Results from the Dixit/Stiglitz monopolistic competition model



Similar documents
17 Capital tax competition

Production. 2. Y is closed A set is closed if it contains its boundary. We need this for the solution existence in the profit maximization problem.

Addendum to: Importing Skill-Biased Technology

Chapter 7: Answers to Questions and Problems

Institute of Informatics, Faculty of Business and Management, Brno University of Technology,Czech Republic

1 Example 1: Axis-aligned rectangles

Problem Set 3. a) We are asked how people will react, if the interest rate i on bonds is negative.

Structural Estimation of Variety Gains from Trade Integration in a Heterogeneous Firms Framework

Calculation of Sampling Weights

Fisher Markets and Convex Programs

Trade Adjustment and Productivity in Large Crises. Online Appendix May Appendix A: Derivation of Equations for Productivity

Kiel Institute for World Economics Duesternbrooker Weg Kiel (Germany) Kiel Working Paper No. 1119

Elements of Advanced International Trade 1

Answer: A). There is a flatter IS curve in the high MPC economy. Original LM LM after increase in M. IS curve for low MPC economy

Support Vector Machines

Price Competition in an Oligopoly Market with Multiple IaaS Cloud Providers

Substitution Effects in Supply Chains with Asymmetric Information Distribution and Upstream Competition

Solution: Let i = 10% and d = 5%. By definition, the respective forces of interest on funds A and B are. i 1 + it. S A (t) = d (1 dt) 2 1. = d 1 dt.

How Sets of Coherent Probabilities May Serve as Models for Degrees of Incoherence

An Alternative Way to Measure Private Equity Performance

SPEE Recommended Evaluation Practice #6 Definition of Decline Curve Parameters Background:

Follow links for Class Use and other Permissions. For more information send to:

THE DISTRIBUTION OF LOAN PORTFOLIO VALUE * Oldrich Alfons Vasicek

8.5 UNITARY AND HERMITIAN MATRICES. The conjugate transpose of a complex matrix A, denoted by A*, is given by

IS-LM Model 1 C' dy = di

Leveraged Firms, Patent Licensing, and Limited Liability

Recurrence. 1 Definitions and main statements

How To Calculate The Accountng Perod Of Nequalty

The Economics of Two-sided Markets 2. Platform competition!

where the coordinates are related to those in the old frame as follows.

Income Distribution, Product Quality, and International Trade

The OC Curve of Attribute Acceptance Plans

Oligopoly Theory Made Simple

Quasi-Hyperbolic Discounting and Social Security Systems

The literature on many-server approximations provides significant simplifications toward the optimal capacity

Abstract. Abstract Introduction Two Models Classic Optimal Lot Size (OLS) Model Monopolistic Competition 3

Luby s Alg. for Maximal Independent Sets using Pairwise Independence

Multi-Product Price Optimization and Competition under the Nested Logit Model with Product-Differentiated Price Sensitivities

OPTIMAL INVESTMENT POLICIES FOR THE HORSE RACE MODEL. Thomas S. Ferguson and C. Zachary Gilstein UCLA and Bell Communications May 1985, revised 2004

Equlbra Exst and Trade S effcent proportionally

On the Role of Consumer Expectations in Markets with Network Effects

Industry export competitiveness and optimal quantitative strategies for international emissions trading

Section 5.4 Annuities, Present Value, and Amortization

The Games of Cournot Sports

8 Algorithm for Binary Searching in Trees

Buy-side Analysts, Sell-side Analysts and Private Information Production Activities

The Greedy Method. Introduction. 0/1 Knapsack Problem

Economic Models for Cloud Service Markets

The Stock Market Game and the Kelly-Nash Equilibrium

Marginal Benefit Incidence Analysis Using a Single Cross-section of Data. Mohamed Ihsan Ajwad and Quentin Wodon 1. World Bank.

On the Optimal Control of a Cascade of Hydro-Electric Power Stations

Pricing Model of Cloud Computing Service with Partial Multihoming

Supply network formation as a biform game

2008/8. An integrated model for warehouse and inventory planning. Géraldine Strack and Yves Pochet

Module 2 LOSSLESS IMAGE COMPRESSION SYSTEMS. Version 2 ECE IIT, Kharagpur

Power-of-Two Policies for Single- Warehouse Multi-Retailer Inventory Systems with Order Frequency Discounts

GASTALE: An oligopolistic model of production and trade in the European gas market

RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPER

IDENTIFICATION AND CORRECTION OF A COMMON ERROR IN GENERAL ANNUITY CALCULATIONS

Logistic Regression. Lecture 4: More classifiers and classes. Logistic regression. Adaboost. Optimization. Multiple class classification

Cautiousness and Measuring An Investor s Tendency to Buy Options

Depreciation of Business R&D Capital

No 144. Bundling and Joint Marketing by Rival Firms. Thomas D. Jeitschko, Yeonjei Jung, Jaesoo Kim

Optimality in an Adverse Selection Insurance Economy. with Private Trading. November 2014

reduce competition increase market power cost savings economies of scale and scope cost savings Oliver Williamson: the efficiency defense

BERNSTEIN POLYNOMIALS

NMT EE 589 & UNM ME 482/582 ROBOT ENGINEERING. Dr. Stephen Bruder NMT EE 589 & UNM ME 482/582

PRICING AND REPLENISHMENT STRATEGIES IN A DISTRIBUTION SYSTEM WITH COMPETING RETAILERS

J. Parallel Distrib. Comput.

How To Compare Frm To An Isac

Performance Analysis of Energy Consumption of Smartphone Running Mobile Hotspot Application

benefit is 2, paid if the policyholder dies within the year, and probability of death within the year is ).

PRIVATE SCHOOL CHOICE: THE EFFECTS OF RELIGIOUS AFFILIATION AND PARTICIPATION

Can Auto Liability Insurance Purchases Signal Risk Attitude?

TENSOR GAUGE FIELDS OF DEGREE THREE

Analysis of Premium Liabilities for Australian Lines of Business

1. Fundamentals of probability theory 2. Emergence of communication traffic 3. Stochastic & Markovian Processes (SP & MP)

DEFINING %COMPLETE IN MICROSOFT PROJECT

Discriminatory versus Uniform-Price Electricity Auctions with Supply Function Equilibrium

What should (public) health insurance cover?

Enabling P2P One-view Multi-party Video Conferencing

Product-Form Stationary Distributions for Deficiency Zero Chemical Reaction Networks

Capacity Reservation for Time-Sensitive Service Providers: An Application in Seaport Management

Awell-known result in the Bayesian inventory management literature is: If lost sales are not observed, the

Optimal Consumption and Investment with Transaction Costs and Multiple Risky Assets

Modelling the Cocaine and Heroin Markets in the Era of Globalization and Drug Reduction Policies Claudia Costa Storti and Paul De Grauwe

When Talk is Free : The Effect of Tariff Structure on Usage under Two- and Three-Part Tariffs

n + d + q = 24 and.05n +.1d +.25q = 2 { n + d + q = 24 (3) n + 2d + 5q = 40 (2)

SUPPLIER FINANCING AND STOCK MANAGEMENT. A JOINT VIEW.

Understanding the Impact of Marketing Actions in Traditional Channels on the Internet: Evidence from a Large Scale Field Experiment

What does economic theory tell us about labour market tightness?

Outsourcing Service Processes to a Common Service Provider under Price and Time Competition

BANDWIDTH ALLOCATION AND PRICING PROBLEM FOR A DUOPOLY MARKET

Adverse selection in the annuity market with sequential and simultaneous insurance demand. Johann K. Brunner and Susanne Pech *) January 2005

Internet companies extensively use the practice of drop-shipping, where the wholesaler stocks and owns the

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions

Regulation, Market Structure and Service Trade Liberalization

Number of Levels Cumulative Annual operating Income per year construction costs costs ($) ($) ($) 1 600,000 35, , ,200,000 60, ,000

The Mathematical Derivation of Least Squares

What is Candidate Sampling

Transcription:

Results from the Dxt/Stgltz monopolstc competton model Rchard Foltyn February 4, 2012 Contents 1 Introducton 1 2 Constant elastcty sub-utlty functon 1 2.1 Preferences and demand.............................. 1 2.1.1 General case................................ 2 2.1.2 Cobb-Douglas case ( Dxt-Stgltz lte )................. 7 2.2 Frms and producton............................... 8 2.3 Market equlbrum................................. 8 1 Introducton The Dxt/Stgltz monopolstc competton model has been wdely adopted n varous felds of economc research such as nternatonal trade. The Dxt and Stgltz (1977) paper actually contans three dstnct models, yet economc lterature has mostly taken up only the frst one (constant elastcty case) and ts market equlbrum soluton. The man results of ths subset of Dxt and Stgltz (1977) are derved and explaned below n order to ad n understandng ths wdespread model. 2 Constant elastcty sub-utlty functon 2.1 Preferences and demand Assumpton 2.1. Preferences are gven by a (weakly-)separable, convex utlty functon u = U(x 0, V (x 1, x 2,..., x n )) where U( ) s ether a socal ndfference curve or the multple of a representatve consumer s utlty. x 0 s a numerare good produced n one sector whle x 1, x 2,..., x n are dfferentated goods produced n another sector. 1 1 Wth weakly-separable utlty functons, the MRS (and thus the elastcty of substtuton) of two goods from the same group s ndependent of the quanttes of goods n other sub-groups (see Gravelle and Rees 2004, 67). 1

Dxt and Stgltz (1977) treat three dfferent cases n whch they alternately mpose two of the three followng restrctons: 1. symmetry of V ( ) w.r.t. to ts arguments; 2. CES specfcaton for V ( ) 3. Cobb-Douglas form for U( ) However, throughout the lterature many authors have mposed all three restrctons together n what Neary (2004) calls Dxt-Stgltz lte. The next secton examnes the more general case n whch only restrctons 1 and 2 are mposed. Subsecton 2.1.2 brefly looks and the more specal case of Dxt-Stgltz lte. 2.1.1 General case Frst-stage optmzaton. Assumpton 2.2. In the CES case the utlty functon s gven as [ ] 1/ρ u = U x 0, wth ρ (0, 1) to allow for zero quanttes and ensure concavty of U( ). ρ s called the substtuton or love-of-varety parameter. 2 Furthermore, U( ) s assumed to be homothetc n ts arguments. Snce U( ) s a separable utlty functon, the consumer optmzaton problem can be solved n two separate steps: frst the optmal allocaton of ncome for each subgroup s determned, then the quanttes wthn each subgroup. Defnton 2.1. Let y be a quantty ndex presentng all goods x 1, x 2,..., x n from the second sector such that [ ] 1/ρ y x ρ. (1) Fgure 1 shows some llustratve examples for the two-dmensonal case. As requred, the utlty functon s concave and x 1, x 2 are nether complements nor perfect substtutes f ρ (0, 1). The frst-stage optmzaton problem s gven as follows: x ρ max. U(x 0, y) s.t. x 0 + q y = I where I s the ncome n terms of the numerare and q s the prce ndex of y. 3 2 Wth ρ = 1, x 1,..., x n are perfect substtutes as the subutlty functon smplfes to V (x 1, x 2,..., x n) = x and thus t does not matter whch x s consumed. For ρ < 0 they are complements (see Brakman et al. 2001, 68). 3 The ncome conssts of an ntal endowment whch s normalzed at 1, plus frm profts dstrbuted to consumers or mnus a lump sum requred to cover frm losses. However, snce the dscusson here s lmted to the market equlbrum case, frms make zero proft so I = 1. 2

Fgure 1: CES functons wth two-dmensonal doman and varyng ρ parameter (from left to rght: ρ = {-10, 0.5, 0.99}). The frst case s excluded n ths model due to the restrctons on parameter ρ. From the Lagrangan L = U(x 0, y) λ[x 0 qy I] we obtan the frst-order condtons From (2) and (3) we get the necessary condton = U 0 λ = 0 x 0 (2) y = U y λq = 0 (3) λ = x 0 + qy I = 0 U y U 0 = q = p y p 0 (4) whch s the famlar U /U = p /p as q s the prce ndex for y and p 0 = 1 due to the numerare defnton. Snce U( ) was assumed homothetc, ths unquely dentfes the share of expendture for x 0 and y because these solely depend on relatve margnal utltes. Denote the share of expendture on y as s(q) and that on x 0 as (1 s(q)). Then the optmal quanttes for each sector are x 0 = (1 s(q))i y = s(q)i q (5) Second-stage optmzaton. s Gven the defnton of y and s(q), the second-state problem max. y = s.t. [ x ρ ] 1/ρ p x = s(q)i 3

The Lagrangan L = ( xρ )1/ρ λ( p x s(q)i) yelds the frst-order condtons = y 1 ρ x ρ 1 λp = 0 x (6) λ = p x s(q)i = 0 (7) Solvng (6) for x gves x = y(λp ) 1/(ρ 1) (8) Insertng ths nto (7) and solvng for λ we get p y(λp ) 1/(ρ 1) = s(q)i λ 1/(ρ 1) y = s(q)i λ 1/(ρ 1) = s(q)i) y [ ] 1 (9) Fnally, pluggng (9) back nto (8) we get the prelmnary demand functon facng a sngle frm n the second sector: 4 x = s(q)ip 1/(ρ 1) 1 (10) To further smplfy ths expresson, take (10) to the power of ρ and sum over : 5 x ρ = [ ] 1/ρ y = x ρ = From (5) and (11) we obtan x ρ = (s(q)i)ρ ρ 1 (s(q)i) ρ s(q)i [ ρ ] 1/ρ s(q)i y = [ ] (ρ 1)/ρ (11) pρ/(ρ 1) Result 2.1. For the utlty functon gven n Assumpton 2.2 and the composte quantty ndex from Defnton 2.1 the correspondng prce ndex s q = [ ] (ρ 1)/ρ (12) 4 The summaton ndex has been changed to to reflect that t n s unrelated to. 5 The last step follows from the fact that both sums are dentcal, regardless whether the ndex or s used. 4

Usng Result 2.1, (10) can be smplfed to arrve at Result 2.2. For the utlty functon gven n Assumpton 2.2, the resultng demand functon facng a sngle frm s [ ] 1/(1 ρ) q x = y (13) p wth y and q defned n (1) and (12), respectvely. Some remarks regardng the demand functon and CES preferences are n order. Frst, by pluggng y = s(q)i/q nto (13) and takng logs, t can easly be seen that the varetes x 1, x 2,..., x n have unt ncome elastctes log x / log I. Second, assumng a suffcently large number of varetes so that prcng decsons of a sngle frm do not affect the general prce ndex, the prce elastcty of demand for x s ɛ d = log x log p = 1 (14) q const. ρ 1 At ths pont t s convenent to defne σ 1/(1 ρ) so that ɛ d = σ. 6 Thrd, to get the elastcty of substtuton between two varetes, from (6) we see that x x = [ ] 1/(1 ρ) p and hence the elastcty of substtuton can be obtaned as Ths can be summarzed as p ɛ s = log(x /x ) log(p /p ) = log(p /p ) 1/(1 ρ) = 1 log(p /p ) 1 ρ = σ (15) Result 2.3. Dxt-Stgltz preferences gven n Assumpton 2.2 result n constant demand and substtuton elastctes gven by ɛ d = 1 ρ 1 = σ ɛ s = 1 1 ρ = σ Often the model s specfed drectly n terms of σ nstead of ρ, 7 wth u = U(x 0, y), y [ x 1 1/σ ] 1/(1 1/σ), q [ p 1 σ ] 1/(1 σ) Fourth, to see why the CES utlty specfcaton s called varety-lovng, nspect the largesubgroup case wth many varetes n wth smlar prce levels,.e. p p and hence x = x. Then expendture s equally dvded over all varetes x 1, x 2,..., x n snce they symmetrcally 6 Here σ s dfferent from σ(q) n Dxt and Stgltz (1977), but reflects the notaton of many other Dxt- Stgltz-based models. 7 For example, see Baldwn et al. (2005, 38). 5

enter nto the subutlty functon. smplfy to If there exst n varetes, the expressons for y and q [ n ] 1/ρ y = x ρ = xn 1/ρ (16) [ n ] (ρ 1)/ρ q = = pn (ρ 1)/ρ (17) Pluggng (5) and (17) nto (13) gves a smplfed demand functon for the large-subgroup case: x = s(q)i np. (18) Substtutng ths for x n the subutlty functon (1), we obtan [ n [ ] ] ρ 1/ρ s(q)i V (n) = y = np (1/ρ) s(q)i = n np = n 1/ρ 1 (nx) whch s ncreasng n n as ρ (0, 1) by assumpton. The last equalty provdes some ntutve nsghts: snce (nx) s the actual quantty produced, the term n 1/ρ 1 > 1 can be seen as an addtonal bonus, so varety represents an externalty or the extent of the market. Increasng the market sze nx has a more than proportonal effect on utlty due to ths term (Brakman et al. 2001, 68). That utlty ncreases wth varety can also be seen by recallng that V (x) = y = s(q)i/q and examnng how q from (17) changes wth n, as shown n Fgure 2. Fgure 2: Prce ndex q as a functon of the number of varetes n (assumng p = 1) q 1.0 0.8 Ρ 0.9 0.6 Ρ 0.5 0.4 0.2 Ρ 0.1 0.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 n It s evdent that for constant expendture, the prce ndex falls rapdly, wth utlty rsng as a consequence. Ths effect s more pronounced for ρ closer to 0, whch can ntutvely be explaned usng Fgure 1: for ρ close to 1, all varetes are close substtutes and hence ntroducng another smlar varety only moderately ncreases utlty. The converse s true for ρ close to 0. 6

2.1.2 Cobb-Douglas case ( Dxt-Stgltz lte ) In ths secton we nspect a specal case of the model n whch all three of the ntally mentoned restrctons on utlty are mposed. Assumpton 2.3. If U( ) s Cobb-Douglas and V ( ) s CES, the resultng utlty functon s gven by u = U(x 0, y) = x 1 α 0 y α. Agan a two-state optmzaton approach s applcable. Frst-stage optmzaton. The maxmzaton problem s stated as follows: max. s.t. u = x 1 α 0 y α (19) x 0 + qy = I As n (4), the necessary condton from the Lagrangan s U y /U 0 = q, whch together wth the budget constrant yelds the well-known result for Cobb-Douglas utlty: x 0 = (1 α)i (20) y = αi q (21) Second-stage optmzaton. From here the second-stage optmzaton proceeds exactly as n the general case, wth α replacng s(q). Usng the defnton of q one arrves at the demand functon gven n Result 2.2. Wth the Cobb-Douglas / CES case t can easly be verfed that a sngle-stage optmzaton process yelds the same results. The Lagrangan n ths case s L = x 1 α 0 wth the relevant frst-order condton beng [ = x (1 α) α 0 x ρ [ ] α/ρ [ x ρ λ x 0 + x ρ p x I ] ] (α ρ)/ρ ρx ρ 1 λp = 0 Dvdng the frst-order condtons for x and x, multplyng by p and summng over the 7

demand functon can be obtaned: I x 0 = x x = [ ] 1/(ρ 1) p p p x = x p = p 1/(1 ρ) p 1/(1 ρ) x x x = (I x 0)p 1/(ρ 1) pρ/(ρ 1) = I x 0 q [ q = y p q 1/(1 ρ) p 1/(1 ρ) ] 1/(1 ρ) [by def. of q] 2.2 Frms and producton It s assumed that all frms producng varetes of x have dentcal fxed and margnal costs. Snce consumers demand all exstng varetes symmetrcally, any new frm enterng the market wll choose to produce a unque varety and explot monopolstc prcng power nstead of enterng nto a duopoly wth an exstng producer. Also, every frm wll choose to produce one varety only (see Baldwn et al. (2005, 42) on how to derve ths result). Producton for each frm exhbts (nternal) ncreasng returns to scale. Ths s mpled by ntroducng fxed costs n addton to (constant) margnal costs as stated above. Hence the cost functon has the form C(x) = cx + F (22) where c s the margnal costs and F the fxed cost per varety (there are no economes of scope). 8 2.3 Market equlbrum Equlbrum n ths model s determned by two condtons: frst, frms maxmze profts consstent wth the demand functon (13); second, as ths creates pure proft whch nduces new frms to enter the market, quanttes of x adust untl the margnal frm ust breaks even (free entry condton). Proft maxmzaton. Snce each frm produces a unque varety, monopolstc prcng apples and each frm faces the maxmzaton problem max. π = p(x)x cx F (23) It s assumed that each frm takes prce settng behavor of other frms as gven (other frms do not adapt ther prces as a reacton to the frm s prce) and that frms gnore effects of ther prcng decsons on the prce ndex q. Agan, ths assumpton s only plausble wth a suffcently large number of frms. 8 As all frms have dentcal cost functons, face dentcal demand functons and all varetes enter symmetrcally nto the utlty functon, subscrpts wll be omtted from now on,.e. x = x, p = p. 8

The necessary frst-order condton resultng from (23) s the well-known ] p [1 + 1ɛd = c [ p 1 1 ] = c σ where ɛ d s the elastcty of demand, whch was shown to equal σ = 1/(ρ 1) n Result 2.3. Solvng for p, we obtan Result 2.4. In equlbrum, the optmal prce s gven by p e = c ρ, where p e s calculated as a constant mark-up over margnal cost c. Free entry condton. As the model assumes free entry, new frms wll enter the market and produce a new varety as long as ths yelds postve proft. When a frm enters the market and starts producng a new varety, consumers dvert some of the expendture prevously spent on exstng varetes to purchase the new good. The quantty of each varety sold decreases, as does proft due to rsng average costs. As a consequence, the free entry condton states that n equlbrum the margnal frm (ndexed by n) ust breaks even,.e. operatng proft equals fxed cost: 9 (p n c)x n = F (24) Wth symmetry and dentcal frms, condton (24) holds for all ntramargnal frms as well. Solvng (24) for x, we get Result 2.5. The free entry condton dctates that n equlbrum the quantty of each varety produced s x e = F p e c = F (σ 1). (25) c Naturally, n equlbrum the number of varetes produced has to be consstent wth the demand functon from (18), and therefore s(p e n e (ρ 1)/ρ ) F = p e n e (p e c) (26) must hold. Ths unquely dentfes an equlbrum f the left-hand sde s a monotonc functon of n, whch s the case f the elastcty w.r.t. n has a determnate sgn. It s assumed to be negatve as the quantty of each varety consumed decreases when more varetes are avalable. See Dxt and Stgltz (1977, 300) for a formal condton for ths to hold. Before fnshng ths secton, some further remarks regardng the equlbrum are necessary. Frst, from (25) t can be seen that equlbrum quanttes are constant and depend on the two cost parameters, F and c, and on one demand parameter, σ, all of whch are exogenously determned. They are ndependent of other factors such as the number of varetes produced. Therefore, aggregate manufacturng output can only ncrease by ncreasng the number of 9 Ignorng nteger constrants, the number of frms n s assumed to be large enough that ths can be stated as an equalty. 9

varetes. Ths determnes the outcome of models such as Krugman (1980), where ncreasng the market sze va trade lberalzaton results n more varetes, not hgher quanttes per frm. 10 Second, calculatng equlbrum operatng proft (gnorng fxed costs) as π e = (p e p e ρ)x e π e = (1 ρ)p e x e π e = p ex e σ we see that operatng profts are determned as a constant proft margn 1/σ of revenue p e x e. 10 However, ths result depends on several assumptons, vz. ce-berg trade costs, homothetc cost functons and mll prcng,.e. nvarant mark-ups (see Baldwn et al. 2005, 42). 10

References Baldwn, R. E., R. Forsld, P. Martn, G. I. P. Ottavano, and F. Robert-Ncoud (2005). Economc geography and publc polcy. Prnceton, N.J.: Prnceton Unv. Press. Brakman, S., H. Garretsen, and C. van Marrewk (2001). An ntroducton to geographcal economcs. Cambrdge: Cambrdge Unv. Press. Dxt, A. K. and J. E. Stgltz (1977). Monopolstc competton and optmum product dversty. Amercan Economc Revew 67 (3), 297 308. Gravelle, H. and R. Rees (2004). Mcroeconomcs (3rd ed.). Harlow: Pearson. Krugman, P. R. (1980). Scale economes, product dfferentaton, and the pattern of trade. Amercan Economc Revew 70 (5), 950 959. Neary, J. P. (2004). Monopolstc competton and nternatonal trade theory. In S. Brakman and B. J. Hedra (Eds.), The Monopolstc Competton Revoluton n Retrospect, pp. 159 184. Cambrdge: Cambrdge Unv. Press. 11