Roundtable on Monetary Policy in a Low Growth, Low Interest Rate Environment



Similar documents
Statement by. Janet L. Yellen. Chair. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Financial Services

Lecture 4: The Aftermath of the Crisis

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

Euro Zone s Economic Outlook and What it Means for the United States

U.S. Fixed Income: Potential Interest Rate Shock Scenario

2013 global economic outlook: Are promising growth trends sustainable? Timothy Hopper, Ph.D., Chief Economist, TIAA-CREF January 24, 2013

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Sweden 2013 Article IV Consultation: Concluding Statement of the Mission Stockholm May 31, 2013

Reducing public debt: Turkey

Chronic deflation in Japan 1

RIA Novosti Press Meeting. Economic Outlook and Policy Challenges for Russia in Odd Per Brekk Senior Resident Representative.

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

authority increases money supply to stimulate the economy, people hoard money.

Session 12. Aggregate Supply: The Phillips curve. Credibility

IW Monetary Outlook December 2015

7. Spillovers from Russia to the CCA

Chapter 12: Gross Domestic Product and Growth Section 1

Governor's Statement No. 34 October 9, Statement by the Hon. BARRY WHITESIDE, Governor of the Bank and the Fund for the REPUBLIC OF FIJI

Economic Outlook, November 2013 November 21, Jeffrey M. Lacker President Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Why Treasury Yields Are Projected to Remain Low in 2015 March 2015

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February Opening remarks by the Governor

Managing the Fragility of the Eurozone. Paul De Grauwe University of Leuven

ECON 3312 Macroeconomics Exam 3 Fall Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets

chapter: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Krugman/Wells 2009 Worth Publishers 1 of 58

Figure 1: Real GDP in the United States

Answer: C Learning Objective: Money supply Level of Learning: Knowledge Type: Word Problem Source: Unique

Better domestic economy but lower rates

Forecasting Chinese Economy for the Years

FLASH ECONOMICS. Are there good reasons not to accept 1% inflation in the euro zone? ECONOMIC RESEARCH

Discussion of Consequences of Government Deficits and Debt

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Long run v.s. short run. Introduction. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

General Certificate of Education Advanced Subsidiary Examination January 2013

With lectures 1-8 behind us, we now have the tools to support the discussion and implementation of economic policy.

Growth and volatility will define global economy in 2016, says PineBridge Investments

Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number

New Monetary Policy Challenges

e 2015f. Real GDP Growth (%)

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Gundlach s High-Conviction Investment Idea By Robert Huebscher December 26, 2012

An outlook on the Spanish economy Official Monetary and Financial Institutions Forum (OMFIF), London

The U.S. Macroeconomic Situation and Monetary Policy

The U.S. Outlook and Monetary Policy. Esther L. George President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City

Strengthening the banking union and the regulatory treatment of banks sovereign exposures Informal ECOFIN, April 22, 2016 Presidency note

International Monetary and Financial Committee

Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

Switzerland 2013 Article for Consultation Preliminary Conclusions Bern, March 18, 2013

Module 4 Glossary. Board of Governors of the Fed. Business Cycle. Contraction in the business cycle Contractionary Fiscal Policy

Lecture 2. Output, interest rates and exchange rates: the Mundell Fleming model.

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 17 MACROECONOMIC VARIABLES AND ISSUES March 17, 2016

Spain Economic Outlook. Rafael Doménech EUI-nomics 2015 Debating the Economic Conditions in the Euro Area and Beyond Firenze, 24th of April, 2015

The U.S. and Midwest Economy in 2016: Implications for Supply Chain Firms

THE RETURN OF CAPITAL EXPENDITURE OR CAPEX CYCLE IN MALAYSIA

Meeting with Analysts

Book Title: Other People s Money: Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in. Publisher: The University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London

organizers for the invitation to share with this distinguished group my views on some of the

MACROECONOMIC AND INDUSTRY ANALYSIS VALUATION PROCESS

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Chapter 9. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

Preparing for 2015 Housing Market Opportunities

2.5 Monetary policy: Interest rates

Moving Forward With the Normalization of Yields

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

Chapter 4 Consumption, Saving, and Investment

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam

Bank credit developments in Spain European Association of Public Banks (EAPB) Annual Congress

E D I T I O N CLEP O F F I C I A L S T U D Y G U I D E. The College Board. College Level Examination Program

Business Conditions Analysis Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 736

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER PROBLEMS WITHOUT ASTERISKS

BANK OF ISRAEL Office of the Spokesperson and Economic Information. Report to the public on the Bank of Israel s discussions prior to deciding on the

Bank of Finland Bulletin 4/2015

X. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1/

Peter Praet: Monetary policy under uncertainty

2.If actual investment is greater than planned investment, inventories increase more than planned. TRUE.

3 Macroeconomics LESSON 8

Monetary Policy as a Carry Trade

ARC Assigns BBB Rating to Italy

Fiscal Consolidation During a Depression

Gauging Current Conditions: The Economic Outlook and Its Impact on Workers Compensation

For a closed economy, the national income identity is written as Y = F (K; L)

18 ECB FACTORS AFFECTING LENDING TO THE PRIVATE SECTOR AND THE SHORT-TERM OUTLOOK FOR MONEY AND LOAN DYNAMICS

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

Research and Statistics Department, Bank of Japan.

Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy

Research. What Impact Will Ballooning Government Debt Levels Have on Government Bond Yields?

Financial Evolution and Stability The Case of Hedge Funds

OVERCOMING THE ZERO BOUND WITH NEGATIVE INTEREST RATE POLICY

Chapter 12. Aggregate Expenditure and Output in the Short Run

18 ECB STYLISED FACTS OF MONEY AND CREDIT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE

In this chapter we learn the potential causes of fluctuations in national income. We focus on demand shocks other than supply shocks.

@%C+DE !"#$%&'( 1)*L4=#*+.C+2))3)& .)$)&+/&#0* /4&)$5+67"' 87)9+:%;#*'%*

Transcription:

Istanbul Finance Summit Roundtable on Monetary Policy in a Low Growth, Low Interest Rate Environment Senior Deputy Governor of the Bank of Italy Salvatore Rossi Istanbul, 8 September 2015

The role of interest rates short- or long-term, nominal or real is pervasive in modern economies. Changes in interest rates affect: the value of wealth accumulated by savers, their propensity to save, the financing cost for borrowers, the evaluation of investment projects, the sustainability of fiscal debt, the stance of monetary policy. And the list could go on. We know that in many advanced economies, short- and long-term nominal interest rates are at historically low levels. And they have been very low for several years by now. This environment should not be viewed merely as a consequence of the central banks' reaction to the global financial crisis; in a longer time perspective, it is also the end point of a trend. Some data: since the early 1990s the 10-year nominal yields on Government bonds have declined by 10 percentage points in the UK, 9 in the euro area, 6 in the US and Japan; short-term nominal interest rates have followed a similar pattern though with a larger volatility. How come? What are the associated risks and policy changes? In trying to answer these questions let me first recall that the nominal interest rate can be viewed as the sum of three components: 1) the real interest rate, 2) the expected inflation, and 3) a term premium. Economic theory tells us that the real interest rate is the price that equates the supply of savings with the demand for funds aimed at financing investment. Supply and demand, in turn, are determined by factors such the preference of households to smooth consumption across time and the productivity of capital. The expected inflation and the term premium components of the nominal interest rate are self-explaining: when buying a long term bond I want a return that could compensate me for the potential loss in my future purchasing power, and for the risk of a potential capital loss if I needed to sell the bond prior to maturity.

A lot of influencing factors are involved here: expectations about future economic growth and inflation; the degree of risk aversion; financial markets volatility, domestically and abroad, since capital markets have become globally integrated. Which of these factors can explain the current low interest rate environment? I would indicate two sets of factors: transitory, and structural. The latter are particularly important, since they may suggest that the current environment is a longrun phenomenon, bound to stay with us for quite some time. The transitory factors are evident: first of all the expansionary monetary policy stance put in place by many central banks in response to the global financial crisis, and, in the euro area, also to the sovereign debt crisis. We know that most central banks in the advanced countries, as policy rates were reaching the zero lower bound, have enriched their monetary policy toolbox with various unconventional measures, the most important and visible one being programs of securities purchases (QE). Another transitory factor is the de-leveraging by the private sector. In part this is due to a financial regulation becoming much stricter than before the crisis. And here comes the structural factors. They can be summarized as follows: an excess of desired saving over desired investment, leading to lower economic growth and real interest rates. This is essentially the secular stagnation hypothesis proposed last year by Larry Summers 1. Barry Eichengreen, one of the most prominent economic historians of our times, has recently written an illuminating article on this topic 2. He discusses four possible explanations. 1) High savings rates in emerging-market economies. This is the well-known global savings glut hypothesis put forward years ago by Ben Bernanke 3. The idea is 1 Summers, H. L. (2014), U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound. Business Economics, 49, pp. 65-73. 2 Eichengreen, B. (2015), Secular Stagnation: The Long View. American Economic Review, pp. 66-70. 3 Bernanke, B. S. (2005), The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. The Sandburg Lecture, Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA, March 10. 3

that in some emerging countries, China in particular, social protection systems are so limited and weak that households feel forced to increase their precautionary saving. 2) The decline in the relative price of investment goods (machinery, equipment, ICTs), thanks to technological progress. For a given investment project, a fall in the relative price of investment reduces the demand for funds. With less investment spending chasing the same savings, the result can be a lower real interest rates and, potentially, a chronic excess of desired saving over desired investment. 3) A lower rate of population growth, in the advanced economies and now also in some emerging markets. It is reflected in a slower growth of the labor force, in turn requiring less investment. 4) The fourth possible explanation is the more controversial one. The idea is that the pace of scientific and technological inventions has slowed down, since the golden XX century of electricity and ICTs, and will never recover, causing a corresponding permanent scarcity of high-return investment opportunities. Robert Gordon is a supporter of such a pessimistic view 4. Personally, I don't believe in this fourth factor: the innovative capabilities of humankind have always caught philosophers and economists by surprise. But the other three factors are serious and deserve to be addressed. Let me now briefly touch upon some policy implications. Nearly eight years after the onset of the financial crisis, global growth is disappointing on average, but with a high variance across countries and regions. The U.S. recovery is continuing at a sustained pace, while growth in the euro area and Japan is currently still modest, though expected to pick up. Emerging economies' growth will decline for the fifth year in a row in 2015, although these economies will continue to increase their share of global GDP. 4 Gordon, R. (2012), Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 18315. 4

Against this outlook, monetary policy stance across major economies may become asynchronous in the coming months, when the Federal Reserve will actually start the announced normalization process. The big question is: how much transitory are the transitory factors explaining the current low interest rate environment? What will happen when monetary policy normalizes? Or will the structural factors prevail and keep real and nominal interest rates low forever, or at least for a very long time? On the first point, Reinhart and Rogoff 5, among others, have shown that in the aftermath of financial crises economic recessions tend to be more severe than in typical business cycle recessions and the recovery takes longer. Credit cycles last longer than business cycles. But eventually they come to an end, once households and corporates balance sheets have been repaired. And that poses the problem of how and when normalizing monetary policy. On the second point, a challenge relates to possible spillover effects on emerging-market economies of changes in the monetary policy stance in advanced countries. Large capital flows went to emerging-market economies in the last years, in search for yield, putting upward pressure on asset prices and exchange rates in those economies. They might suddenly reverse when monetary conditions change in advanced economies. The risk is that the process becomes disorderly, with impaired liquidity in certain markets or asset classes, rapidly diffusing contagion to other correlated asset classes. These risks call for clear and effective communication strategies by central banks, while the authorities in emerging economies should further strengthen policy buffers and further advance structural reforms. Another delicate policy challenge regards the relation between monetary and fiscal policies. The combination of high public debt accumulated in many advanced economies in response to the financial crisis and very low interest rates has strengthened the interdependencies between the two policies. 5 Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. (2009), This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. 5

Exceptionally low nominal interest rates have contained debt servicing costs, and that's good news; the flip side is that fiscal positions are highly exposed to changes in the monetary policy stance, especially if changes are abrupt. Finally, what if the current low interest rates were the new long-run equilibrium? In this case I would see serious challenges for monetary policy management. Central banks might more often encounter the zero lower bound on nominal rates, which would imply less room to maneuver the policy rate to counteract deflationary shocks. The economy would be less resilient to negative shocks. Central banks might have to increasingly resort to what we call unconventional policies. But we do not know how effective these tools are as a normal business cycle stabilizer, and what macroeconomic risks they might entail. Let me conclude signaling another risk. Economic policies became exceptionally accommodative after the financial crisis in order to save the world from another Great Depression. Financial panic was destroying households' and corporates' confidence and curtailing aggregate demand, so macroeconomic policies, both fiscal and monetary, had to fill the gap, as long as needed. The phase of very low nominal interest rates has been necessary, and still is necessary in many areas of the world including the euro area, in order to support growth, fight deflation risks and sustain employment. But low growth, and the ensuing low interest rates, risk feeding on themselves if allowed to linger for too long: households may eventually feel compelled to save more, because they see, for instance, their insurance policies and retirement schemes at risk of not being fully honored. At the same time, low growth implies low return from real investment, and this creates perverse incentives to search for yield taking risk on board; this may jeopardize financial stability. One main lesson comes from these considerations. The most effective and long-lasting solution to tackle the declining trend of real interest rates is to act forcefully and preemptively to support growth. Support remains necessary from the demand side; but in the longer run it must come from the supply side, by identifying and implementing those reforms that, encouraging investment, may boost 6

productivity and support job creation. We need to prove Robert Gordon's prophecy wrong. The consequent increase in potential economic growth would raise the real interest rate and push nominal interest rates into a safer territory. 7