessed Value (AV ) $212,455.44 $59,941.29 $131,530 $502,660 AV / SP Ratio 0.82 0.12 0.70 1.21 Year Built 1968.86 10.63 1950 1999 Number of Residential Units 4.25 2.03 2 10 Note: The number of observations in each quartile group varies due to ties in the sales price data.

Exhibit 2 Results from Applying Vertical Inequity Measures to Multifamily Property Sample Data JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003 Intercept 7,248.29* (4.128) Paglin and Fogarty Model Cheng Model IAAO Model Bell Model 0.802* (5.848) SP 0.791* (75.456) lnsp 0.918* (79.162) 0.910* (81.272) 3.8e-07* (5.676) 11,237.68* (3.147) 0.743* (18.581) Clapp Model (Second Stage) 0.378 (1.520) Sunderman et al. Model 4,365.34 (0.322) 0.865* (8.733) SP 2 1.23e-07 (1.283) lnav 1.047* (49.10) LOW 18,098.11 (1.201) HIGH 7,347.39 (0.509) LOWSP 0.133 (1.065) HIGHSP 0.056 (0.550) F-Statistic 5,693.68* 6,266.58* 32.22* 2,850.34* 2,410.70* 1,140.74* R 2 (%) 89.25 90.13 4.49 89.27 77.85 89.32 Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 179

Exhibit 2 (continued) Results from Applying Vertical Inequity Measures to Multifamily Property Sample Data 180 Allen Paglin and Fogarty Model Cheng Model IAAO Model Bell Model Clapp Model (Second Stage) Sunderman et al. Model Interpretation Regressive (intercept term is significantly greater than zero). Regressive (slope coefficient is significantly less than one based on F-Statistic of 50.32, which is significant at the 1% level). Regressive (slope coefficient is significantly less than zero). Regressive (significant positive intercept term indicates regressivity, significant slope term and insignificant quadratic term indicate linearity). Regressive (slope coefficient is significantly greater than one based on F- Statistic of 4.87, which is significant at the 5% level). Equitable (insignificant intercept, LOW, and HIGH terms). Notes: t-statistics are in parentheses. N 688. *Indicates significance at the 1% level Paglin and Fogarty Model: AV a 0 a 1 SP. Cheng Model: AV a 0 a 1 ln SP. IAAO Model: AV /SP a 0 a 1 SP. Bell Model: AV a 0 a 1 SP a 2 SP 2. Clapp Model (second stage results only): ln SP B 0 B 1 ln AV. Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton: AV a 00 a 10 SP a 01 LOW a 02 HIGH a 11 LOWSP a 12 HIGHSP.

Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 181 Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton (1990) model, the results indicate that lower value properties in this sample are assessed at a higher proportion of market value (as proxied by sales price) than are higher value properties (significance level of 1%). The intercept term in the Paglin and Fogarty (1972) model is positive and significantly different from zero. The R 2 for this model is.89. The slope coefficient in the Cheng (1974) model is significantly less than one, based on an F-Statistic of 50.32, which is significant at the 1% level. The Cheng model has an R 2 of.90. Though small in magnitude, the slope coefficient in the IAAO (1978) model is negative and significant. The R 2 for the IAAO model is only.04, which is consistent with the R 2 reported in other studies using the IAAO model. In the Bell (1984) model, the significant and positive intercept term indicates a regressive tax system, but the coefficient on the quadratic term is not statistically significant. The R 2 for the Bell model is.89. The slope coefficient of 1.047 from the second stage of the Clapp (1990) model is significantly greater than 1 at the 5% level Exhibit 3 Relationship between AV and SP in Multifamily Property Sample 500 400 Assessed Value (AV in $000) 300 200 100 Perfect Equity 45 Degree Line Regression Line AV = 7.2483 +0.7913SP R 2 =.8925 0 0 100 200 300 400 500 Sales Price (SP in $000) JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003

182 Allen based on an F-Statistic of 4.87, but the difference is not significant at the 1% level. The R 2 for the Clapp model is.78. The intercept term and the coefficients for LOW and HIGH in the Sunderman, Birch, Cannaday and Hamilton (1990) model are not significantly different from zero, indicating no vertical inequity in the tax structure for this sample. However, a plot of the data shown in Exhibit 3 (with a fitted linear trend line and a 45 degree line that indicates perfect equity with all properties assessed at 100% of their market values) does not support an S-shaped relationship between assessed value and sales price, suggesting that the spline model is not the appropriate functional form for testing vertical inequity in this sample. Even so, the R 2 for the Sunderman et al. model is approximately.89. (The results shown are based on knots determined by the break points identifying the lowest and highest onethirds of the sample based on sales price. Varying the knots by 10% in either direction does not affect the insignificance of the coefficients of interest.) Conclusion Previous studies that have examined vertical inequity in ad valorem property tax systems have largely focused on single-family residential properties. This study applies several of the analysis methods proposed in those studies to examine vertical inequity in the property tax system for a sample of multi-family properties. The choice of which of the various models to use to measure vertical inequity in this and other multi-family property markets depends largely on the nature of the relationship between assessed value and sales price and on whether sales price is a reasonable estimate of market value. Because the market for small-scale (twoto ten-unit) multi-family properties in the Fort Lauderdale metropolitan area appears to have been adequately active during the sample period, sales price is a reasonable proxy for market value. Furthermore, visual inspection of a plot of the data used in this study suggests that the relationship between assessed value and sales price is approximately linear. Together, these characteristics suggest that the Paglin and Fogarty (1972) model and the Cheng (1974) model are most appropriate for measuring vertical inequity in this sample. Both of these models (along with the IAAO, 1978; Bell, 1984; and Clapp, 1990) models) indicate the presence of vertical inequity. Specifically, the evidence indicates that lower value properties are assessed at a higher proportion of their market value than are higher value properties. This finding is consistent with the notion that the assessment process is more accurate for lower value properties in this market. Owners of higher value properties in this market appear to be receiving favorable tax treatment in comparison to owners of lower value properties. To demonstrate the economic significance of this finding, consider that the average property in the lowest price quartile of this sample has an indicated market value of $77,772 and is assessed at 92% of this amount and that the average property

Measuring Vertical Property Tax Inequity 183 in the highest price quartile has an indicated market value of $257,873 and is assessed at 82% of this amount. Applying a tax rate of 30 mills to assessed value (or 3%, which is typical for this market), the effective tax rate in terms of market value for the average property in the lowest price quartile is 2.76% ((77772.92.03)/77772.0276) while the effective tax rate in terms of market value for the average property in the highest price quartile is 2.46% ((257873.82.03)/257873 0.0246). If the average property in the lowest price quartile were assessed at 82% of market value instead of 92%, the annual tax bill (at 30 mills) for that property would be $1,913.19 instead of $2,146.51, an annual property tax savings of $227.32, or 10.6%. Capitalizing this savings (which can be interpreted as an increase in net operating income) at an assumed overall rate of 10% suggests that property value in the lowest price quartile could be increased by an average of $2,273.20, or 2.92% (2273.20/77772 0.0292). While these results can not be generalized to all multi-family property markets, this study demonstrates how vertical property tax inequity can be measured in other multi-family property markets and should prove valuable for multi-family property owners in their efforts to maximize profitability. Endnote 1 The first three screening criteria (transactions involving the same family name, government agencies or financial institutions) serve to eliminate transactions with different conditions of sale that could result in observed prices that are biased from market value. The fourth screening criterion eliminates transactions involving more than one property. This screen is necessary because recorded prices reflect the total transaction price without distinguishing the price of individual parcels when there are multiple parcels included in the transaction. The final screening criteria serves to eliminate potential outliers in the data for which assessed value and transaction price differ widely such that AV/SP 0.70 or AV/SP 1.25. Outliers could be the result of personal property being included in the transaction, unusual financing arrangements, a property being significantly renovated or damaged between the date of the assessment and the transaction date, changes in the property s highest and best use between these dates, or numerous other issues. Taken together, the net effect of these five screening criteria is to narrow the range of AV/SP ratios included in the sample, which could bias the analysis in favor of the null hypothesis (no vertical inequity in this sample). References Bell, E. J., Administrative Inequity and Property Assessment: The Case for the Traditional Approach, Property Tax Journal, 1984, 3:2, 123 31. Benson, E. D. and A. L. Schwartz, Jr., Vertical Equity in the Taxation of Single-Family Homes, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1997, 14:3, 215 31. Benson, E. D. and A. L. Schwartz, Jr., An Examination of Vertical Equity Over Two Reassessment Cycles, Journal of Real Estate Research, 2000, 19:3, 255 73. Cheng, P. L., Property Taxation, Assessment Performance and Its Measurement, Public Finance, 1974, 29:3, 268 84. JRER Vol. 25 No. 2 2003

184 Allen Clapp, J. M., A New Test for Equitable Real Estate Tax Assessment, Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 1990, 3:9, 233 49. Denne, R. C., Introduction, in Analyzing Assessment Equity: Techniques for Measuring and Improving the Quality of Property Tax Administrations, Edited by the International Association of Assessing Officers, Chicago, IL, 1977. Doering, W. W., Property Tax Equalization and Conventional Measures of Assessment Performance, in Analyzing Assessment Equity: Techniques for Measuring and Improving the Quality of Property Tax Administrations, International Association of Assessing Officers (Ed.), Chicago, IL, 1977. Haurin, D. R., An Empirical Analysis of Property Tax Equity, Property Tax Journal, 1988, 5 18. International Association of Assessing Officers, Improving Real Property Assessment: A Reference Manual, Chicago IL, 1978. Kochin, L. A. and R. W. Parks, Vertical Equity in Real Estate Assessment: A Fair Appraisal, Economic Inquiry, 1982, 20, 511 31. Paglin, J. L. and M. Fogarty, Equity and the Property Tax: A New Conceptual Focus, National Tax Journal, 1972, 25, 557 65. Reinmuth, J. E., The Measurement of Vertical Inequities in Assessment Practice, in Analyzing Assessment Equity: Techniques for Measuring and Improving the Quality of Property Tax Administrations, International Association of Assessing Officers (Ed.), Chicago, IL, 1977. Sirmans, G. S., B. A. Diskin and H. S. Friday, Vertical Inequity in the Taxation of Real Property, National Tax Journal, 1995, 49, 71 84. Smith, B. C., Applying Models for Vertical Inequity in the Property Tax to a Non-Market Value State, Journal of Real Estate Research, 2000, 19:3, 321 44. Sunderman, M. A., J. W. Birch, R. A. Cannaday and T. W. Hamilton, Testing for Vertical Inequity in Property Tax Systems, Journal of Real Estate Research, 1990, 7, 319 34. This study has greatly benefited from comments and suggestions provided by William Dare of Oklahoma State University, Rhupert Rhodd of Florida Atlantic University, the anonymous reviewers and the Journal of Real Estate Research Special Issue Editor, James Frew. Marcus T. Allen, Florida Atlantic University, Fort Lauderdale, FL 33314 or mallen@fau.edu.