The Age of Retirement

Similar documents
PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2011: RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES AUSTRALIA

How To Understand The Economic And Social Costs Of Living In Australia

2 Voluntary retirement module specification

Retirement Saving in Australia

Dragan Savic. 12 August 2013

Australia s Future Tax System Preliminary Submission from the Institute of Actuaries of Australia

An update on the level and distribution of retirement savings

Retirement incomes. Aisur. Submission to the Tax White Paper Task Force. July 2015

The Future of Australia - An Accounting Analysis

Principles and key features of required reform

Australia: Retirement Income and Annuities Markets. Contractual Savings Conference April 2008 Greg Brunner

Australian superannuation: an equitable and sustainable arrangement in a post crisis world?

Contributing the Family Home to Super

An explanation of social assistance, pension schemes, insurance schemes and similar concepts

Old Age Income Protection in Australia

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

NEW ZEALAND S RETIREMENT INCOMES CHALLENGE MARCH 2012

Actuaries Institute Submission

Is widowhood out of date in the 21st Century?

ATTACHMENT 10 STATEMENT OF REFORM PRIORITIES, CHALLENGER SUBMISSION TO TAX FORUM, OCTOBER 2011

The Institute of Public Accountants. Review of retirement income stream regulation

TAX & SUPERANNUATION:

1. INTRODUCTION 2. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 3. SUBMISSIONS. Loretta DeSourdy Head of Regulatory Affairs Westpac New Zealand Limited PO Box 691 Wellington

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2009: RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES UNITED STATES

ASFA Research and Resource Centre

STATEMENT FROM THE NATIONAL REFORM SUMMIT

Regulation impact statement Unincorporated small business tax discount

Live Long and Prosper? Demographic Change and Europe s Pensions Crisis

Smart strategies for maximising retirement income

FISCAL INCENTIVES AND RETIREMENT SAVINGS Project Outline

OECD PROJECT ON FINANCIAL INCENTIVES AND RETIREMENT SAVINGS Project Outline

Superannuation and high account balances

RBA ECONOMICS COMPETITION

Australia. Qualifying conditions. Benefit calculation. Defined contribution. Key indicators: Australia. Australia: Pension system in 2014

Building super on a fair foundation: Reform of the taxation of superannuation contributions

English Summary. Chapter I: Economic outlook. Denmark USA Euro area

FEDERAL BUDGET 2009 SUMMARY

The 2004 Report of the Social Security Trustees: Social Security Shortfalls, Social Security Reform and Higher Education

Risk management for long-term guaranteed annuity products. Investment risk. Keywords: longevity risk, ageing, retirement, annuity, regulation.

Contact us. Hoa Bui T: + 61 (02) E: hbui@kpmg.com.au. Briallen Cummings T: + 61 (02) E: bcummings01@kpmg.com.au.

Structuring & Tax. Ensuring your plans for your super become a reality. By Ben Andreou Partner Head of Structuring & Tax

Labour Market Responses to the Abolition of Compulsory Superannuation. by Louise Carter 1

Retirement Income White Paper Insights Presentation

4. Work and retirement

Chapter 4: Ageing pressures and spending

For many Australians, their main form of savings over their lifetime is their home. Directing savings towards a home provides two benefits:-

Tax White Paper Supplementary Submission on Retirement Incomes. Minimum Drawdown Rules. Category A. 24 July 2015

Submission to the Tax White Paper Taskforce review of Australia s retirement income system

Men retiring early: How How are they doing? Dave Gower

New Zealand Superannuation and KiwiSaver

Understanding Superannuation

Changes to regulatory settings for financial products dealing with longevity

Briefing Paper on Equity Release

Submission to the Taxation Review Panel. Adequate, fair, sustainable, and simple: Retirement incomes reform. ACOSS, February 2009

- on termination due to redundancy

Introduction 1 Key Findings 1 The Survey Retirement landscape 2

A super waste of money

Review into the Governance, Efficiency, Structure and Operation of Australia's Superannuation System

Representing Retirees of the United Nations in Australia. Representing Retirees of the United Nations in Australia

BANK OF PAPUA NEW GUINEA SUBMISSION TO THE TAX REVIEW COMMITTEE ON TAXATION IN SUPERANNUATION AND LIFE INSURANCE

Equity and retirement income provision in Australia

Scottish Independence. Charting the implications of demographic change. Ben Franklin. I May 2014 I.

Retirement Policies, Annuities and Longevity Insurance in

The Economists Voice

Understanding retirement income Version 5.0

LIFE EXPECTANCY AND SOCIAL SECURITY: WHY LONGEVITY INDEXING THE PAYROLL TAX RATE MAKES GOOD ECONOMIC SENSE. Abstract

UNITED NATIONS INDEPENDENT EXPERT ON THE QUESTION OF HUMAN RIGHTS AND EXTREME POVERTY

Tax discussion paper submission. May 2015 The Association of Superannuation Funds of Australia (ASFA)

Key Findings ASIC Report 419. Australian Financial Attitudes and Behaviour Tracker Wave 1: March August 2014

What are my Pension Options?

Measuring retirement savings adequacy in Australia

Topics. AMA Private Health Insurance Comparison 2016 Budget Breakdown Top Ten Tax Tips for AMA Private Health Insurance Comparison

Australia Introduction. Who are Older Australians? WINNER 2014 ALUCA TURKSLEGAL SCHOLARSHIP. Question 10

An Evaluation of the Possible

Retirement Incomes for an Ageing Australia. Hazel Bateman

25*$1,6$7,21)25(&2120,&&223(5$7,21$1''(9(/230(17

Can Equity Release Mechanisms fund long term care costs? Desmond Le Grys

Chapter 3 Multi-pillar System and Underlying Principles

Towards sustainable Dutch occupational pensions

ANZ SUBMISSION TO THE AUSTRALIAN GOVERNMENT ON AUSTRALIA S DEMOGRAPHIC CHALLENGES AND A MORE FLEXIBLE AND ADAPTABLE RETIREMENT INCOME SYSTEM

The Definition of a Social Insurance Scheme and its Classification as Defined Benefit or Defined Contribution. John Pitzer.

The self-employed and pensions

FAMILY FORTUNES A GUIDE TO SAVING FOR RETIREMENT. A Discussion Meeting. Discussion Topics

Smart strategies for maximising retirement income 2012/13

OECD THEMATIC FOLLOW-UP REVIEW OF POLICIES TO IMPROVE LABOUR MARKET PROSPECTS FOR OLDER WORKERS. DENMARK (situation mid-2012)

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. SUBMISSION 12 March 2014 Final 2

Retirement for All Australians

HELP Interest Rate Options: Equity and Costs

The reform of the Hungarian pension system (A reformed reform)

dream long-term Economic Projection for 2011 Pdf version

2016/17 Budget. 1. Effective Budget Night 7.30pm (AEST) 3 May New lifetime cap for non-concessional superannuation contributions

International Retirement Security Survey

Age, Demographics and Employment

Australia. Old Age, Disability, and Survivors. Australia. Exchange rate: US$1.00 equals 1.32 Australian dollars (A$). Qualifying Conditions

SIEPR policy brief. Efficient Retirement Design. By John B. Shoven. About The Author. Stanford University March 2013

PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2011: RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES SWEDEN

Investment Company Institute and the Securities Industry Association. Equity Ownership

The Reverse Mortgage-a Response to Ageing Polish Society

Transcription:

An independent report prepared for AIST Union by the Australian Centre for Financial Studies. The principal author of this report is Professor Kevin Davis, Research Director at the Australian Centre for Financial Studies

Table of Contents Executive Summary... 3 1. Introduction... 6 2. The Australian Situation... 8 2.1 The History of Social Perspectives on Retirement Incomes Policy in Australia... 8 2.2 The Economic and Social Setting... 10 2.3 Retirement Regulations... 17 2. International Context... 18 3. The Retirement Decision... 20 4. The Post-Retirement Experience... 25 5. Conclusions and Policy Issues... 27 APPENDIX 1: CURRENT AGE PENSION RATES AND CONDITIONS... 30 REFERENCE LIST... 31 January 27, 2014 2

Executive Summary Unlike some systems which have a public pension based on contributions over the working life of an individual, the Australian Age pension is generally viewed as a (means tested) entitlement, regardless of years of labour force participation. The existence of this universal, means-tested, age pension inherently reflects fairness considerations, by ensuring that some minimal level of income support is available to all individuals beyond some age at which they may no longer be able to generate income through employment. That does, however, influence perceptions of what is fairness. Unlike some other countries where early retirement is permissible after reaching a certain number of years of employment and contributions to the national scheme (albeit with a lower annual pension), the Australian debate on fairness is focused on age per se as the critical issue. Shifting the debate to incorporate such considerations is merited, and becomes particularly important when the relationship between the Preservation Age (for access to superannuation savings) and the Official Retirement Age (for eligibility for the age pension) is being considered. The current gap between the preservation age of 60 years and the official retirement age of 65 years enables workers to fund early retirement from super balances, shifting their lifetime leisure consumption profile (with more leisure prior to the official retirement age, and lower lifetime consumption). To the extent that this is a purely voluntary choice, with no consequences for government budgets, it is difficult to see why that should be a concern for society. Ongoing, trend increases in national productivity and real incomes (with real average weekly earnings increasing by around 30 per cent since the start of the millennium) should provide the opportunity for older workers, with consumption habits formed at earlier ages when real incomes were lower, to elect to take some of the gains as increased leisure. With around a third of retirees projected to receive the full age pension even when the superannuation system reaches maturity after 2040, there are many lower income workers whose voluntary early retirement would have little consequences for the government budget. For many of these, financial wealth achieved if they worked till the official retirement age would still be below the assets test requirements for receipt of the full pension. Their early retirement has limited consequences for the government budget other than loss of tax revenue from their early exit from the workforce. But, there are two sets of circumstances where this benign scenario does not apply. One is in the case of involuntary retirement where health or job loss considerations lead to early retirement. ABS survey figures on reasons for retirement, and data from the HILDA survey suggest that such involuntary retirement may comprise a significant fraction of retirees. (One study puts the proportion at over 25 per cent). For such involuntary retirees, the post-retirement experience is less satisfying both in financial terms and in general wellbeing. Thus there is the need for the retirement age debate to be cognisant of the fact that a possibly substantial proportion of retirees have not entered that state voluntarily. Measures to facilitate continued workforce participation of older laid-off workers, whose skill sets may not match available job opportunities, as well as to ensure support for those with health issues (such as may be provided for some by the National Disability Insurance Scheme) are thus important issues. The other caveat is where early retirees run down super balances and thus (by virtue of having lower assets at the official retirement balance) increase their subsequent pension income at a cost to the government budget. Government retirement incomes policy should, arguably, be designed not to provide incentives to take such actions although again questions of what is meant by equity become important. Unfortunately, the means test acts essentially as a disincentive for January 27, 2014 3

continued work and accumulation of retirement savings balances, and is found by some researchers to have significant disincentive effects on continued workforce participation. And while the transition to retirement scheme was established with the sensible objective of enabling earlier access to pension savings to support a shift to part time work and ultimate retirement, the question needs to be asked whether it is achieving that objective or whether it has been driven by tax arbitrage strategies of more wealthy individuals. (Changes to maximum superannuation contribution limits in 2012 should, at least, reduce the opportunities for such tax arbitrage). But there is scope for policies to do more to provide incentives for deferral of retirement for those who wish or are able to do so. There are two types of financial disincentive to postponing retirement age. One is the effect of the means test whereby accumulation of further assets from savings out of wage income above reduces subsequent pension entitlements. The other is the deferral of receipt of pension income, which given a constant expected lifetime (and there is no evidence that age of retirement affects mortality), reduces the amount of lifetime pension wealth which the individual can expect to receive. While there is some small financial incentive for continuation of work beyond the official retirement age (the work bonus test), it falls far short of being actuarially fair such that deferring retirement has no effect on the expected level of lifetime pension income to be received. Another important consideration is the observation of a significant increase in the proportion of households approaching retirement age who still have outstanding mortgage debt. There is anecdotal evidence of this reflecting decisions to fund higher consumption levels pre-retirement (including providing financial support to other family members for house purchase) with the intention to use superannuation balances to pay down the mortgage. Some part of that higher consumption may also be trading up to higher value dwellings to enjoy the amenity benefits in retirement, influenced by the exclusion of the family home from the assets test for the pension. This potential cause of distortion to asset allocation, and also disincentive to downsizing in retirement warrants attention. While (significantly) increasing the allowable amount for the assets test and simultaneously including the value of the family home would be one way of rectifying such distortions, it would require significant political will. This report also raises the question of what is meant by retirement. As well as meaning different things to different people, it is also important to recognise that a significant number of retirees subsequently become unretired, re-entering the workforce for financial or other reasons. In Australia, that figure is around 10 per cent of retirees (based on ABS survey data) which is considerably less than in the USA, where the retirement safety net is much less robust. The report also examines international evidence on determinants of actual retirement decisions. The actual retirement age (which on average is generally below the official retirement age) had been declining internationally until prior to the Global Financial Crisis, but is now increasing) is influenced by changes in the official retirement age. That reflects both financial considerations but also anchoring of perceptions about what is the normal retirement age. But in Australia, there is some evidence that the preservation age may be more relevant for influencing expectations regarding age of retirement. In examining the motivations for retirement, it would appear that the financial incentive is especially strong for males, who indicate that access to pensions and superannuation are the strongest reason to retire from age 55. It is less so for females until after January 27, 2014 4

age 65, with reasons such as health and family being stronger at earlier ages. The appropriate relationship between, and levels of the official retirement age and the preservation age, warrant much more study, and more consideration also needs to be given to equity and lifestyle choice considerations than is implied by the current focus on primarily national output and budgetary considerations. January 27, 2014 5

1. Introduction One of the major challenges for governments in developed economies is the need to ensure the sustainability of retirement systems. Demographic forces such as lower birth rates and increased longevity have resulted in increasing demands on governments to provide for the needs of an ageing population. To reduce the rapidly increasing burden on the public purse, and thus improve the sustainability of retirement systems, governments around the world are implementing options such as mandating retirement savings contributions, encouraging voluntary contributions and other forms of private retirement savings, promoting workforce participation for older workers, and increasing the retirement age at which individuals become eligible for a public pension. Similar developments have occurred in Australia. Since 1992, the vast majority of the working population has participated in a mandated retirement savings plan through the superannuation guarantee contribution (SGC) and received tax incentives to encourage further voluntary contributions to the scheme. To enhance the sustainability of the Australian system, policy changes have been implemented which will eventually lead to an increase in the pension eligibility age - hereafter referred to as the official retirement age (ORA) - to 67 for both men and women born after January 1 st 1957. Further, mandatory contribution rates for superannuation are scheduled to increase from the current 9 per cent of employee s wages to 12 per cent by July 2019. There is also ongoing discussion regarding increasing the age (and/or rate of withdrawal) at which individuals can access accumulated superannuation savings. That age of access is referred to as the preservation age (PA). These developments raise a number of questions which this report seeks to address: What is the meaning and consequences of retirement for individuals? (Box 1 addresses the issue of the meaning of retirement) What role do the ORA and PA play in influencing individual retirement decisions relative to other considerations such as health, employment options, wealth etc.? What are the equity/distributional consequences of changes to the ORA and PA? Answers to these questions can help to address important policy questions such as: Is the current emphasis on retirement as a well-defined event involving exit from the work force appropriate? If the age pension is viewed as an age related entitlement conditional on wealth or income characteristics, what is the appropriate set of conditions which might induce optimal continuation in the workforce while in receipt of some age pension, or induce individuals to retire at an optimal age? Should the ORA differ in response to individual characteristics such as: length of workforce participation; gender; or occupational characteristics which are correlated with effective working life and expected life span? What should be the relationship between the ORA and PA and drawdown arrangements or constraints on use of superannuation savings? January 27, 2014 6

What are the potential consequences for other components of the Government budget (such as health and disability expenditures) from changing the ORA and PA? BOX 1: What is Retirement? One of the complexities in analysing retirement issues lies in determining a suitable definition of retirement. While the official retirement age (ORA) is relatively easy to determine as the age at which an age pension or other government benefits become available, identifying the actual age of retirement is less straightforward. Some individuals below the official retirement age who are no longer in the workforce may be treated as retired, but may be part of the hidden unemployed (or may be in de facto retirement due to eligibility for other government unemployment or health benefits). Others may regard themselves as retired by virtue of having left their long term career occupation, and taken up full or part time employment of some different type (and possibly drawing down accumulated superannuation or other savings). Conversely, individuals above the ORA may be employed full or part time, possibly drawing down superannuation or other savings (with some part time employees in receipt of some level of age pension benefits). An important consideration is whether retirement is voluntary or involuntary effectively forced upon individuals earlier than expected due to health problems or loss of employment. The post-retirement experience of the involuntary retired can be expected to differ significantly from those how retire voluntarily. In practice, for many individuals, retirement is not a unique event. US data suggests that only around half of retirees cease work permanently with around a quarter of retirees subsequently becoming unretired by returning to the workforce for some further period (Maestas, 2010). In Australia, survey data collected by the ABS in 2007 indicated that there were 310,000 former retirees in the workforce relative to 3.1 million retired individuals. The main reasons given for returning to work were: financial need (36% for males and 42% for females) and bored (31% for males and 14% for females). The apparent difference between the USA and Australian unretiring experience is no doubt influence by differences in the nature of the retirement income support safety net between the two countries. Such policy related questions are best considered in the context of available evidence about relationships between labour force participation experience, occupational choice, retirement age, income and wealth, gender, post retirement activities, health, and longevity. Consequently the available evidence is considered later in this report. Prior to that, however, to provide context, section 1 provides an brief overview of the historical development of Australian retirement incomes policy and of the current Australian economic and social setting within which these questions need to be addressed, while section 2 provides some international comparisons of policy arrangements and trends regarding retirement age. Section 3 examines evidence on individual decision-making regarding retirement and the roles of labour force experience, effective working life, longevity and health. Section 4 considers how retirement age influences post-retirement experience, including mortality. Section 5 summarizes and considers policy implications. January 27, 2014 7

2. The Australian Situation 2.1 The History of Social Perspectives on Retirement Incomes Policy in Australia1 The Age pension was introduced in Australia around the start of the 20 th century reflecting increased community acceptance of the notion that support for the aged was not solely the responsibility of the individual, but a collective responsibility for the whole community (Dixon, 1977). A means test (income and/or assets) has been applied since inception reflecting both a needs perspective and a budgetary cost perspective, and the family house was excluded from the test in the early years of Federation. While initially the eligibility age was common for males and females, it was reduced in 1910 to 60 for women on the grounds that women generally became incapacitated for regular work at an earlier age than men (Kewley, 1973, p 75) (Treasury, 2001). In 1997, the commitment to keep the single pension at 25 per cent of average weekly earnings was enshrined in legislation, and the rate for married individuals set at a slightly lower level. While there were several attempts to introduce a universal national part-contributory pension scheme (most recently recommended by the Hancock Report in 1976) this approach was never supported by government. Ultimately the current superannuation scheme, involving (mandatory and voluntary) private, tax favoured, retirement savings was introduced and operates alongside of the government-provided, budget funded, age pension arrangements. The Australian retirement income arrangements mean that there is no actual, or widely perceived, link between an individual s taxation contributions during their working life and pension entitlements, unlike in some other nations. Pension payments are funded out of current government budget revenues ( pay as you go ). 2 The age pension is generally viewed as a (means tested) entitlement, regardless of years of labour force participation. While eligibility age has traditionally been defined by years since birth, recent increases reflecting increased longevity could be interpreted as an implicit shift towards definition by years of remaining life expectancy as discussed by Foreman and Chen (2008). While that could be implemented at an aggregate level, it raises the issue of whether individual differences should be taken into account. Foreman and Chen also note that the official retirement age could alternatively be defined using other concepts. These include: mortality risk (age at which risk of death within one year exceeds some critical level such as 2 per cent); or a constant working life to expected retirement years ratio (e.g. 3 to 1) based on mortality tables (and other information) such that individuals commencing work at an earlier age could, ceteris paribus, retire earlier. It is important to note that attitudes towards retirement policy may be shaped by the institutional context within which individuals have been brought up. For example, the French pension system involves eligibility for receipt of a full pension after a specified number of years of employment related contributions have been made. In Australia, where there is no formal designation of some part of labour income taxes as contributions to a retirement provision, there is less attention paid to length of working life as an eligibility criterion, rather than age per se. 1 This section draws heavily on The Treasury (2001) and Nielson (2010) 2 In fact, Nielson (2010) reports that the Chifley Government in 1945 established a National Welfare Fund, which received some part of budget tax receipts, as part of planning for a national superannuation scheme, but that this operated solely as an accounting device until its abolition in 1985. January 27, 2014 8

Particularly relevant to these considerations is the concept of fairness. The existence of a universal, means-tested, age pension, inherently reflects fairness considerations, by ensuring that some minimal level of support is available to all individuals beyond some age at which they may no longer be able to generate income through employment or running down of accumulated savings. But, it can be argued, current arrangements mean that it is not actuarially fair, potentially biasing retirement decisions. (See Box 2) BOX 2: Actuarially Fair Pension Arrangements A relevant concept for considerations of alternative policies is an actuarially fair pension. This is based on thinking of the pension as a lifetime annuity which, subject to some wealth related eligibility conditions, should be available and of equal expected value to all recipients. The expected value for any individual will depend on the number of years from commencement of the pension to expected death. Thus, an individual who works to an older age should expect to receive a larger annual pension than one who retires earlier. (This type of approach applies for the US Social Security System and in reforms in the 1990s to Italian and Swedish schemes, which adopted notional defined contribution schemes (Hairault et al, 2010)). Compounding the inequity, if this is not the case, individuals who retire later and/or who have had more years in employment can be expected to have, on average, contributed more to the taxation revenue needed to sustain the pension system. An arrangement of this sort was introduced by the Howard Government in the 1997-98 Budget, providing that those who deferred age pension take-up while continuing to work a minimum of 25 hours per week, accrued a cumulative tax exempt bonus entitlement of 9.4 per cent of his or her basic pension entitlement for each full year of employment past pension qualifying age (maximum 5 years deferral) (Treasury 2001). This scheme was closed to new entrants who had not qualified for the age pension by 20 September 2009. It was replaced by a Work Bonus scheme 3 whereby an increased allowance was made for income earned in calculating the income test for pension eligibility. (Only 50 per cent of earned income up to a maximum of $500 per fortnight was included initially. Recent changes to this were announced in 2012 4 ). The Age pension in Australia is now supplemented by superannuation savings. Institutionalised employee superannuation began in Australia in September 1985 when the Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) sought a three per cent employer contribution as part of its National Wage Case claim. This principal was approved in 1986 and subsequently new industrial awards were progressively negotiated under these guidelines. It was not until 1 July 1992, that the superannuation guarantee was introduced requiring employers to make tax-deductible superannuation contributions on behalf of their employees. From a base of three per cent, higher levels of contributions were phased-in over a ten-year period, reaching the maximum of nine per cent in 2002/03. Mandatory contribution rates for superannuation are scheduled to increase from the current 9 per cent of employee s wages to 12 per cent by July 2019. 3 According to http://www.superguide.com.au/how-super-works/goodbye-pension-bonus-hello-work-bonus 4 http://jennymacklin.fahcsia.gov.au/node/1974 January 27, 2014 9

2.2 The Economic and Social Setting Since the introduction of the SGC, economic growth and technological change have led to increased average income levels (See Figure 1) and wealth accumulation, suggesting scope for better living standards in retirement. As Table I indicates, average household real disposable income has increased consistently over the past two decades, before declining slightly with the onset of the Global Financial Crisis. Figure 1 Household Average Real Disposable Income 5 : 1994-2010 $1,000 $900 $800 $700 $600 $500 $400 $300 $200 $100 $0 Source: ABS, CAT 6523.0 Household Income and Income Distribution, Australia - Detailed tables, 2009-10 These economic gains have been offset to some extent by demographic changes such as increased longevity, a low birth rate 6 and consequent decline in the working-age population relative to those of non-working age (young and elderly). Figure 2: Australian Fertility Rate 2001-11 2.00 Australian Fertility Rate: 2001-2011 1.95 1.90 1.85 1.80 1.75 1.70 1.65 1.60 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Source: ABS, CAT 3301.0 Births Australia, 2011 With better standards of living, better health care and lower mortality rates, average longevity over the past century has increased significantly. Life expectancy has increased from around 47 years for a male born in the 1890s to 79 years for one born in 2007-2009. The natural consequence of this has been a commensurate increase in years of life post-retirement, with remaining life expectancy at age 5 Disposable income is measured as Gross income less income tax, the Medicare levy and the Medicare levy surcharge 6 The fertility rate represents the number of children an average woman has during her lifetime, and the replacement rate for a developed country is estimated to be around 2.1. The most recent statistics from the ABS show that Australia s fertility rate is reasonably flat at around 1.88. January 27, 2014 10

1961 1963 1965 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 AIST-ACFS Research Project 2013 65 increasing from 11 years to 18 years over the same period. The challenge for retirement systems, therefore, is to provide for individuals through this extended non-working period. Table 2 Life expectancy (additional years of life) for people at selected years of age Males Females At At age At birth At age 65 birth 65 1881 1890 47.2 11.1 50.8 12.3 1891 1900 51.1 11.3 54.8 12.8 1901 1910 55.2 11.3 58.8 12.9 1920 1922 59.2 12 63.3 13.6 1932 1934 63.5 12.4 67.1 14.2 1946 1948 66.1 12.3 70.6 14.4 1953 1955 67.1 12.3 72.8 15 1965 1967 67.6 12.2 74.2 15.7 1975 1977 69.6 13.1 76.6 17.1 1985 1987 72.7 14.6 79.2 18.6 1995 1997 75.6 16.1 81.3 19.8 2004 2006 78.7 18.3 83.5 21.5 2007 2009 79.3 18.7 83.9 21.8 As Figure 3 shows, in the early 1970s there were around 7 workers for each person of retirement age, with this declining to 5 by 2011. While the ratio of working age population to those under 15 has increased from 2 to around 3.5 over the same period, this portends a slower growth in the working age population over the longer term when the aged population is increasing. 8.00 7.00 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 Figure 3 Working Age/Non-Working Age Population, Australia 1961-2011 Working Age to Non-Working Age Population Working Age to Over 65's Working Age to Under 15's Source: World Bank, http://data.worldbank.org/country/australia An ageing population and higher longevity of those in retirement means that, with relatively fewer of working age, meeting retiree needs involves substantial intergenerational income and wealth consequences. Family arrangements have also been changing, with later family formation and increased longevity leading to increased age of inheritances and bequests from parents, and family January 27, 2014 11

1978 1979 1981 1983 1984 1986 1988 1989 1991 1993 1994 1996 1998 1999 2001 2003 2004 2006 2008 2009 2011 AIST-ACFS Research Project 2013 restructurings due to divorce/separations and remarriage/re-partnering (Hayes et al, 2010 provide an overview). These changes in family arrangements, together with the ageing of the population can impact the extent to which families can support retirees and supplement retiree income. Another relevant factor is technological change which is changing available employment options and skill requirements with potentially adverse consequences for employment security, income and alternative employment options for many older workers approaching retirement age. Increasing globalisation and competition from lower wage workers in developing countries can aggravate the adverse employment and income impact of technological change on workers (and business owners) in affected occupations and industry, even though society as a whole can benefit from these trends. Figure 4 shows trends in labour force participation rates while figure 5 shows recent trends in the ratio of part time to full time work for different age groups. Participation rates of males in the workforce for the age groups 55-59 years, 60 to 64 years and over 65 years showed some decline over the past two decades but have returned over recent years to similar levels as in the late 1970s. Female participation rates for the age groups 55-59 years and 60 to 64 years, on the other hand, have shown a consistent increase since the late 1980s, with a marked acceleration since the late 1990s. Participation rates of females over 65 show some increase in the post GFC period. Male 90.0 80.0 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 Figure 4 Trends in Labour Force Participation Rates 1992 2011 55-59 years 60-64 years 65 years and over Source: ABS, Cat 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, July 2012 January 27, 2014 12

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 1978 1979 1981 1983 1985 1986 1988 1990 1992 1993 1995 1997 1999 2000 2002 2004 2006 2007 2009 2011 AIST-ACFS Research Project 2013 Female 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 55-59 years 60-64 years 65 years and over Source: ABS, Cat 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, July 2012 As the ratio of full time to part-time male workers shown in Figure 5 indicates, there has been some decline over the past two decades in the 55 to 59 and 60 to 64 age groups, possibly indicating ongoing casualization of the workforce, The ratio of full to part-time workers has changed little in the over 65 year age group. For females, the ratio of full to part time workers increased in the 55 to 59 age group, stayed relatively constant in the 60 to 64 age group, and declined slightly in the over 65 age group. Given the increased participation rates across all age groups it more difficult to define any impact of casualization amongst the female workforce. Male Figure 5 Ratio of full-time to part-time workers: 1992-2011 10.0 9.0 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 55-59 60-64 65 + Source: ABS, Cat 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, July 2012 January 27, 2014 13

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 AIST-ACFS Research Project 2013 Female 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 55-59 60-64 65 + Source: ABS, Cat 6105.0 - Australian Labour Market Statistics, July 2012 Hidden within those aggregate changes are substantial shifts in the composition of employment shown in Figure 6. Strong growth has occurred in the professional services area, in occupations requiring higher education training, and in mining and construction, with little or no growth in areas such as manufacturing, agriculture, and lower skilled occupations. For older workers in many industries these structural shifts can imply redundancies and limited opportunities to obtain employment in growth sectors, thereby hastening retirement. January 27, 2014 14