Warren Buffett, Black-Scholes and the Valuation of Long-dated Options

Similar documents
The Binomial Option Pricing Model André Farber

Journal of Financial and Economic Practice

On Black-Scholes Equation, Black- Scholes Formula and Binary Option Price

11 Option. Payoffs and Option Strategies. Answers to Questions and Problems

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS OPTION PRICING

BINOMIAL OPTIONS PRICING MODEL. Mark Ioffe. Abstract

DETERMINING THE VALUE OF EMPLOYEE STOCK OPTIONS. Report Produced for the Ontario Teachers Pension Plan John Hull and Alan White August 2002

Use the option quote information shown below to answer the following questions. The underlying stock is currently selling for $83.

Black Scholes Merton Approach To Modelling Financial Derivatives Prices Tomas Sinkariovas Words: 3441

Black-Scholes-Merton approach merits and shortcomings

Options: Valuation and (No) Arbitrage

For both risk and return, increasing order is b, c, a, d. On average, the higher the risk of an investment, the higher is its expected return. 2.

Key Concepts and Skills

Are Bonds Going to Outperform Stocks Over the Long Run? Not Likely.

1 The Black-Scholes Formula

第 9 讲 : 股 票 期 权 定 价 : B-S 模 型 Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes Model

Two-State Options. John Norstad. January 12, 1999 Updated: November 3, 2011.

Option Values. Option Valuation. Call Option Value before Expiration. Determinants of Call Option Values

Call and Put. Options. American and European Options. Option Terminology. Payoffs of European Options. Different Types of Options

CHAPTER 10 RISK AND RETURN: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL (CAPM)

PRESENT DISCOUNTED VALUE

Option pricing. Module 3

Chapter 8 Financial Options and Applications in Corporate Finance ANSWERS TO END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

Option Valuation. Chapter 21

How To Calculate Financial Leverage Ratio

How To Price A Call Option

Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model. Chapter 13

An Introduction to Exotic Options

Quantitative Strategies Research Notes

Implied Volatility Skews in the Foreign Exchange Market. Empirical Evidence from JPY and GBP:

Steve Meizinger. FX Options Pricing, what does it Mean?

Statement by Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research (

Option Pricing Beyond Black-Scholes Dan O Rourke

Lecture 4: The Black-Scholes model

Simple formulas to option pricing and hedging in the Black Scholes model

Challenges in the Life Insurance Industry

Futures Price d,f $ 0.65 = (1.05) (1.04)

Three Investment Risks

Insights. Understanding market value margins in options prices. September Background

A Piece of the Pie: Alternative Approaches to Allocating Value

GN47: Stochastic Modelling of Economic Risks in Life Insurance

NPH Fixed Income Research Update. Bob Downing, CFA. NPH Senior Investment & Due Diligence Analyst

How To Value Options In Black-Scholes Model

Jorge Cruz Lopez - Bus 316: Derivative Securities. Week 11. The Black-Scholes Model: Hull, Ch. 13.

Employee Options, Restricted Stock and Value. Aswath Damodaran 1

The Intuition Behind Option Valuation: A Teaching Note

Why asset management arms of banks should continue to lend bank shares

CHAPTER 5 OPTION PRICING THEORY AND MODELS

Lecture Notes: Basic Concepts in Option Pricing - The Black and Scholes Model

Two-State Option Pricing

Estimating Volatility

Volatility: A Brief Overview

VALUATION IN DERIVATIVES MARKETS

BERYL Credit Pulse on High Yield Corporates

The Black-Scholes Formula

Option Values. Determinants of Call Option Values. CHAPTER 16 Option Valuation. Figure 16.1 Call Option Value Before Expiration

OPTIONS and FUTURES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

Option Pricing Theory and Applications. Aswath Damodaran

Call Price as a Function of the Stock Price

Retirement Savings: Choosing a Withdrawal Rate That Is Sustainable

BINOMIAL OPTION PRICING

Econ 330 Exam 1 Name ID Section Number

The Tax Benefits and Revenue Costs of Tax Deferral

Options Pricing. This is sometimes referred to as the intrinsic value of the option.

Financial Options: Pricing and Hedging

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

Discussion of Gertler and Kiyotaki: Financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis

EC247 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS AND CAPITAL MARKETS TERM PAPER

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Institutional Finance 08: Dynamic Arbitrage to Replicate Non-linear Payoffs. Binomial Option Pricing: Basics (Chapter 10 of McDonald)

MONEY, INTEREST, REAL GDP, AND THE PRICE LEVEL*

VALUING REAL OPTIONS USING IMPLIED BINOMIAL TREES AND COMMODITY FUTURES OPTIONS

Option pricing. Vinod Kothari

DERIVATIVE SECURITIES Lecture 2: Binomial Option Pricing and Call Options

Review of Basic Options Concepts and Terminology

Tutorial: Structural Models of the Firm

CHAPTER 3 THE LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL

International Money and Banking: 12. The Term Structure of Interest Rates

Finance 350: Problem Set 6 Alternative Solutions

TPPE17 Corporate Finance 1(5) SOLUTIONS RE-EXAMS 2014 II + III

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

Chapter Seven STOCK SELECTION

CHAPTER 21: OPTION VALUATION

Investment Research: How Much is Enough?

Caput Derivatives: October 30, 2003

Article from: Risk Management. November 2005 Issue 6

Invesco Great Wall Fund Management Co. Shenzhen: June 14, 2008

Black-Scholes Equation for Option Pricing

The power of money management

Successful value investing: the long term approach

CHAPTER 11 INTRODUCTION TO SECURITY VALUATION TRUE/FALSE QUESTIONS

2. Exercising the option - buying or selling asset by using option. 3. Strike (or exercise) price - price at which asset may be bought or sold

Chapter 3: Commodity Forwards and Futures

Homework Solutions - Lecture 2

Other variables as arguments besides S. Want those other variables to be observables.

PERSPECTIVES. Reasonable Expectations for the Long-Run U.S.Equity Risk Premium. Roger G. Clarke, Ph.D and Harindra de Silva, Ph.D.

American and European. Put Option

Eurodollar Futures, and Forwards

Computational Finance Options

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Transcription:

First draft: May 2009 Current version: June 2009 Warren Buffett, Black-Scholes and the Valuation of Long-dated Options BRADFORD CORNELL CALIFORNIA INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY PASADENA, CA 91125 626 564-2001 bcornell@hss.caltech.edu I would like to thank Jaksa Cvitanic and Levon Goukasian for helpful comments.

Warren Buffett, Black-Scholes and the Valuation of Long-dated Options Abstract In his 2008 letter to Berkshire shareholders, Warren Buffett presented a critique of the Black-Scholes option pricing model as a tool for valuing long-dated options, including options that Berkshire had written. Given Mr. Buffett s track record, it worth investigating precisely why he thinks that the Black-Scholes model fails to provide a fair value for longdated options. Unfortunately, the alleged deficiencies in the model are not transparent because Mr. Buffett s letter fails to develop his viewpoint in terms of option pricing theory. This short article fills the gap by interpreting Mr. Buffett s argument in the context of option pricing theory. It turns out that Mr. Buffett is really making a statement about political economics more than option pricing.

Introduction: Warren Buffett on long-dated options Despite referring to derivatives as weapons of mass financial destruction, Warren Buffett has not been shy about investing in derivatives. In his 2008 letter to the shareholders of Berkshire Hathaway, Mr. Buffett explains that that Berkshire will enter into derivatives transactions if prices are sufficiently favorable. With respect to the investments already made, he states, I believe each contract we own was mispriced at inception, sometimes dramatically so. In light of their reported poor performance, some Berkshire derivative contracts have attracted particular attention. The source of the most controversy has been long dated put options that Berkshire wrote on major stock market indexes, primarily the S&P 500. Using the required mark-to-market accounting, in 2008 Berkshire reported losses exceeding $5 billion on these contracts. In light of the reported losses, Mr. Buffett went to some lengths to explain why he thought the long-dated options were good investments. His explanation was premised on the view that the Black-Scholes option pricing model was a poor tool for valuing long-date equity index put options. Referring to the Black- Scholes model, Mr. Buffett went so far as to say that If the formula is applied to extended periods, however, it can produce absurd results. The purpose of this short paper is to explore exactly why Mr. Buffett believes the Black-Scholes model leads to absurd results by analyzing example calculations he presented in his shareholder letter. II. Buffet s Argument and the Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model Rather than directly analyzing the Black-Scholes model, Mr. Buffett frames his - 1 -

critique of the model in terms of example calculations. In deference to Mr. Buffett, and to avoid mischaracterization, here is his entire explanation from the shareholder letter. It s often useful in testing a theory to push it to extremes. So let s postulate that we sell a 100- year $1 billion put option on the S&P 500 at a strike price of 903 (the index s level on 12/31/08). Using the implied volatility assumption for long-dated contracts that we do, and combining that with appropriate interest and dividend assumptions, we would find the proper Black-Scholes premium for this contract to be $2.5 million. To judge the rationality of that premium, we need to assess whether the S&P will be valued a century from now at less than today. Certainly the dollar will then be worth a small fraction of its present value (at only 2% inflation it will be worth roughly 14 ). So that will be a factor pushing the stated value of the index higher. Far more important, however, is that one hundred years of retained earnings will hugely increase the value of most of the companies in the index. In the 20th Century, the Dow-Jones Industrial Average increased by about 175-fold, mainly because of this retained-earnings factor. Considering everything, I believe the probability of a decline in the index over a one-hundred-year period to be far less than 1%. But let s use that figure and also assume that the most likely decline should one occur is 50%. Under these assumptions, the mathematical expectation of loss on our contract would be $5 million ($1 billion x 1% x 50%). But if we had received our theoretical premium of $2.5 million up front, we would have only had to invest it at 0.7% compounded annually to cover this - 2 -

loss expectancy. Everything earned above that would have been profit. Would you like to borrow money for 100 years at a 0.7% rate? Let s look at my example from a worst-case standpoint. Remember that 99% of the time we would pay nothing if my assumptions are correct. But even in the worst case among the remaining 1% of possibilities that is, one assuming a total loss of $1 billion our borrowing cost would come to only 6.2%. Clearly, either my assumptions are crazy or the formula is inappropriate. When Mr. Buffett refers to a $1 billion put option in the example, he means that $1 billion is the maximum loss if the index were to go to zero. Given the hypothetical index level of 903, this implies that the put options are effectively written on 11,074,200 units of the index. To use the Black-Sholes model to price European put options on an index three inputs are required the dividend yield, the risk-free rate and the volatility. At the time that Mr. Buffett published his letter reasonable approximations for each of these were 3%, 4.8% and 18%, respectively. The 3% dividend yield is both the approximate yield on the date of Mr. Buffet s letter and the approximate average payout rate over the prior fifty years. The 4.8% risk-free rate is somewhat greater than the yield on 30-year Treasury bonds because at the time of the Berkshire letter disruptions in the financial market led many analysts, including Mr. Buffett, to believe that Treasury yields were artificially low. The 18% is based on estimates of the long-run historical standard deviation of nominal returns for the S&P 500. These assumptions are evidently quite close to those used by Mr. Buffett because when they are substituted into the Black- Scholes model the estimated value of the put position is found to be $2.46 million, within rounding error of the $2.5 million figure that Mr. Buffett refers to in his letter. - 3 -

Mr. Buffett clearly states that this value is much too high, but does not explicitly explain why the model fails to give the appropriate value. One thing he points to is inflation. Over the course of 100 years, depreciation in the purchasing power of the dollar will tend to increase nominal stock prices. Although Mr. Buffett is right to stress the impact of inflation, the Black-Scholes model takes account of this factor through the use of the nominal risk-free rate. As long as the inflation rate impounded in the risk-free rate is a reasonable estimate of long-run inflation, there will be no inflation bias in the model s estimate of value. Although Mr. Buffett bases his example calculations on the future earnings Berkshire could achieve by investing the option premiums, those potential earnings are explicitly accounted for in the Black-Scholes model through the inclusion of the longterm risk-free rate in the model. Consequently, when Mr. Buffett speaks of the deficiencies of the model, he could not be referring to the failure to adequately account for the time value of money. It should be noted, however, that a long-horizon makes estimated option values highly sensitive to the choice of the risk-free rate and the associated inflation rate that underlies it. For example, if the risk-free rate is dropped to 3.8% the estimated value of Mr. Buffett s hypothetical option position rises almost fivefold to $11.1 million, whereas if the rate is increased to 5.8% the estimated value falls by more than a factor of five to only $0.45 million. Nonetheless, Mr. Buffett does not appear to be arguing that the source of the mispricing is the failure to use a proper risk-free rate. The problem must lie elsewhere. - 4 -

The estimated value of long dated puts is also highly sensitive to the choice of the dividend yield. Here, however, it is hard to quarrel with the choice of 3% because it represents both the approximate current yield on the S&P 500 and, serendipitously, the long-term average yield. Furthermore, Mr. Buffett does not claim in his letter that the failings of the model are somehow tied to use of an improper dividend yield. The final factor to consider, other than the form of the model itself, is the longterm volatility. To review, the standard Black-Scholes model assumes that returns follow a lognormal diffusion. This implies that the time T distribution of the stock price, or index, is given by 1 Ln S T ~ Normal [Ln S 0 + ( 2 /2)*T, 2 *T]. (1) In equation (1), S 0 is the current stock price, S T is the stock price at the date of expiration, T, is the drift which equals the expected return on the index minus the dividend yield, and is the volatility. To apply equation (1) an estimate of is required. Without reliving the extensive debate on the equity risk premium, the risk-free rate is selected as an estimate of for. 2 This implies that the equity premium equals the dividend yield. Given this assumption, in addition to those previously discussed, equation (1) implies that the probability that S T will be less than S 0 100 years hence comes to about 4%, a number greater than the 1% probability that Mr. Buffet claims is much too large. This means that Buffett has two 1 See, for example, Hull (2009) 2 See, for example, Cornell (1999). - 5 -

possible beefs. First, the equity premium, and therefore, the drift should be larger. Second, something is wrong with the volatility. The culprit is unlikely to be the drift. Although variation in the drift does impact the probability that the index will be below its initial level at expiration, it does not affect the estimate of value produced by the Black-Scholes model. Because Mr. Buffett s ultimate view is that the model overvalues the puts, his main criticism cannot be based to any meaningful extent on the drift term. The final candidate, other than the arbitrage argument on which the model is based, is the volatility. If Mr. Buffett is criticizing the use of the lognormal diffusion assumption when pricing long-term options, he is not alone. Recall that the lognormal assumption implies that volatility increases linearly with respect to the horizon over which it is measured as shown in equation (1). There is empirical evidence which indicates that the linearity assumption fails to hold at long horizons. For example, Siegel (2008) reports that the variance of real returns on the S&P 500 historically have failed to rise linearly with the horizon. If the long-run volatility is lower, the value of long-term put options will be less. For instance, a volatility of 15%, instead of 18%, reduces the estimated value of Mr. Buffett s hypothetical put position to $1.5 million. It also reduces the probability that the index will be lower at expiration than at initiation. The assumption that volatility fails to rise linearly with the horizon of which it is measured is not without controversy. First, the reduction that Siegel points to is less true of nominal returns than real returns. Whereas Siegel (2008) reports that historical volatility at 20-year horizons is about 25% below the prediction of the lognormal diffusion model for real returns, the number using nominal returns is less than 12%. In - 6 -

addition, the conclusion is sample dependent. At horizons of 10 years the lognormal model essentially matches the historical data. Furthermore, some scholars, including Pastor and Stambaugh (2009), argue that return volatility as a function of the horizon may actually increase more than the lognormal assumption predicts. In any event, the evidence regarding the volatility of nominal returns over the long run is not strong enough to support Mr. Buffett s contention that the Black-Scholes model produces absurd results. He must have had something else in mind. It is unlikely that Mr. Buffett put billions of dollars of Berkshire s capital at risk on the basis of an academic debate regarding the historical estimation of stock price volatility. More fundamentally, the debate over historical estimation of volatility is ultimately irrelevant because the model requires an estimate of future volatility. The Black-Scholes model will produce absurd results if it is based historical estimates of volatility that have become outdated. It is here, I believe, that Mr. Buffett parts ways with the application of the Black-Scholes model on which Berkshire s mark-to-market accounting is based. As Mr. Buffett notes, the value of long-dated put options is derived from the extreme right hand tail of the distribution of outcomes for which the ending index value is less than the strike price. Historically, this has been the result of a combination of two factors negative real stock returns and falling prices. For example, the worst period in the history of the American stock market was from 1929 through 1932 when real returns fell and there was significant deflation making nominal returns even more negative. The value of long-dated puts is based on the likelihood that such events will occur again with a likelihood that is determined largely by the volatility parameter. The key question, - 7 -

therefore, is whether the assumption of lognormal diffusion assumption accurately approximates the likelihood of such recurrences. Clues elsewhere in his letter suggest that Mr. Buffett believes that it does not. Early on in his letter, Mr. Buffett observes, with respect to the current economic crisis, that This debilitating spiral has spurred our government to take massive action. In poker terms, the Treasury and the Fed have gone all in. Economic medicine that was previously meted out by the cupful has recently been dispensed by the barrel. These once-unthinkable dosages will almost certainly bring on unwelcome aftereffects. Their precise nature is anyone s guess, though one likely consequence is an onslaught of inflation. Mr. Buffett s observations regarding response of the government to the current crisis suggest that he believes a repeat of the 1930s is not possible. The reason being that governments will respond strongly and aggressively to prevent downturns, even deep downturns, from turning into deflationary spirals by providing whatever liquidity is needed to halt deflation. If this is so, then the assumption that nominal stock returns follow a lognormal diffusion over the long term with a volatility that can be estimated from historical data is not realistic. Instead, the lower tail of the probability distribution will be impacted by something akin to a soft reflecting barrier induced by the inflationary reactions of governments and central banks to economic crises. Cornell, Cvitanic and Goukasian (2009) show that the existence of such limitations on possible stock price paths, compared with the assumption of a lognormal diffusion, has a significant impact on option prices. In this case, the impact of inflationary government responses would be - 8 -

to markedly reduce the estimated value of long-dated put options. Depending on the aggressiveness of the governmental response to potential deflation, the values for longdated puts given by the standard Black-Scholes model using historical volatility can turn out to be absurdly high as Mr. Buffett asserts. There is one final clue that supports the foregoing interpretation of Mr. Buffett s investment in long-dated index puts. Remember that Mr. Buffett states that if the formula is applied to extended time periods, however, it can produce absurd results. This implies that over shorter time intervals Mr. Buffett believes that the formula yields more reasonable results. Such reasoning is consistent with the political economics interpretation of Mr. Buffett s critique presented previously. During normal times, when aggressive injection of liquidity is not required, the lognormal approximation is reasonable. Where it breaks down is near the left-hand tail when extensive government intervention is required to prevent deflation. But it is precisely that tail from which longdated puts derive their value. In the short-run, the probability of reaching the tail is too small to be meaningful. But if volatility grows linearly with time, eventually the lefthand tail becomes important. Government policies which cut off that tail, therefore, have a dramatic impact on the value of long-dated puts but have little impact on short-dated contracts except possibly during times of crisis. In conclusion, although Mr. Buffett s critique of the Black-Scholes model might appear to be another attack on geeks bearing formulas, it is better seen as a statement about the changing nature of America s political economy. If threat of severe recession and deflation cause governments to respond with massive injections of liquidity, then naïve application of the Black-Scholes model will produce absurd results for long-dated - 9 -

options if it is based on standard assumptions and historical data. The problem, however, is not the theory on which the model is based, but that government intervention implies that the long-run distribution of returns will not be lognormal. In particular, the lefthand tail will be truncated, sharply reducing the value of long-dated put options. If this is so, Mr. Buffett has made another wise investment even if his rationalization of it somewhat misses the mark. II. Conclusion In his 2008 letter to Berkshire shareholders, Warren Buffett criticizes the Black- Scholes option pricing model arguing that it can produce absurd values for long-dated put options. Though Mr. Buffett does not explicitly say so, a careful analysis of his viewpoint reveals that his criticism boils down to the belief that future nominal stock prices are not well approximated by a lognormal distribution with a volatility estimated from historical data. Instead, Mr. Buffett apparently believes that inflationary policies of governments and central banks will limit future declines in nominal stock prices compared with those predicted by an historically estimated lognormal distribution. If Mr. Buffett is right on this point, then the Black-Scholes model will indeed significantly overvalue long-dated put options. - 10 -

REFERENCES Buffett, Warren., 2009, Letter to the Shareholders of Berkshire Hathaway, http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/letters/2008ltr.pdf. Cornell, Bradford, 1999, The Equity Risk Premium and the Long-run Future of the Stock Market. John Wiley and Sons, New York, NY. Cornell, Bradford, Jaksa Cvitanic and Levon Goukasian, 2009, Beliefs regarding fundamental value and optimal investing, unpublished working paper, California Institute of Technology. Hull, John C., 2009, Options, Futures and Other Derivative Securities, Seventh Edition, Prentice-Hall, New York. Pastor, Lubos and Robert F. Stambaugh, 2009, Are stocks really less volatile in the long run?, unpublished working paper, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago. Siegel, Jeremy, 2008, Stocks for the Long Run, McGraw-Hill, New York. - 11 -