Cost-Benefit Analysis. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley



Similar documents
Notes - Gruber, Public Finance Chapter 20.3 A calculation that finds the optimal income tax in a simple model: Gruber and Saez (2002).

Externalities: Problems and Solutions. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

WHY STUDY PUBLIC FINANCE?

Economics Chapter 7 Review

Chapter 18. MODERN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS Third Edition

TRADE AND INVESTMENT IN THE NATIONAL ACCOUNTS This text accompanies the material covered in class.

Maximising Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus: How do airlines and mobile companies do it?

Economics 101 Multiple Choice Questions for Final Examination Miller

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 6: Measuring the Price Level and Inflation. The Price Level and Inflation. Connection between money and prices. Index Numbers in General

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Long run v.s. short run. Introduction. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Politics, Surpluses, Deficits, and Debt

New Keynesian Theory. Graduate Macroeconomics I ECON 309 Cunningham

Global Financial Management

March 12, 2007 Survey Results on Education Among California Business Leaders

Chapter 13. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Choice of Discount Rate

PART A: For each worker, determine that worker's marginal product of labor.

Concept 5. Inflation What is inflation? Inflation means prices are rising and the purchasing power of the dollar is declining.

Asymmetric Information

Discounted Cash Flow. Alessandro Macrì. Legal Counsel, GMAC Financial Services

Monopolistic Competition

Advanced International Economics Prof. Yamin Ahmad ECON 758

Bailouts and Stimulus Plans. Eugene F. Fama

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Implications of Tax Evasion for Deadweight Loss

THE ECONOMY AT FULL EMPLOYMENT. Objectives. Production and Jobs. Objectives. Real GDP and Employment. Real GDP and Employment CHAPTER

Quantity of trips supplied (millions)

Corporate Finance & Options: MGT 891 Homework #6 Answers

Econ 202 Section 4 Final Exam

The Taxable Income Elasticity and the Implications of Tax Evasion for Deadweight Loss. Jon Bakija, April 2011

For instance between 1960 and 2000 the average hourly output produced by US workers rose by 140 percent.

ECON 443 Labor Market Analysis Final Exam (07/20/2005)

Inquiry into Access of Small Business to Finance

FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING: VISIONARY THINKING OR OXYMORON? Aswath Damodaran

CHAPTER 23 FISCAL POLICY: COPING WITH INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Economic Growth in Cities (and policies to promote it) Economics 312 Martin Farnham

Chapter 7: Market Structures Section 1

1.1 Introduction. Chapter 1: Feasibility Studies: An Overview

E D I T I O N CLEP O F F I C I A L S T U D Y G U I D E. The College Board. College Level Examination Program

Labor Demand The Labor Market

hp calculators HP 17bII+ Net Present Value and Internal Rate of Return Cash Flow Zero A Series of Cash Flows What Net Present Value Is

FISCAL POLICY* Chapter. Key Concepts

Obligation-based Asset Allocation for Public Pension Plans

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Lab 17: Consumer and Producer Surplus

applet-magic.com INTRODUCTION TO COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS

Name: Date: 3. Variables that a model tries to explain are called: A. endogenous. B. exogenous. C. market clearing. D. fixed.

2016 Wiley. Study Session 2: Quantitative Methods Basic Concepts

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART I BASIC CONCEPTS

Prof. Robert N. Stavins ENR-201/Econ Fundamentals of Net Present Value Analysis

Consumers face constraints on their choices because they have limited incomes.

We will study the extreme case of perfect competition, where firms are price takers.

REVIEW of Marxian Political Economy: Theory, History and Contemporary Relevance

Chapter 7 Externalities

ECON 102 Spring 2014 Homework 3 Due March 26, 2014

Fiscal Policy: Structural/Cyclical. Size of government Questions And Business Cycle Smoothing Issues

CHAPTER 13 MARKETS FOR LABOR Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Chapter 6 Supply, Demand, and Government Policies

Midterm Exam - Answers. November 3, 2005

ECON 600 Lecture 5: Market Structure - Monopoly. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes.

Capital Structure: Informational and Agency Considerations

Theory of Demand. ECON 212 Lecture 7. Tianyi Wang. Winter Queen s Univerisity. Tianyi Wang (Queen s Univerisity) Lecture 7 Winter / 46

NATIONAL INCOME AND PRODUCT ACCOUNTING MEASURING THE MACROECONOMY

Chapter 15: Spending, Income and GDP

Market Supply in the Short Run

The Cost of Production

Determinants of Social Discount Rate, general case

7 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapter. Key Concepts

Econ 201 Final Exam. Douglas, Fall 2007 Version A Special Codes PLEDGE: I have neither given nor received unauthorized help on this exam.

Prospect Theory Ayelet Gneezy & Nicholas Epley

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2015

LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES

Example 1. Consider the following two portfolios: 2. Buy one c(s(t), 20, τ, r) and sell one c(s(t), 10, τ, r).

Hurley, Chapter 7 (see also review in chapter 3)

ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

4. Answer c. The index of nominal wages for 1996 is the nominal wage in 1996 expressed as a percentage of the nominal wage in the base year.

Economics 212 Principles of Macroeconomics Study Guide. David L. Kelly

Tutor2u Economics Essay Plans Summer 2002

Interest rate Derivatives

Macroeconomics, Fall 2007 Exam 3, TTh classes, various versions

MANAGEMENT OPTIONS AND VALUE PER SHARE

Tools for Project Evaluation. Nathaniel Osgood 1.040/1.401J 2/11/2004

Project Evaluation Guidelines

VALUATION OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES. Presented By Sade Odunaiya Partner, Risk Management Alliance Consulting

A Primer on Valuing Common Stock per IRS 409A and the Impact of FAS 157

Risk, Return and Market Efficiency

The Problem with Structural Unemployment in the U.S.

Market Failure. presented by: Dr. Ellen Sewell

CHAPTER 8. Practise Problems

Effects on pensioners from leaving the EU

Human Resources: Compensation/Rewards

VALUE %. $100, (=MATURITY

Name Eco200: Practice Test 2 Covering Chapters 10 through 15

Review Question - Chapter 7. MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Workers Total Output Average Marginal

Transcription:

Cost-Benefit Analysis 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley 1

OUTLINE Chapter 8 8.1 Measuring the Costs of Public Projects 8.2 Measuring the Benefits of Public Projects 8.3 Putting It All Together 8.4 Conclusion 2

DEFINITION Cost-benefit analysis The comparison of costs and benefits of public goods projects to decide if they should be undertaken. 3

Chapter 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis 8. 1 Measuring the Costs of Public Projects The Example 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 3 of 21

MEASURING CURRENT COSTS Cash-flow accounting: Accounting method that calculates costs solely by adding up what the government pays for inputs to a project, and calculates benefits solely by adding up income or government revenues generated by the project. Opportunity cost: The social marginal cost of any resource is the value of that resource in its next best use. 5

MEASURING CURRENT COSTS General rule: Economic costs are only those costs associated with diverting the resource from its next best use Perfectly Competitive Markets Social Cost = Price (true for labor and material) Imperfectly Competitive Markets A. Monopoly: (suppose asphalt is produced by monopoly) Price = Marginal cost + Monopoly Marginal Profit > Marginal cost On efficiency grounds, Social cost = Marginal cost Profit is a transfer from govt (taxpayers) to monopoly (this matters for redistribution but not efficiency) B. Labor market with unemployment: Suppose a minimum wage set at $10 creates involuntary unemployment The unemployed would be willing to work for $6 on average but cannot find jobs Govt provides jobs paying $10/hour. Social Cost = $6 = $10 (wage) - $4 (surplus value of jobs for workers) 6

MEASURING FUTURE COSTS Present discounted value (PDV): A dollar next year is worth 1+r times less than a dollar now because the dollar could earn r in interest if invested. Government uses public debt (Treasury Bills) with interest r to borrow (example: r = 6% nominal, r-inflation=3%) Social discount rate: The appropriate value of r to use in computing PDV for social investments. Problematic predictions for the long-run: r=3% $100 in 100 years = 1/(1 + r) 100 = $5.2 today Long-run costs (such as global warming) are heavily discounted 7

LONG-RUN SOCIAL DISCOUNTING 2 reasons for discounting $1 in distant future relative to $1 today 1) Absolute discounting: people prefer $1 now than $1 in one year. But on ethical grounds, not clear why we should do absolute discounting (except for meteorite end of world risk) 2) Economic growth makes future generations richer so $1 extra means less for them than for us Even with zero absolute discounting, we want to discount future. In ideal world those two effects are embodied in interest rate r so we just need to take current r to discount Problem is that we don t know how growth (and hence r) are going to evolve over next 100 years If economy collapses due to global warming, future people will be poor and we don t want to discount. This implies we should use low discounting for distant future (Weitzman) 8

Chapter 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis 8. 1 Measuring the Costs of Public Projects Measuring Future Costs 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 8 of 21

VALUING DRIVING TIME SAVED 1.Using Market-Based Measures to Value Time: Wages If individuals optimize their labor supply decision: at the margin, hourly wage = value of one extra hour of leisure The value of saving time can be measured using wages (whether people use the saved time to work more or enjoy more leisure) This theoretical proposition runs into some problems in practice: 1) Individuals may not be able to freely trade off leisure and hours of work; jobs may come with hours restrictions 2) Wage should include not only cash wage paid to worker but also fringe benefits (total hourly compensation cost) 3) One hour sitting in traffic is worse than losing one hour of leisure value of reducing traffic higher than time saved 10

Using Survey-Based Measures to Value Time: Contingent Valuation Contingent valuation: Asking individuals to value an option they are not now choosing or do not have the opportunity to choose. Only feasible method to value situations where there is no market price: Value of saving endangered species, keeping the Arctic pristine, etc. Popular among environmentalists to argue that causes were worthy 11

The Problems of Contingent Valuation The structure of contingent valuation surveys can lead to widely varying responses (Diamond and Hausman). Examples of issues: 1) Isolation of issues matters (asking 1 thing vs many) 2) Order of issues matters 3) The embedding effect matters (preserving 1 lake, vs 3 lakes) Can only make rational allocation decision by looking at all the issues at the same time: allocate a budget among all causes. Government is best placed to make this allocation. Asking people cause by cause does not make sense for evaluating benefits for public policy decisions 12

Using Revealed Preference to Value Time Revealed preference: Letting the actions of individuals reveal their valuation (also called hedonic approach) Examples: 1) How much people are willing to pay to avoid queues: gas price controls of 1970s generated queues but small mom and pop stations exempted from price controls (could charge more and had smaller queues): can compare the difference in prices relative to queue length: Save $10 by queuing 1 hour 1 hour is worth $10 2) How much people are willing to pay for fast highway lanes (e.g., FasTrak lanes in Bay Area) In all cases, it is not just time saved, but avoiding unpleasant queuing or traffic You also estimate the value of time for the marginal person (i.e. the person indifferent between paying vs. spending time) not necessarily the same as the average person 13

VALUING SAVED LIVES Valuing human lives is the single most difficult issue in costbenefit analysis. Many would say that human life is priceless, that we should pay any amount of money to save a life. By this argument, valuing life is a reprehensible activity; there is no way to put a value on such a precious commodity. However, virtually any government expenditure has some odds of saving a life (e.g., making roads safer, health care, etc.) To escape the impotence that would be imposed by the life is priceless argument, one needs to be able to place some value on a statistical human life. Contrast between statistical life (fewer accidents) and a real life (one specific person at risk): Possible to set a value on a statistical life but not on a real life 14

A P P L I C A T I O N Valuing Life Chapter 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis The sticky ethical problem of valuing life arises in many instances in public policy, as shown by these examples. 1. In 1993, consumer groups demanded that General Motors recall about 5 million pickup trucks it had manufactured between 1973 and 1987. This recall would cost $1 billion and would, according to government calculations, save at most 32 more lives (since the trucks were slowly falling out of use). Using these estimates, the cost per life saved by the recall would have been $1 billion/32 = $31.25 million. 2. In October 1999, a commuter train crash at London s Paddington Station killed 31 people and prompted calls by an outraged public for more investment in rail safety measures. At best ($3 billion to save three lives per year for 50 years), this would mean spending $20 million per life saved; at worst ($9 billion to save one life per year for 30 years), it would mean $300 million per life saved. 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 15 of 21

Revealed Preference VALUING SAVED LIVES As with valuing time savings, the method preferred by economists for valuing life is to use revealed preferences. We can value life by estimating how much individuals are willing to pay for something that reduces their odds of dying. Compensating differentials Additional (or reduced) wage payments to workers to compensate them for the negative (or positive) amenities of a job, such as increased risk of mortality (or a nicer location). Example: bonuses needed to recruit soldiers during Afghanistan- Irak wars US studies show that revealed value of life is $7.6 million 16

Chapter 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis 8. 2 Measuring the Benefits of Public Projects Valuing Saved Lives Government Revealed Preference 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 18 of 21

Chapter 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis 8. 3 Putting It All Together 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 20 of 21

OTHER ISSUES IN COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS Common Counting Mistakes: When analyzing costs and benefits, a number of common mistakes arise, such as: -Counting secondary benefits (e.g., more commerce activity around new highway comes at the expense of other places) -Counting labor as a benefit (e.g., labor is a cost, jobs created means those workers do not produce something else) -Double-counting benefits (e.g., rise in house values due to reduced commuting cost) Distributional Concerns: The costs and benefits of a public project do not necessarily accrue to the same individuals. Uncertainty: The costs and benefits of public projects are often highly uncertain. 19

CONCLUSION Government analysts at all levels face a major challenge in attempting to turn the abstract notions of social costs and benefits into practical implications for public project choice. What at first seems to be a simple accounting exercise becomes quite complicated when resources cannot be valued in competitive markets. Nevertheless, economists have developed a set of tools that can take analysts a long way toward a complete accounting of the costs and benefits of public projects. 20