THE PETROL TAX DEBATE



Similar documents
THE REVENUE EFFECT OF CHANGING ALCOHOL DUTIES

Car CO2 taxation and it s impact on the British car fleet

EU study on company car taxation: presentation of the main results

Key Solutions CO₂ assessment

Tax benefits for ultra low emission vehicles

OVERVIEW OF PURCHASE AND TAX INCENTIVES FOR ELECTRIC VEHICLES IN THE EU

2015 BUDGET REPORT. arval.co.uk

CO2 BASED MOTOR VEHICLE TAXES IN THE EU IN 2016

Introduction. How company cars are taxed. Calculating the cash equivalent

Budget 2014 Its impact on your fleet

The Open University s repository of research publications and other research outputs

Reducing Carbon Emissions Through Transport Taxation

How To Calculate Tax Burden In European Union

CO2 BASED MOTOR VEHICLE TAXES IN THE EU IN 2015

THE TAX BURDEN OF TYPICAL WORKERS IN THE EU 27

Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax ratio fell to 39.3% of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

Impact of VAT reduction on the consumer price indices

Company Car Tax 2011/12

Co-ordinated versus uncoordinated European carbon tax solutions analysed with GEM-E3 1 linking the EU-12 countries

Special needs education in the Netherlands

relating to household s disposable income. A Gini Coefficient of zero indicates

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU 27

GET IT ALL - HIGH PERFORMANCE, SUPERIOR ECONOMY AND EXCELLENT ENVIRONMENTAL CREDENTIALS. AND ALL WITHOUT

How Effective Are Green Taxes?

The Hart report: The Economics of aeuropean Hydrogen Infrastructure for Automotive

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU Edition. James Rogers & Cécile Philippe May (Cover page) Data provided by

IS ENERGY IN ESTONIA CHEAP OR EXPENSIVE?

Income tax: company car tax rates

EUROPEAN UNION. Chapter prepared by. Marc Greven

How To Understand Factoring

S&P ESG Pan-Europe Developed Sovereign Bond Index. June 2015

Annex 2C International comparisons of gas and electricity prices

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD By Kyle Pomerleau

NEW PASSENGER CAR REGISTRATIONS BY ALTERNATIVE FUEL TYPE IN THE EUROPEAN UNION 1 Quarter

Executive summary. Global Wage Report 2014 / 15 Wages and income inequality

Costs Imposed by Foreign- Registered Trucks on Britain's Roads

CO 2 -based Motor Vehicle Tax

carbon footprinting a guide for fleet managers

Alcohol Consumption in Ireland A Report for the Health Service Executive

Health Care in Crisis

The sceptical optimist: Mike Schussler Economists.co.za. 1

THE PERFORMANCE - OF THE UK INLAND MAILS BUSINESS OF CONSIGNIA

How To Tax A Car In The Uk

From Carbon Subsidy to Carbon Tax: India s Green Actions 1

Energy Taxation in Europe, Japan and The United States

WHAT EUROPEANS THINK ABOUT CONNECTED CARS

Renault continues to lead volume brands as new car CO 2 emissions fall across Europe

Early Childhood Education and Care

// BRIEF STATISTICS 2014

Ageing OECD Societies

UK INVESTMENT: HIGH, LOW, RISING, FALLING?

The Chancellor made rather too much of the 27 billion the OBR found. down the back of the sofa in November. As I ve said on a number of

Attendance Allowance. Benefit and support you may get if you are ill or disabled and aged 65 or over

Taxation and the Company Car

The impact on the UK economy of a reduction in fuel duty

Monitoring CO 2. emissions from new passenger cars in the EU: summary of data for 2012

Energy and Environment issues in road transport. Prof. Stef Proost KULeuven (B)

Climate policy and energy pricing in the UK

Carbon Emissions Trading and Carbon Taxes

Quantity of trips supplied (millions)

5. Income tax and National Insurance contributions

Including details of the 2014 emissions-based changes, Vehicle Excise Duty and fuel allowances.

PRE-BUDGET REPORT: REVIEW OF CHARITY TAXATION

What if BAU would come true?

UK Energy Statistics, Q3 2015

Academic Reading sample task Identifying information

5 Taxes on consumption

WORKSHOP ON GLOBAL FUEL ECONOMY INITIATIVE TOPIC: MOTOR VEHICLES RELATED TAXES

Skatteudvalget SAU Alm.del Bilag 11 Offentligt. Vehicle taxes in the. 23 September 2013

Inventarisatie toepassing EU btw-regelgeving op hoveniersdiensten

Information Sheet: VAT on private pleasure craft

The energy industry and energy price issues in Slovakia during recent years 1

Overview of vehicle taxation schemes (including incentives for electric vehicles), Content: 1. National vehicle taxation schemes Overview...

Wind energy scenarios for A report by the European Wind Energy Association - July Wind energy scenarios for 2020

Mechanical Breakdown Insurance Policy Summary

THE TAXATION OF COMPANY CARS. Calculating the cash equivalent

Company Car Tax 2014/2015

Excise Taxation Customer Bulletin 6. Occasional Importation of Products Subject to Excise Duty. Temporary registered consignee

Transport Price Indices

INTERNATIONAL TRACKED POSTAGE SERVICE

The wine market: evolution and trends

College costs are rising for a number of reasons: Calculating the decline in State-level support for college education:

Energy prices and bills report Results and key messages for commerce and industry. 10 th December 2014

Key Solutions CO2 Assessment

The Tax Burden of Typical Workers in the EU Edition

Carer s Allowance. May 2009

NEWSLETTER MARCH 2007 MAIN TAX RATES, ALLOWANCES AND RELIEFS 2007/08

Future funding outlook for councils 2019/20

MAKING DECISIONS ABOUT MONEY INCLUSION IRELAND. Promoting the rights of people with an intellectual disability

UK Energy Statistics

Business Vehicle Finance from Ford. A guide to Business Vehicle Finance and company vehicle taxation

On a mission to reduce traffic congestion for all

Vehicle Registration Tax

SUBMISSION FROM AA IRELAND ON THE COMBINED SUBJECTS OF: Motor Tax Rebalancing to take account of CO2 Emissions

Taxation of tobacco products in the European Union. Frank Van Driessche DG Taxation and Customs Union May 2006

Chapter 3 Review Math 1030

Public Spending Under Labour

EBA REPORT ON THE BENCHMARKING OF DIVERSITY PRACTICES. EBA-Op July 2016

Bio-natural-gas for cleaner urban transport

Transcription:

THE PETROL TAX DEBATE Zoë Smith THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Briefing Note No. 8

Published by The Institute for Fiscal Studies 7 Ridgmount Street London WC1E 7AE Tel 2 7291 48 Fax 2 7323 478 mailbox@ifs.org.uk www.ifs.org.uk Institute for Fiscal Studies, July 2 ISBN 1-93274-9-5 Published online at http://www.ifs.org.uk

The petrol tax debate Zoë Smith Recent increases in the price of petrol have led to the current debate about the rate at which petrol is taxed in the UK. Although rising oil prices have contributed to the increased cost, the government has been criticised for imposing a high tax rate on petrol and other road fuels. In the UK, two indirect taxes are imposed on road fuels. In addition to VAT, excise duty is also levied at the rates shown in Table 1. Table 1. Duties on road fuels, March 2 Fuel type Duty, pence per litre Unleaded petrol 48.82 Higher octane unleaded petrol (including lead replacement petrol) 5.89 Ultra low sulphur diesel 48.82 In July 2, the total tax (duty plus VAT) on lead replacement petrol (LRP) was 72 per cent of the retail price and total tax on unleaded petrol was 73 per cent of the retail price. There has been particular concern that high taxes on road fuel impose a high burden on those who can least afford it low-income groups, rural areas and the disabled, for example. This Briefing Note documents trends in the price of road fuel and shows how the tax rate has contributed to the change in price over time. It also examines the effect of the price increases on certain subgroups of the population. Background Figure 1 shows the retail prices of leaded/lead replacement petrol 1 and of unleaded petrol over the last 1 years up to July 2. The line labelled RPI shows how the price of petrol would have increased if it had increased exactly in line with inflation. The prices of both types of fuel increased broadly in line with inflation until 1993. After this date, both prices increased faster than the rate of inflation and there has been a particularly rapid increase over recent months. Since Labour came to office in May 1997, there has been a 37 per cent increase in the price of leaded petrol/lrp and 2 percentage points have been due to tax. 2 In the case of unleaded petrol, the increase has been 42 per cent and 26 percentage points have been due to tax. For the period from May 1997 until June 2, the increase in the price of leaded petrol/lrp was 25 percentage points greater than the rate of inflation and the increase in the price of unleaded petrol was 27 percentage points greater than the rate of inflation. In the period from March 2 (after the budget) to September 2, there has been a 8.6 per cent increase in the price of unleaded petrol. Of this 8.6 per cent increase, just over 1 percentage point has been due to tax with the remainder being due to the increase in the pre-tax price. 1 From 1 January 2, a virtual ban on leaded petrol was introduced except for specialist interest groups such as classic car clubs. Leaded petrol was replaced with lead replacement petrol. The figures in this Briefing Note compare the price of leaded petrol before this date with the price of LRP after this date. Although they are not the same product, anyone with a car that used leaded petrol would have been forced to buy lead replacement petrol so the comparison between the prices of the two different products seems the natural one to make. 2 This is comparing the price of leaded petrol in May 1997 with the price of LRP in July 2. 1

Figure 1. The price of leaded petrol/lrp and unleaded petrol 1 9 8 Price, pence per litre 7 6 5 4 3 2 Leaded petrol/lrp Unleaded petrol RPI 1 Jul-9 Jan-91 Jul-91 Jan-92 Jul-92 Jan-93 Jul-93 Jan-94 Jul-94 Jan-95 Jul-95 Jan-96 Jul-96 Jan-97 Jul-97 Jan-98 Jul-98 Jan-99 Jul-99 Jan- Jul- Figure 2. Real duty on leaded petrol/lrp and unleaded petrol, March 2 prices 6 5 Duty, pence per litre 4 3 2 1 Leaded petrol/lrp Unleaded petrol Mar-86 Mar-88 Mar-9 Mar-92 Mar-94 Mar-96 Mar-98 Mar- The government has blamed increased oil prices around the world, but despite this, there has been pressure on the Chancellor to cut the duty on road fuel. From 1993 to 1999, road fuel duty was been increased automatically by a fixed percentage above inflation. This escalator was set at 3 per cent in March 1993 and was increased the following November to 5 per cent and then to 6 per cent in 1997. In the November 1999 Pre-Budget Report, 3 the escalator was abolished, with any future increases being decided on a Budget-by-Budget basis. Figure 2 3 HM Treasury, Stability and Steady Growth for Britain: Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 4479, November 1999. 2

shows the effect that these increases have had on the real rate of duty on both leaded petrol/lrp and unleaded petrol. 4 Over the period from 1987, duty on unleaded petrol has increased by over 6 percentage points more than the rate of inflation. Since the beginning of the 199s, there has been a steady real increase in both duty rates every year except in March 2 when there was a fall in duty on leaded petrol/lrp. The fall in duty on leaded petrol/lrp occurred because LRP is taxed at a lower rate than leaded petrol. Figure 3. Components of the retail price of unleaded petrol 9 8 7 Pre-tax price VAT Duty Pence per litre 6 5 4 3 2 1 Jul-9 Jan-91 Jul-91 Jan-92 Jul-92 Jan-93 Jul-93 Jan-94 Jul-94 Jan-95 Jul-95 Jan-96 Jul-96 Jan-97 Jul-97 Jan-98 Jul-98 Jan-99 Jul-99 Jan- Jul- Table 2. European road fuel duty, June 1999 Duty plus VAT, pence per litre Leaded petrol Unleaded petrol UK 62.13 55.47 France 49.94 46.24 Netherlands - 44.84 Finland - 44.41 Italy 45.13 42.29 Denmark - 41.25 Sweden - 4.82 Germany - 4.12 Belgium 44.5 39.92 Portugal 4.2 37.96 Austria - 32.35 Ireland 36.11 29.8 Spain 3.54 28.4 Luxemburg 31.73 27.11 Greece 28.18 24.39 Notes: Leaded petrol was not available in Austria, Denmark, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands or Sweden in June 1999. Source: HM Customs and Excise Annual Report (1998/9). 4 Differential duty was introduced on unleaded petrol in 1987. 3

Figure 3 shows the three components of the retail price of unleaded petrol duty, VAT and the pre-tax price over the last 1 years. In April 1999, there was a sharp increase in the pretax price (the top band on the graph). Although the pre-tax price has risen in recent months, over the past few years increases in the tax rate have contributed to the rise in the retail price of petrol. The UK currently has a tax rate that is higher than that in any other European country on both leaded and unleaded petrol. Table 2 shows the European tax rates (duty plus VAT) on both products as at June 1999. The tax on unleaded petrol is 2 per cent higher in the UK than in France, which has the next highest rate in Europe. The purpose of a fuel tax There are two purposes of a road fuel tax in the UK. The first is an attempt to change behaviour and reduce the amount that people use their cars in order to protect the environment, and the other is to raise revenue. When an individual makes decisions regarding vehicle ownership and usage, they will typically take into account those costs that are purely private, such as the price of the car, insurance and petrol prices, but they might not to take into account any of the additional costs which are not directly charged for. There are a number of ways in which road transport imposes additional or social costs on others. Social costs could include air and noise pollution, congestion and road damage. Attempting to reduce the consumption of road fuel and the amount of car usage is one way to try to restrict the amount of damage done to the environment. Imposing an additional tax on road fuel in the form of a fixed amount per unit of fuel consumed (a specific tax) attempts to raise the price the consumer pays to the level that more accurately reflects these additional social costs. The question remains, to what extent will households alter their behaviour (drive their cars less, switch to more efficient cars) in the face of higher prices?. The relationship we are interested in is that between miles driven and the cost of those miles, since it is by altering the cost per mile that taxes on road fuels will influence behaviour. Evidence suggests in fact that a one per cent increase in the real cost per mile of driving will reduce miles travelled by less than half of one per cent (in the short term). This is not a very large response, which suggests that any attempt to reduce reliance on the car by increasing the cost of fuel will not have been very successful. This is not to say that the high rate of duty has not had any effect on the behaviour of motorists. For example, people may have switched to buying more fuel-efficient cars, which helps to reduce the harmful effect on the environment. The fact that there is some response to increases in price, even though it is small, does imply that there will have been some reduction in miles driven, especially with such a high tax on petrol, but it is impossible to tell whether the price of petrol now adequately reflects the social costs of road transport. Even if people did respond to price increases by reducing car use, the fact that some aspects of pollution from road transport (such as congestion or soot) are only loosely linked to the level of fuel used means that the policy is not very well targeted to protect the environment. One source of pollution carbon dioxide emission is closely related to fuel consumption, and the global warming effects of carbon dioxide depend linearly on emissions, so for this particular pollutant a fuel tax may be appropriate, but this is not generally true. Levels of congestion, for example, vary by time of day and location. Similarly, the harmful effects of some pollutants such as black smoke (which appear to contribute significantly to respiratory disorders) depend on when and where they are emitted for example, the harmful effect can be greater in highly populated areas. So attempting to reduce the social costs associated with road transport by imposing an additional tax on road fuel consumption is difficult because of the lack of response to changes 4

in the price of petrol and because fuel cost is not always very closely related to the social cost involved. In fact, it is the lack of response by motorists to increases in the price of fuel that makes a fuel tax a very attractive source of revenue for the government. If people do not cut back the amount of fuel they buy after a tax increase, large amounts of money can be easily raised. In 1999/2, fuel duties (excluding VAT) raised 22.3 billion, which represented 6 per cent of total government revenue. 5 Six pence on all road fuel duties raises as much money as one penny on the basic rate of income tax. 6 A recent development in fuel taxation was the announcement in the November 1999 Pre- Budget Report that any further increases in fuel duty, above the rate of inflation, would be spent on improving public transport and modernising the road network. 7 Setting aside taxes to spend in specified areas in this way is referred to as hypothecation. Apart from the possibility that people are less averse to tax increases if they know where the money is being spent, it is difficult to see any real advantage of this policy. There is no way to guarantee that money allocated to spending on roads and transport is over and above the amount that would have been spent otherwise particularly in the long term. This is because when the announcement was made, the government s spending plans were set out only until March 22. In any spending plans set out after this date, any revenue allocated to transport could take into account that resources from increases in road fuels are to be spent in this area. For example, there is no way of knowing whether the transport spending plans announced in July 2 took account of any possible future increases in fuel duties. The distributional effects of road fuel tax A frequent objection to high taxes on fuel is the effect that the tax has on certain groups of the population those on low incomes and those living in rural areas, amongst others. This section examines the effect of the road fuel tax on sub-groups of the population, according to income and the density of population. 8 The effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duties is analysed by comparing the cost of achieving a given level of economic welfare before the tax increase with the cost of achieving the same level of economic welfare after the tax increase. Everything else in the comparison is kept constant in order to isolate the effect of the tax increase. The cost-of-living index measures how much extra income is needed to get back to the original welfare level. 9 In Figure 4, households are ranked according to income and divided into 1 equal groups, so the first group (decile) contains the poorest 1 per cent of households. The effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duties on the cost of living of each household is then averaged across each income decile. The effect of the tax increase on the cost of living of the poorest households is smaller than the effect on richer households, with the greatest effect being on middle-income households. Although the increase in the cost of living even in the sixth decile 5 HM Treasury, Prudent for a Purpose: Working for a Stronger and Fairer Britain, HC 346, March 2. 6 Treasury Ready Reckoner, November 1999. 7 HM Treasury, Stability and Steady Growth for Britain: Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 4479, November 1999. 8 Data from the National Travel Survey from 1988 to 1993 are used and income, price and mileage data are uprated to 1997 (see L. Blow and I. Crawford, The Distributional Effects of Taxes on Private Motoring, Commentary no. 65, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 1997, for more details). 9 For a more detailed explanation, see Blow and Crawford (1997) as in footnote 8. 5

is only around.2 per cent, repeated increases in fuel duty would have a much larger effect. However, the distribution of the effects is largely caused by many households in the lowest income groups not owning a car. If we take only households that own cars, as in Figure 5, the cost of living of the lowest (car-owning) income groups is most adversely affected by the tax increase, with the effect becoming smaller as we move up the income distribution. Figure 4. Effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duty on cost of living, by income decile: all households.4.35 Increase in cost of living, %.3.25.2.15.1.5 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income decile Figure 5. Effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duty on cost of living, by income decile: car-owning households.4.35 Increase in cost of living, %.3.25.2.15.1.5 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income decile 6

Figure 6. Effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duty on cost of living, by population density: all households.4.35 Increase in cost of living, %.3.25.2.15.1.5 Rural Urban Population density Figure 7. Effect of a 6 per cent real increase in duty on cost of living, by population density: car-owning households.4.35 Increase in cost of living, %.3.25.2.15.1.5 Rural Urban Population density Another possible area for concern is the effect on rural areas compared with more urban areas. Figure 6 shows the effect of a 6 per cent fuel duty increase on cost of living, averaged over all households according to the population density where each household lives. 1 Figure 7 does 1 The four bands of population density are for local authorities with the number of people per hectare being <3.5 (most rural), 3.5 9.9, 1 19.9 and 2 34.9 (most urban). 7

the same for all car-owning households. For both groups, the cost of living increases slightly more in rural areas than it does in more urban areas. Conclusions There have been steep increases in the price of fuel in recent months and, although increases in the pre-tax price have played a part, high taxes have contributed to the rise. However, with the fuel duty escalator now ended, we are unlikely to see future real increases that are as high as this, since in his Pre-Budget Speech in November 1999, the Chancellor stated that future real increases would be lower than 6 per cent: [we] are now in a position instead of the pre-announced 6 per cent escalator to make our decisions Budget by Budget with the following commitment: if there are any real term rises in road fuel duties, they will be lower and the revenues will go straight to a ring-fenced fund for the modernisation of roads and public transport. The aims of the road fuel tax are conflicting. The property of demand for fuel that makes it difficult to reduce consumption through price rises makes it a good source of revenue for the Chancellor. If the government did succeed in getting people out of their cars and onto public transport, they would lose fuel as a valuable source of revenue. Analysis of the effect of fuel duty rises on the cost of living of households across different income groups and across households living in areas of different population density suggests that an increase in fuel duty does impose a higher burden on poor car-owning households and on rural dwellers. But this does not mean that a fuel tax should not be used to try to protect the environment if it is decided that this is the most appropriate way to do so. It is the overall progressivity of the whole tax and benefit system that we are concerned about. The adverse effect on the cost of living of subsections of the population that we are concerned about could be compensated for, for example, by improving rural public transport. 8