Threshold Values in German Labor Law and Job Dynamics in Small Firms: The Case of the Disability Law



Similar documents
Why More West than East German Firms Export

Working Paper Immigration and outsourcing: a general equilibrium analysis

Higher Wages in Exporting Firms: Self-Selection, Export Effect, or Both? First Evidence from German Linked Employer-Employee Data

Revealing Taste-Based Discrimination in Hiring: A Correspondence Testing Experiment with Geographic Variation

Is Temporary Agency Employment a Stepping Stone for Immigrants?

Temporary Work as an Active Labor Market Policy: Evaluating an Innovative Program for Disadvantaged Youths

Human Capital and Ethnic Self-Identification of Migrants

Risk Aversion and Sorting into Public Sector Employment

The Wage Return to Education: What Hides Behind the Least Squares Bias?

Is Economics a Good Major for Future Lawyers? Evidence from Earnings Data

Revisiting Inter-Industry Wage Differentials and the Gender Wage Gap: An Identification Problem

Do Financial Incentives Promote the Employment of the Disabled?

Performance Related Pay and Labor Productivity

Curriculum Vitae. PD Dr. Boris Hirsch

Diskussionspapiere der DFG- Forschergruppe (Nr.: ): Heterogene Arbeit: Positive und Normative Aspekte der Qualifikationsstruktur der Arbeit

Works Councils and Separations: Voice, Monopoly, and Insurance Effects

Unwillingness to Pay for Privacy: A Field Experiment

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance Benefits

Seemingly Irrelevant Events Affect Economic Perceptions and Expectations: The FIFA World Cup 2006 as a Natural Experiment

The Effect of Choice Options in Training Curricula on the Supply of and Demand for Apprenticeships

Leadership at School: Does the Gender of Siblings Matter?

A Note on the Determinants and Consequences of Outsourcing Using German Data

Exports, foreign direct investment, and productivity: Evidence from German firm level data. Joachim Wagner

Are the Self-Employed Really Jacks-of-All-Trades? Testing the Assumptions and Implications of Lazear s Theory of Entrepreneurship with German Data

Education, Market Rigidities and Growth

Copayments in the German Health System: Does It Work?

Life Satisfaction and Relative Income: Perceptions and Evidence

Disability and Job Mismatches in the Australian Labour Market

Programmierbeispiele zur Datenaufbereitung der Stichprobe der Integrierten Arbeitsmarktbiografien (SIAB) in Stata

Apprenticeship Training What for? Investment in Human Capital or Substitution of Cheap Labour?

Profit-sharing and the financial performance of firms: Evidence from Germany

Agency in Health-Care: Are Medical Care-Givers Perfect Agents?

Working Paper Estimating the Returns to Education Using the Newest Current Population Survey Education Questions

Curriculum Vitae Thorsten Schank

Does the Glass Ceiling Exist? A Cross-National Perspective on Gender Income Mobility

Quota Systems for Disabled Persons: Parameters, Aspects, Effectivity

Firm-specific Training: Consequences for Job Mobility

Item Nonresponse in Wages: Testing for Biased Estimates in Wage Equations

econstor zbw

Fixed Effects Bias in Panel Data Estimators

The Determinants of Performance Appraisal Systems: A Note (Do Brown and Heywood s Results for Australia Hold Up for Britain?)

Working Paper Series. RatSWD. Working Paper No. 2. A Modern Statistical Infrastructure for Excellent Research an Policy Advice

Addison, John T.; Bellmann, Lutz; Schnabel, Claus; Wagner, Joachim

Is There a Social Security Tax Wedge?

Discussion Papers. Viktor Steiner Katharina Wrohlich. Work Incentives and Labor Supply Effects of the Mini-Jobs Reform in Germany

Working Paper Vocational training and gender: wages and occupational mobility among young workers

ALWA-Befragungsdaten verknüpft mit administrativen Daten des IAB (ALWA-ADIAB)

Apprenticeship Training and the Business Cycle

Earnings in private jobs after participation to post-doctoral programs : an assessment using a treatment effect model. Isabelle Recotillet

Employer-Provided Health Insurance and Labor Supply of Married Women

Do exporters really pay higher wages? First evidence from German linked employer-employee data

Tax incentives, bequest motives, and the demand for life insurance: Evidence from two natural experiments in Germany. Nicolas Sauter.

Curriculum vitae. I. Personal details Carsten Burhop Date of birth: 02 November 1973 Nationality: German address:

Wage Posting or Wage Bargaining? Evidence from the Employers Side

Curriculum Vitae. 02/2003 Doctoral Degree from the University of Kassel: Dr. rer. pol. (summa cum laude).

Jahrbücher f. Nationalökonomie u. Statistik (Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart 2009) Bd. (Vol.) 229/5

Earnings, Disposable Income, and Consumption of Allowed and Rejected Disability Insurance Applicants

Do Migrants Get Good Jobs in Australia? The Role of Ethnic Networks in Job Search

Working Paper A call for comparative research: Consequences of a rising income inequality for state activities

Trade Union Membership and Dismissals

The Elasticity of Labor Demand and the Optimal Minimum Wage

The frequency of visiting a doctor: is the decision to go independent of the frequency?

Unfair Wage Perceptions and Sleep: Evidence from German Survey Data

DO FIRMS PAY FOR PERCEIVED RISKS AT WORK?**

Better Sexy than Flexy? A Lab Experiment Assessing the Impact of Perceived Attractiveness and Personality Traits on Hiring Decisions

Human Capital Spillovers and Economic Performance in the Workplace in 2004: Some British Evidence

FDZ-Arbeitspapier Nr. 28

Do the Best Go West? An Analysis of the Self-Selection of Employed East-West Migrants in Germany

Unpaid Work at Home. Younghwan Song *

econstor zbw

Rights of residence for researchers from non-eu countries in Germany. Overview on potential residence permits pursuant to the German Residence Act

Student Aid, Repayment Obligations and Enrolment into Higher Education in Germany Evidence from a Natural Experiment

Exporter Performance in the German Business Services Sector: First Evidence from the Services Statistics Panel. by Alexander Vogel

Working Paper The German manufacturing sector is a granular economy. Discussion Paper series, Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit, No.

INNOVATION THROUGH INTEGRATION: DIGITAL START-UPS AS EMPLOYERS FOR PEOPLE WITH IMMIGRATION BACKGROUNDS

Aderonke Osikominu. Applied Econometrics, Economics of Education, Labor Economics, Program Evaluation

Measuring Employability A First Empirical Approach

Trade Union Membership and Dismissals

Mohrenweiser, Jens; Wydra-Sommaggio, Gaby; Zwick, Thomas. Conference Paper Adverse Selection and Information Advantages of Training Firms

Determining Future Success of College Students

New register data from the German public employment service on counseling and monitoring the unemployed

Curriculum Vitae. Contact details. Current positions. Personal. Education and qualications

University of Zurich. Happiness and unemployment: a panel data analysis for Germany. Zurich Open Repository and Archive. Winkelmann, L; Winkelmann, R

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

Master of Arts Program Sociology European Societies. Institute of Sociology Freie University Berlin

Teenage Pregnancies and Births in Germany: Patterns and Developments

Working Paper Identifying regional labor demand shocks using sign restrictions

Health Impaired Employees Job Satisfaction: New Evidence from Athens, Greece

Get Training or Wait? Long-Run Employment Effects of Training Programs for the Unemployed in West Germany

Trust in Public Institutions over the Business Cycle

Jahrbücher f. Nationalökonomie u. Statistik (Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart 2012) Bd. (Vol.) 232/2

The Effectiveness of European Active Labor Market Policy

Publications: German Economic Research Institutes on Track

Why Do Firms Recruit Internationally?

Discussion Papers. Silke Anger. Working Time as an Investment? The Effects of Unpaid Overtime on Wages, Promotions, and Layoffs

Are German Tax-Revenue Forecasts Flawed?

Job Satisfaction and Employee Turnover: A Firm-Level Perspective

Jahrbücher f. Nationalökonomie u. Statistik (Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart 2010) Bd. (Vol.) 230/4

How To Study Health Insurance Coverage By Race And Ethnicity

Nurses Labour Supply Elasticities: The Importance of Accounting for Extensive Margins

Transcription:

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 386 Threshold Values in German Labor Law and Job Dynamics in Small Firms: The Case of the Disability Law Joachim Wagner Claus Schnabel Arnd Kölling November 2001 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor

Threshold Values in German Labor Law and Job Dynamics in Small Firms: The Case of the Disability Law Joachim Wagner Institute of Economics, University of Lüneburg, HWWA, Hamburg and IZA, Bonn Claus Schnabel Institute of Economics, Friedrich-Alexander-University Erlangen-Nuremberg Arnd Kölling Institute for Employment Research of the Federal Labor Services, Nuremberg Discussion Paper No. 386 November 2001 IZA P.O. Box 7240 D-53072 Bonn Germany Tel.: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-210 Email: iza@iza.org This Discussion Paper is issued within the framework of IZA s research area The Welfare State and Labor Markets. Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the institute. Research disseminated by IZA may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent, nonprofit limited liability company (Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Haftung) supported by the Deutsche Post AG. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its research networks, research support, and visitors and doctoral programs. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. The current research program deals with (1) mobility and flexibility of labor markets, (2) internationalization of labor markets and European integration, (3) the welfare state and labor markets, (4) labor markets in transition, (5) the future of work, (6) project evaluation and (7) general labor economics. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character.

IZA Discussion Paper No. 386 November 2001 ABSTRACT Threshold Values in German Labor Law and Job Dynamics in Small Firms: The Case of the Disability Law * According to the German disability law, or Schwerbehindertengesetz, either six percent of all jobs in an establishment must be occupied by disabled empoyees or the firm has to pay a penalty of DM 200 per month for every job under consideration. This note reports results from the first econometric investigation of the impact of this rule on job dynamics in small firms. Based on data from the IAB Establishment Panel we find no clear-cut evidence that employment in establishments at the first threshold of the law reacts differently on demand shocks than establishments below or above the threshold. JEL Classification: J23, J38 Keywords: Threshold values, disability law, labor demand Joachim Wagner Institute of Economics University of Lüneburg 21332 Lüneburg Germany Tel.: +49 4131-78-2330 Fax: +49 4131-78-2026 Email: wagner@uni-lueneburg.de This paper uses data from the IAB Establishment Panel, financially supported by the ESF. A previous version has been presented at the Econometric Society European Meeting ESEM 2001, the European Association of Labour Economists EALE Conference 2001, and the Jahrestagung 2001 of the Verein fuer Socialpolitik. We thank our discussants and participants at these conferences and other workshops for helpful comments. We appreciate the suggestions of an anonymous referee. The usual disclaimer applies.

2 1. Introduction Like in many other countries, relations between employers and employees in Germany are governed by a huge number of laws. Often these rules do apply only in establishments above a critical size, and often these thresholds are defined by the number of employees (see Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft 1998). A case in point is the German disability law, or Schwerbehindertengesetz: For establishments with 16 or more employees it demands that either six percent of all jobs must be occupied by disabled empoyees or the firm has to pay a penalty of DM 200 per month for every job that should have been occupied by a disabled worker but that is not. 1 For establishments with 15 employees (none of which is disabled) this law leads to a threshold value that is costly to cross: hiring one more (not disabled) employee increases costs by the wage and non-wage costs of this employee plus the penalty of DM 200 per month. If for example total labor costs per month for the job under consideration are DM 4000, this means an increase in the costs for hiring one more worker in an establishment at the threshold by 5 percent per month compared to firms below or above the threshold. These extra costs are often considered by businessmen (as well as by some economists) to form a barrier to job creation in small firms at the first threshold of the disability law. 2 It is argued that firms with 15 employees facing a positive demand shock will be retentive of hiring one more (not disabled) employee, and will either in the short run extend the number of hours worked per employee (which is costly, too, due to the premia that have to be paid) or substitute capital for labor in the long run. 3 Whether an establishment with 15 employees will cross the threshold under consideration depends on the size of the positive demand shock, among others. The larger the shock, the less 1 This rule applied before October 2000. In the new law the quota is lowered to five percent, and the penalty depends on the degree to which this quota is met in a complicated non-linear way (see Deutscher Bundestag 2000). 2 See the survey by Friedrich and Hägele 1997. For a discussion of the law and the situation of disabled workers in Germany see Frick and Frick (1994), Henninges, Jung-Hammon and Gruber (1998), and Sadowski and Frick (1992). 3 Note that hiring temporary workers is an option that can be used in the very short run only, because in the disability law employees with a contract length of more than eight weeks are not excluded from calculating the total number of workers. Due to missing information in the data used in our empirical study, however, we can not investigate the role of temporary employment.

3 weight will be put on the DM 200 penalty per month. However, given that we have no reason to assume that the size distribution of shocks differs systematically between establishments below, at, or above the threshold, we hypothesize that establishments with 15 employees have a lower probability to create a new job than establishments with slightly less or more employees. A similar reasoning applies for establishments with 16 (not disabled) employees that are facing a negative demand shock. Compared to establisments with e.g. 15 or 17 employees, firing a worker lowers costs not only by the wage and non-wage costs of this employee but by DM 200 per month extra due to the fact that the penalty must no longer be paid. Therefore, the incentive to reduce employment in times of negative demand shocks is hypothesized to be higher in establishments with 16 employees than in slightly smaller or larger establishments ceteris paribus. Information on the actual role played by the first threshold due to the disability law in small firm job dynamics in Germany is scarce. Beside anecdotal evidence telling stories of bosses of craft shops who did not hire the much needed sixteenth plumber or carpenter (evidently not a job easily done by a disabled person) and extended overtime instead, we have some results based on surveys of firms pointing rather vaguely to negative effects of the penalty rule for job creation (Diery, Schubert and Zink 1997; Friedrich and Hägele 1997). Empirical evidence based on econometric investigations is missing, and we are not aware of any econometric study on the effects of similar thresholds in other countries. In this note we intend to fill this gap. The rest of the paper is organised as follows: Section 2 introduces the data used in our study, section 3 discusses the method we applied in our empirical investigation and presents the results, and section 4 concludes. 2. Data An econometric analysis of the effects of the threshold value of the German disability law on job dynamics must be based on a set of longitudinal data at the establishment level with detailed information on the number of employees covered by social insurance, and the data must contain information on positive and negative demand shocks facing the establishments. Longitudinal data, or panel data, are needed because we must be able to follow the units over time; furthermore, panel data allow to control for unobserved heterogeneity. Establishment level data are needed because

4 the law is written in terms of the number of employees in a local production unit, or Betrieb, and not in terms of the number of employees in a legal unit (enterprise, or Unternehmen). Detailed information on the number of employees covered by social security is needed because the owner plus members of his family (who are not covered) and apprentices do not count for the threshold under consideration. Information on positive and negative demand shocks are needed for obvious reasons. Furthermore, the data set must cover a sufficient number of small establishments with numbers of employees that lie just below, exactly at, or just behind the threshold under consideration. To the best of our knowledge there is only one data set in Germany available that fulfils these rather demanding requirements, 4 the IAB Establishment Panel of the Institute for Employment Research of the Federal Labor Services in Germany (or Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung, IAB). This panel surveys some 4000 establishments from all sectors of the economy in West Germany once in a year since 1993 (and about the same number of establishments in East Germany since 1996). In 1998, the data set contains information for some 9,000 observations. It is based on a stratified random sample (using strata for 16 industries and 10 size classes) from the population of all local production units with at least one employee covered by social insurance. To correct for panel mortality, exits, and newly founded units, the samples are augmented regularly, leading to an unbalanced panel data set. Participation of establishments is voluntary, and the response rates (above 70 percent) are high compared to other non-official German firm panel studies. Data are collected in personal interviews with the owners or managers of the establishments by professional interviewers. The panel is created to serve the needs of the Federal Labor Services, so its focus is on employment related matters. 5 One caveat should be mentioned: The IAB Establishment Panel has no information on the number of disabled employees in an establishment. To see why this could be a cause for concern 4 Unfortunately, therefore, our investigation cannot be based on comparative evidence from more than one data set. Given that this is the first econometric study on the effects of the threshold under consideration, using other data sets to replicate or revise our findings is especially important, and we offer any help to do so. 5 For more information on the IAB Establishment Panel see Kölling (2000). Note that the data are confidential but not exclusive. Those interested in using the data for scientific (non-commercial) research should contact the third author via e-mail: arnd.koelling@iab.de.

5 imagine two establishments with 15 employees, one with (at least) one disabled employee (call it company A) and one with no disabled employees (call it company B). If both companies face an identical positive demand shock and hire one more (not disabled) employee, only company B will have to pay the penalty of DM 200 per month. According to our hypothesis, therefore, company B will have a lower probability to create a new job than company A. Without information about the number of disabled workers in an establishment both companies are classified as "exactly at the threshold", and this leads to an errors-in-variables problem in the context investigated here. However, given that we have no information that the probability of employing at least one disabled worker differs systematically between establishments just before, exactly at, and just behind the threshold under consideration, we would argue that this does not harm our conclusions.

6 3. Econometric investigation Our econometric investigation of the role played by German disability law's first threshold in small firm job dynamics is based on data from the IAB Establishment Panel described in section 2 above. We consider all West German establishments working for profit 6 that participated in the survey in at least two consecutive years between 1993 and 1998. Using these data we test two hypotheses derived from theoretical considerations and stated in the introductory section 1 above: Hypothesis 1: Establishments at the first threshold of the German disability law facing a positive demand shock have a ceteris paribus lower probability of hiring one more employee than establishments below or above this threshold. 7 Hypothesis 2: Establishments at the first threshold of the German disability law facing a negative demand shock have a ceteris paribus higher probability of firing one employee than establishments below or above this threshold. As regards hypothesis 1, an establishment is considered to lie at the threshold if it has 15 employees covered by social insurance (excluding apprentices) at June 30 of year t, because hiring one more (not disabled) worker would mean to cross the border from below. To compare like with like, establishments with 13 or 14 (16 or 17) employees are considered to lie just below (above) the threshold. 8 An establishment is considered to face a positive demand shock if the interviewed 6 East German establishments were excluded because of the rather short time span since the survey started. Non-profit sectors like universities and public administration are excluded because labor demand in these parts of the economy cannot be expected to follow standard economic reasoning. The Stata jobs used for all calculations are available from the first author to facilitate replications and extensions. 7 It should be noted that due to data limitations we cannot test what could be called the "second part" of this hypothesis, namely that establishments at the threshold will either in the short run extend the number of hours worked per employee and/or substitute capital for labor in the long run instead. From the survey we have no information on the capital stock of the establishments, and information on overtime is not available in the detailed form needed here. 8 As a caveat we have to admit that the data do not allow an exact sorting of establishments at the threshold and behind due to missing detailed information about part-time workers and the hours worked by parttimers. Without going into details of the law, what we would need to calculate exactly would be some kind of full-time equivalent number of employees. Given that this information is missing in the survey, an establishment with 15 "heads counted" might well have

7 person states that an increase in the economic activity (or Geschäftsvolumen) of the establishment is expected between this year and the next. As regards hypothesis 2, an establishment is considered to lie at the threshold if it has 16 employees covered by social insurance (excluding apprentices) at June 30 of year t, because firing one worker would mean to cross the border from above. Again to compare like with like, establishments with 17 or 18 (14 or 15) employees are considered to lie just above (below) the threshold. An establishment is considered to face a negative demand shock if the interviewed person states that a decrease in the economic activity (or Geschäftsvolumen) of the establishment is expected between this year and the next. The endogenous variable in the empirical model to test hypothesis 1 is a dummy variable with the value one if the establishment reports a higher number of employees covered by social insurance (excluding apprentices) for June 30 in year t+1 than for June 30 in year t, and the value zero otherwise. Similarly, the endogenous variable in the empirical model to test hypothesis 2 is a dummy variable with the value one if the establishment reports a lower number of employees covered by social insurance (excluding apprentices) for June 30 in year t+1 than for June 30 in year t, and the value zero otherwise. Both empirical models contain the following exogenous variables: A dummy variable indicating whether the establishment has been at the threshold or not in year t, a dummy variable showing whether the establishment was facing a positve (in case of hypothesis 1) or negative (in case of hyposthesis 2) demand shock in year t, an interaction term of the threshold dummy and the demand shock dummy, and a set of dummy variables for the various two-year periods covered to control for fixed time effects (economy-wide business conditions, etc.). The models were estimated with pooled data from 1993/94 to 1997/98 forming an unbalanced panel. The method of estimation was random effects probit in order to control for unobserved heterogeneity of establishments. 9 less "full-time equivalents", and, therefore, might be misclassified as being at the margin. A similar reasoning applies in establishments with 16 or more "heads" but less than 15 "full-time equivalents", that might be misclassified as above the margin while being at it or even below. Unfortunately, we cannot solve this errors-in-variables problem. 9 All computations were done with Stata Release 7. Note that it was not possible to estimate the model by fixed effects logit, too, because using this estimator would mean to exclude all

8 Descripitive statistics for data used to investigate hypothesis 1 and 2 are given in table 1 and table 3, respectively, and econometric results are reported in table 2 and table 4. [Table 1 near here] We start with a look at table I. 23 percent of all establishments were at the threshold with 15 employees in year t, and from the data for the distribution of establishments across various sizes we have no evidence for congestion at the threshold. About one third of all firms increased employment between year t and year t+1, while a little more than one in four establishments faced a positive demand shock. Six percent of all establishments were threshold firms with a positive shock. [Table 2 near here] According to hypothesis 1 we expect the estimated coefficient of the threshold dummy to be negative, indicating that establishments at the threshold have a lower probability to increase employment than establishments below or above this threshold, ceteris paribus. Results reported in table 2 support this. Furthermore, the estimated coefficient of the demand shock variable is positive as expected, indicating that establishments that reported to expect an increase in their volume of business in t had a higher probability to increase the number of employees between t and t+1 - this coefficient, however, is not significantly different from zero at a conventional statistical level. If hypothesis 1 holds we expect the interaction term of the threshold dummy and the demand shock dummy to be negative, indicating that being a threshold establishment lowers the effect of a positive demand shock, but the results do not support this. 10 establishments that had the same value of the endogenous variable in all periods (e.g. that did not grow ever), and evidently this makes no sense here. 10 Because the cost of an additional worker might vary across industries and, therefore, the penalty for not hiring a disabled person might vary in its marginal effect, we also ran the regressions separately for establishments from manufacturing (N = 188) and services (N = 218). The estimated coefficients are all insignificant at the five percent level; the point estimates for the threshold dummy and the interaction term of threshold and shock, however, are much larger for services

9 Some indication as to the size of the threshold effect can be achieved by a simple simulation exercise: Taking the results reported in table 2 at face value the estimated probability for an increase in employment between t and t+1 for an establishment that is not at the threshold and not facing a positive demand shock in the first time period considered is 0.56, while a threshold establishment without a positive shock has a much lower value of 0.41. The difference is less clear for firms with a positive shock; the estimated probabilities are 0.66 and 0.63 for non-threshold and threshold establishments, respectively. From table 2, therefore, we have only weak empirical evidence in favor of hypothesis 1. 11 [Table 3 near here] Next, consider hypothesis 2. From table 3 we see that 21 percent of all establishments were at the threshold with 16 employees in year t, and from the data for the distribution of establishments across various sizes we have again no evidence for congestion at the threshold. 40 percent of all firms decreased employment between year t and year t+1, while a little more than one in four establishments faced a negative demand shock. Six percent of all establishments were threshold firms with a negative shock. Note that the last two numbers are more or less identical for the group of establishments used to test hypothesis 1. [Table 4 near here] Let us now turn to the econometric results results reported in table 4. According to hypothesis 2 we expect the estimated coefficient of the threshold dummy to be positive, indicating that establishments at the threshold have a higher probability to decrease employment than establishments below or above this threshold, ceteris paribus. Results in table 4 do not support this. establishments than for manufacturing establishments. The tables with the results are available on request. 11 Note that the null hypothesis that the random effects are all zero cannot be rejected at any level of significance (the probvalue is 0.9958); therefore, the estimation results from the random effects probit model are numerically identical to the results from a simple pooled probit model.

10 The estimated coefficient of the threshold dummy is positive as expected, but not statistically different from zero at a conventional level, and the same holds true for the estimated coefficient of the demand shock variable. If hypothesis 2 holds we expect the interaction term of the threshold dummy and the demand shock dummy to be positive, indicating that being a threshold establishment increases the effect of a negative demand shock, but again the results do not support this. 12 An indication as to the size of the threshold effect can be achieved by simulation, using the results reported in table 4: The estimated probability for a decrease in employment between t and t+1 for an establishment that is not at the threshold and not facing a negative demand shock in the first time period considered is 0.23, while a threshold establishment without a negative shock has a much higher value of 0.33. This difference is smaller for firms with a negative shock; the estimated probabilities are 0.31 and 0.37 for non-threshold and threshold establishments, respectively. From table 4, therefore, we have no compelling evidence in favor of hypothesis 2. 13 4. Concluding remarks According to the results of our econometric investigation the first threshold of the German disability law does not seem to have the kind of strong negative influence on job dynamics in small firms that is often attributed to it in public debates. On the other hand we cannot reject the two hypotheses tested in a way that would allow us to state that the threshold does not matter at all. Frankly, these somewhat inconclusive results can arise (at least, in part) due to problems with the data mentioned earlier, i.e. missing information on (changes in) overtime, capital stock, employment of disabled persons, parttime employees, and strength of demand shocks. 12 Again, the models were estimated separately for establishments from manufacturing (N = 191) and services (N = 206). Only the coefficient of the demand shock variable in the model using data from manufacturing is statistically different from zero at the five percent level of significance; all other coefficients are insignificant. The tables with the results are available on request. 13 Again the null hypothesis that the random effects are all zero cannot be rejected at any level of significance (the probvalue is 0.9963); see footnote 8.

11 Furthermore, even in the large samples of the IAB Establishment Panel there are only small numbers of establishments with 13 to 18 employees, and this might lead to imprecise estimates. Another point might be that the amount of DM 200 an establishment has to pay (will save) as a penalty when crossing the threshold from below (above) is too small to act as an incentive. Economists are used to think at the margin - practitioners may not. The new law effective from October 1, 2000 has increased the penalty up to DM 500 (if the share of disabled employees is below 2 percent) while at the same time rising the first threshold to 20 employees. This introduces some kind of natural experiment. Future research will show whether and how establisments do react to these changes. For the next four years or so, however, the evidence presented in this paper is all we have. References Deutscher Bundestag (2000), Antwort der Bundesregierung auf die Kleine Anfrage der Abgeordneten Johannes Singhammer et al.: Ausgleichsabgabe für Schwerbehinderte, Bundestagsdrucksache 14/3031 vom 10. 5. 2000. Diery, Hartmuth, Hans-Joachim Schubert and Klaus J. Zink (1997), Die Eingliederung von Schwerbehinderten in das Arbeitsleben aus der Sicht von Unternehmen - Ergebnisse einer empirischen Untersuchung, Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung 30, 442-454. Frick, Bernd and Joachim Frick (1994), Labor Market Policy and the Convergence of Interests: The "Benefits" of the German Handicapped Act for Employers and Employees, in: Johannes Schwarze, Friedrich Buttler and Gert G. Wagner (Eds.), Labour Market Dynamics in Present Day Germany, Frankfurt/New York, 217-239. Friedrich, Werner and Helmut Hägele (1997), Ökonomische Konsequenzen von Schwellenwerten im Arbeits- und Sozialrecht sowie die Auswirkungen dieser Regelungen, Studien der ISG Sozialforschung und Gesellschaftspolitik Band 20, Köln.

12 Henninges, Hasso von, Thomas Jung-Hammon und Hannelore Gruber (1998), Arbeitsmarktsituation von Schwerbehinderten, IAB-Werkstattbericht Nr. 13 vom 17. 11. 1998, Nürnberg. Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft (1998), Arbeitsrecht: Gesetzliche Stolpersteine, iwd - Informationsdienst des Instituts der deutschen Wirtschaft 24, No. 30, 23. Juli 1998, 6-7. Kölling, Arnd (2000), The IAB-Establishment Panel, Schmollers Jahrbuch - Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 120, 291-300. Sadowski, Dieter und Bernd Frick (1992), Die Beschäftigung Schwerbehinderter: Betriebswirtschaftliche Analysen und politische Empfehlungen, Idstein.

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics for Data used to investigate Hypothesis 1 Distribution of establishments across various sizes No. of employees in t Percentage of establishm. 13 20.75 14 22.17 15 23.11 16 20.52 17 13.44 Variables in the empirical model Mean Std. Dev. Increase in employment between t and t+1 0.35 0.48 Threshold dummy 0.23 0.42 Positive demand shock dummy 0.28 0.45 Interaction term of threshold and positive shock 0.06 0.25 Source: Own calculations with data from the IAB Establishment Panel; selected industries Pooled data for 1993/94 to 1997/98

Table 2: Results for Hypothesis 1 Endogenous variable: Increase in employment between t and t+1 (Dummy; 1 = yes, 0 = no) Estimation method: Random effects probit Threshold -0.40 * Dummy: 1 = establishment with 15 (2.01) employees in t; 0 = otherwise Demand shock 0.25 Dummy; 1 = increase in activity (1.47) expected between t and t+1 Interaction term of threshold dummy 0.33 and demand shock dummy (0.93) Time period dummies included Random establishment effects included Constant 0.16 (1.10) Number of establishments 406 Pseudo-R 2 0.09 Source: Own calculations with data from the IAB Establishment Panel; selected industries Establishments with 13 to 17 employees in t 0 Pooled data for 1993/94 to 1997/98 Values in brackets are absolute t-values; * indicates statistical significance at the 5 percent level

Table 3: Descriptive Statistics for Data used to investigate Hypothesis 2 Distribution of establishments across various sizes No. of employees in t Percentage of establishm. 14 22.54 15 23.50 16 20.86 17 13.67 18 19.42 Variables in the empirical model Mean Std. Dev. Decrease in employment between t and t+1 0.40 0.49 Threshold dummy 0.21 0.40 Negative demand shock dummy 0.26 0.44 Interaction term of threshold and negative shock 0.06 0.23 Source: Own calculations with data from the IAB Establishment Panel; selected industries Pooled data for 1993/94 to 1997/98

Table 4: Results for Hypothesis 2 Endogenous variable: Decrease in employment between t and t+1 (Dummy; 1 = yes, 0 = no) Estimation method: Random effects probit Threshold 0.29 Dummy: 1 = establishment with 16 (1.51) employees in t; 0 = otherwise Demand shock 0.23 Dummy; 1 = decrease in activity (1.39) expected between t and t+1 Interaction term of threshold dummy -0.11 and demand shock dummy (0.30) Time period dummies included Random establishment effects included Constant -0.74 ** (4.83) Number of establishments 397 Pseudo-R 2 0.06 Source: Own calculations with data from the IAB Establishment Panel; selected industries Establishments with 14 to 18 employees in t 0 Pooled data for 1993/94 to 1997/98 Values in brackets are absolute t-values; ** indicates statistical significance at the 1 percent level

IZA Discussion Papers No. Author(s) Title Area Date 372 J. Konings H. Lehmann Marshall and Labour Demand in Russia: Going Back to Basics 4 09/01 373 S. J. Trejo Does the Statutory Overtime Premium Discourage Long Workweeks? 1 10/01 374 G. J. van den Berg B. van der Klaauw 375 J. A. Dunlevy W. K. Hutchinson Counseling and Monitoring of Unemployed Workers: Theory and Evidence from a Controlled Social Experiment The Pro-Trade Effect of Immigration on American Exports During the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries 6 10/01 1 10/01 376 G. Corneo Work and Television 5 10/01 377 S. J. Trejo Intergenerational Progress of Mexican-Origin Workers in the U.S. Labor Market 1 10/01 378 D. Clark R. Fahr 379 H. Antecol D. A. Cobb-Clark The Promise of Workplace Training for Non- College-Bound Youth: Theory and Evidence from German Apprenticeship The Sexual Harassment of Female Active-Duty Personnel: Effects on Job Satisfaction and Intentions to Remain in the Military 1 10/01 5 10/01 380 M. Sattinger A Kaldor Matching Model of Real Wage Declines 7 10/01 381 J. T. Addison P. Teixeira The Economics of Employment Protection 3 10/01 382 L. Goerke Tax Evasion in a Unionised Economy 3 11/01 383 D. Blau E. Tekin The Determinants and Consequences of Child Care Subsidies for Single Mothers 3 11/01 384 D. Acemoglu J.-S. Pischke Minimum Wages and On-the-Job Training 1 11/01 385 A. Ichino R. T. Riphahn 386 J. Wagner C. Schnabel A. Kölling The Effect of Employment Protection on Worker Effort: A Comparison of Absenteeism During and After Probation Threshold Values in German Labor Law and Job Dynamics in Small Firms: The Case of the Disability Law 1 11/01 3 11/01 An updated list of IZA Discussion Papers is available on the center s homepage www.iza.org.