Prices to Devices: Price Responsive Devices and the Smart Grid



Similar documents
Before the Department of Energy Washington, D.C Smart Grid RFI: Addressing Policy and Logistical Challenges

Energy Efficiency and Demand Response Programs in the United States

Southern California Edison Implementing the Communications and Back Office Systems of a Large Scale Metering Project

Executive Summary... ii. 1. Introduction Purpose and Scope Organization of this Report... 3

Integration of Electric Vehicles National Town Meeting on Demand Response + Smart Grid May 28, 2015

ENERGY ADVISORY COMMITTEE. Electricity Market Review : Electricity Tariff

Realising the benefits of smart meters for consumers and industry

What is the Impact of Utility Demand Charges on a DCFC Host?

WHITEPAPER. Breathing New Life Into Legacy Demand Response. Gain the Benefits of Two-way Communications

Creating a Robust Market for Residential Energy Management through an Open Energy Management Architecture

Managing Electrical Demand through Difficult Periods: California s Experience with Demand Response

SDG&E and Its Illustrative Rate Summary Form

Rule change request. 18 September 2013

Moving Toward Utility-Scale Deployment of Dynamic Pricing in Mass Markets

Schedule OLM-AS OPTIONAL LOAD MANAGEMENT AND AUTOMATION SERVICES RIDER

Enabling 24/7 Automated Demand Response and the Smart Grid using Dynamic Forward Price Offers

Net Energy Metering and the Future of Distributed Generation

Demand Response, Dynamic Pricing, and the Smart Grid in New York

The smart grid and the promise of demand-side management

Demand Response Management System ABB Smart Grid solution for demand response programs, distributed energy management and commercial operations

Demand Response in the Pacific Northwest

Understanding Network Tariff Reform

Updated SCER Demand Side Participation Program December 2013

The Virtual Power Station - achieving dispatchable generation from small scale solar

Southern California Plug-in Electric Vehicle Readiness Plan. Prepared for the Southern California Association of Governments

Demand Response in Capacity and Electricity Markets: What Role Can and Should It Play?

Energy Management. Electric Procurement Strategies. August 27, 2007

Electricity Demand Response

MARKETING AGENCY RFP: CREATIVE PITCH BRIEF

The Smart Energy Pricing Evolution at BGE

BEFORE THE PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION OF THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

SEC STATEMENT OF POLICY ON MODERNIZATION OF ELECTRICITY GRID.

Optimization of Energy and Water Quality Management Systems for Drinking Water Utilities [Project #4271]

Demand Response Programs

Before the Department of Energy Washington, D.C ) ) ) ) ) ) NBP RFI: Data Access, Third Party Use, and Privacy

SEP 2014 OCT 2014 DEC 2014 NOV 2014 HOEP*

Customer Service Business Unit Tariff Programs & Services. Leading the Way in Electricity TM

DEMAND RESPONSE EMERGING TECHNOLOGIES PROGRAM SEMI-ANNUAL REPORT 2013

Australian Energy Market Commission

Energy Efficiency and Automated Demand Response Program Integration: Time for a Paradigm Shift

PREPARED REBUTTAL TESTIMONY OF CHRIS YUNKER CHAPTER 1 ON BEHALF OF SAN DIEGO GAS & ELECTRIC COMPANY. December 12, 2014

HOUSEHOLD SMART METERS DEVELOPING A DEMAND-SIDE

An Oracle White Paper September Smart Grids: Strategic Planning and Development

Efficient Retail Pricing in Electricity and Natural Gas Markets

SECTION 5.15 ELECTRICITY AND NATURAL GAS

Increasing Demand Response in Maine

KANSAS CORPORATION COMMISSION IP-to-IP Interconnection Report

Department of Water and Power City of Los Angeles PROPOSED RATE RESTRUCTURING

Introduction. Along with consulting, I previously. developing regulatory policy initiatives

Executive insights. Shifting the Load: Using Demand Management to Cut Asia's Eletricity Bill. Shifting Load Away from Peak Times

National Smart Meter Programme. Time of Use Tariffs Mandate CER/13/152 Consultation Paper Response

AMI and DA Convergence: Enabling Energy Savings through Voltage Conservation

Naperville Smart Grid Initiative

APPENDIX E ARCHITECTURE COMPONENT/ACTOR DESCRIPTIONS

The NES Smart Metering System. The World s Most Advanced Metering System Solution for the Smart Grid

Demand Response CPUC Filing San Diego Gas & Electric Company. All copyright and trademark rights reserved.

BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

NEW COMMERCIAL Rates. Understanding the. Commercial Customers

Clean Energy Council submission to Queensland Competition Authority Regulated Retail Electricity Prices for Interim Consultation Paper

SIERRA PACIFIC POWER COMPANY dba NV Energy 6100 Neil Road Reno, NV Tariff No. Electric No. 1

Demand Response Management System Smart systems for Consumer engagement By Vikram Gandotra Siemens Smart Grid

The Smart Grid: Utility Master Energy & Sustainability Planning

Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory

NARUC. The Smart Grid: Frequently Asked Questions for State Commissions. The National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners

SAMPLE. Smart Grid Customer Engagement Success Stories

IDENTIFYING PATHS TO SUCCESS: LEARNINGS ON BARRIERS AND DRIVERS TO DEMAND RESPONSE PROGRAM

The Impact of Dynamic Pricing on Low Income Customers

Economic Concepts for Pricing Electricity Network Services A Report for the Australian Energy Market Commission

Draft for comment - OpenADR 2.0 Demand Response Program Guide

Business Energy Efficiency. Webinar August 29, 2012

ELECTRICITY DEMAND SIDE MEASURES

ELECTRIC SCHEDULE E-6 Sheet 1 RESIDENTIAL TIME-OF-USE SERVICE

Program Overview. Free intelligent thermostat and gateway device ($150 - $200 value)

The Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) manages the flow of electric power to approximately 22 million Texas customers representing 85

INDEPENDENT SYSTEM OPERATORS (VI + Access Rules vs. ISO vs. ITSO)

The Effects of Critical Peak Pricing for Commercial and Industrial Customers for the Kansas Corporation Commission Final Report

How does a multi-purpose. network compare to load. management alternatives?

1. Summary. electric grid, strengthen saving programs sponsored by utilities. The project

More MDM Choices: A Hosted MDMS

I. GENERAL FUNCTIONING OF THE RETAIL MARKET AND CONSUMER PARTICIPATION

European Distribution System Operators for Smart Grids. Position paper on Electric Vehicles Charging Infrastructure

Before the UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF ENERGY Office of Electricity Delivery and Energy Reliability 75 FR 57006

SCE s Transactive Energy Demonstration Project. GWAC Workshop Bob Yinger December 10-11, 2013

Western Australian Feed-In Tariff Discussion Paper

REPORT ON EFFORTS TO REDUCE ELECTRIC PEAK DEMAND

An Oracle White Paper May Smart Grid Basics. Turning Information into Power

WHITE PAPER THE NIAGARA FRAMEWORK A PLATFORM FOR DEMAND RESPONSE

Green Power Accounting Workshop: Concept Note For discussion during Green Power Accounting Workshop in Mexico City, May 13th 2011

Short-Term Forecasting in Retail Energy Markets

Review of Salt River Project s Proposed Residential Customer Generation Price Plan. Prepared for Salt River Project

1 Descriptions of Function

SMART ENERGY IN-HOME DISPLAY USER MANUAL

Low Carbon Networks Fund Screening Submission Pro-forma

Dynamic Electricity Pricing in California: Do Customers Respond?

The Power Market: E-Commerce for All Electricity Products By Edward G. Cazalet, Ph.D., and Ralph D. Samuelson, Ph.D.

NetVision. NetVision: Smart Energy Smart Grids and Smart Meters - Towards Smarter Energy Management. Solution Datasheet

ELECTRIC SCHEDULE E-9 EXPERIMENTAL RESIDENTIAL TIME-OF-USE SERVICE FOR LOW EMISSION VEHICLE CUSTOMERS

Firm Uses Internet Service Bus to Enable Smart Grid for Dynamic Energy Savings

Glossary of Terms Avoided Cost - Backfeed - Backup Generator - Backup Power - Base Rate or Fixed Charge Baseload Generation (Baseload Plant) -

Transcription:

Responsive Devices and Ivan O Neill Contents 1. Executive Summary 2. Background 3. Nominal and Relative Information 4. Types of Price Signals 5. Control-Like Effects on Device Behavior of Price Signals 6. Requirements to Enable a National Plug-and-Play Market for HAN Devices Capable of Price Responsiveness 7. Implications 8. Appendix 9. References

1. Executive Summary The Smart Grid promises to improve the quality, resiliency, and integrity of the grid through the optimization of the existing energy delivery infrastructure and integration of new renewable generation sources. A primary element of the Smart Grid is the enhanced communications capabilities that enable consumers to better manage their electricity consumption and costs via new smart appliances and devices located at the customer s premises. These are commonly referred to as Home Area Network (HAN) devices. As Smart Grid communications systems open new opportunities for consumer participation, a variety of HAN stakeholders are defining the format and types of messages and signals that will facilitate energy awareness and empower consumers. Most important are the data signals that provide price information. Numerous studies have confirmed that consumers prefer energy information quantified in monetary terms rather than electrical terms like kilowatt-hours. However, while a nominal price signal of $0.13 per kilowatt hour (kwh) is useful for consumers, additional information is required to enable new price responsive devices that modify their behavior automatically in response to higher or lower prices. Price responsive devices are important because they offer their owners convenient and user-friendly management of energy use in a future where the retail price of electricity will more closely reflect the actual economic cost as it varies throughout the day. Price responsive devices require slightly different price signals than nominal price signals; they require relative price signals that use metrics such as high, medium, and low to convey the context of the nominal price and drive action. This white paper will inform HAN stakeholders of Southern California Edison s HAN research and development work in concert with HAN device suppliers to develop price responsive devices. The intent of this paper is to: Define the types of price signals (e.g., nominal and relative); Review the methods for determining relative price signals; Southern California Edison 2010 1

Highlight the regulatory and policy requirements for establishing a national market for HAN devices; Discuss the technical and behavioral implications of providing price signals; and Inform ongoing Smart Grid policy and standards discussions in the United States at the federal and state levels. Based on SCE s work with a variety of industry partners, SCE makes the following recommendations: Relative price signals benefit HAN devices capable of price responsiveness; Relative price signals enable national and international markets for price responsive HAN devices and can accommodate the wide variety of retail electricity rate structures; Price signals must be authenticated due to the control-like effects they have on price responsive HAN devices; Relative price signals should be simple and clear so they are actionable by cost-constrained HAN devices and understandable by consumers; and Default time-differentiated rates are needed in order to create a sustainable market for price responsive HAN devices like smart appliances. Southern California Edison 2010 2

2. Background Southern California Edison (SCE) and a number of utilities and service providers are deploying Home Area Networks (HAN) to empower their customers to make more informed energy decisions. The use of consumer devices will help them to access a variety of information from their utility and/or electric service provider. A recent survey by The Brattle Group shows that consumers with energy displays conserve an average of 4.3 percent on their energy use. 1 Other research shows consumers do not readily understand kilowatt-hours and strongly prefer price information (e.g., $/hr). 2 Since 2008, SCE has actively collaborated with manufacturers of programmable communicating thermostats (PCTs), in-premise displays, energy management systems (EMSes), plug-in electric vehicles, smart appliances, and other emerging technologies and applications to validate and demonstrate standardsbased methods for communicating price information using the Smart Energy Profile (SEP). 3 Price signals enable HAN applications to inform consumers about electricity pricing and could allow them to automatically adjust their energy use to conserve during high price periods or when a bill is projected to be higher than a budgeted amount defined by the customer. Communicating pricing information is viewed as a critical component to enabling a successful HAN. However, price information can take several different forms and has a variety of contexts and uses. Some in the field support a concept called prices-to-devices, wherein HAN devices are provided with a retail price for electricity, sometimes as frequently as every hour or fifteen minutes (i.e., hourly or so-called real-time pricing ). As HAN technology evolves, a number of stakeholders have proposed requirements, rules, mandates, and/or guidelines on the types of information protocols HAN providers should follow. Some of the entities promulgating standards include various state utility commissions, the National Institutes of Standards and Technology (NIST), the Association of Home Appliance Manufacturers (AHAM), and OpenSG (part of the International Electrotechnical Commission). Southern California Edison 2010 3

3. Nominal and Relative Information Before discussing price signals, it is helpful to illustrate the differences between nominal and relative information using a familiar example. Motorists in many parts of the United States are familiar with highway information signs that are routinely updated during high traffic periods with estimated travel times to various destinations [Figure 1]. Note that while this nominal information has value to drivers, unless an individual drives this route frequently, one would not know if the 23-minute travel time to San Francisco airport (SFO) was a shorter, average, or longer travel time for that particular time of day; therefore, the driver would not know whether to choose an alternate route or to continue with the planned route. The motorist simply knows how long the rest of the drive should take and the impact it could have on his or her plans. Figure 1 Example of Nominal Travel Time Information (Photo: John Huseby/Caltrans) The missing element for a driver unfamiliar with the area is context. Only with context do nominal signals transform into relative signals capable of driving action and useful in decision-making. Continuing the traffic analogy, Southern Southern California Edison 2010 4

California has an extensive network of highway sensors. Various service providers aggregate this information and synthesize the thousands of readings into relative information useful to consumers. SigAlert.com is one such service provider. It applies relative signals (i.e., colors) to nominal traffic readings to provide users with the ability to put their route options in context [Figure 2]. Figure 2 Example of Relative Travel Time Information (Photo: SigAlert.com) Color coding provides quick, at-a-glance guidance with its red, orange, yellow, and green color scheme, each of which corresponds to an average speed reading. In this way, drivers are empowered to choose the quickest route and modify their driving behavior, which has the aggregate effect of easing traffic congestion. SCE proposes using similar methods to advise stakeholder community on ways to facilitate the creation of a national market of HAN devices capable of price responsiveness. 4. Types of Price Signals Both nominal and relative price signals are distinct from rate structures, which employ various strategies to accomplish perceived values of fairness or other policy goals. Price signals can be communicated regardless of the rate structure a consumer chooses. The Appendix provides examples of some rate structures Southern California Edison 2010 5

and a more detailed discussion of how price signals can be used in conjunction with rate structures. 4.1 Nominal Price Signals The nominal price signal is generally the actual retail economic price of electricity expressed in terms of currency ($0.13/kWh). Nominal prices vary widely across the United States depending on the electricity generation method and various rate structures determined by public utility or service commissions and oversight agencies. 4.2 Relative Price Signals Relative price signals attempt to translate peak electric system conditions in a way that provides consumers with objective information on the economic scarcity of electricity specific to that geographic area or sub-system of the electric grid (e.g., ISO/RTO area, utility service territory, circuit, or substation). In order to understand the relative price of a commodity, one needs to know the overall number of relative price levels in the scale and the currently active relative price level. There are three general methods for obtaining relative price information: Manual programming Learning algorithms Trusted-source 4.2.1 Manual Programming In this method, a device is programmed by a user with the information required to determine how relatively high or low the nominal price signals are that it could receive. This typically involves a comparatively sophisticated user interface with a calendar or some other scheduling mechanism for the user to program the device. Manual methods have drawbacks as many devices like refrigerators do not typically have human-machine interfaces capable of supporting detailed user Southern California Edison 2010 6

programming. It also requires additional effort by the consumer to become informed and adept at configuring his or her device. Consumer research on devices requiring detailed user programming like VCRs and early generations of programmable thermostats demonstrates that this can be a barrier to their widespread adoption and use. Although service providers could program the rate structures into the devices, this is impractical for mass markets. Doing so requires configuring and managing millions of devices, puts bandwidth constraints on some communication systems, and imposes more costly memory storage capabilities on devices. The inherent difficulty and inconvenience of manual programming makes it unlikely to scale to a mass market. 4.2.2 Learning Algorithms Over time, a device with a learning algorithm could build a historical model of nominal price signals received and derive its own definition of relativity on which to base its behavior. This has the advantage of being invisible to the consumer and flexible across a variety of national prices. However, the technical requirements for designing appliances with adaptive logic to learn rate structures over time are likely to be unfeasible or unreliable when one considers the constrained platforms and cost implications of embedded devices common in a HAN like PCTs, pool pumps, and smart appliances. This would be compounded when rate structures and underlying prices change based on seasonal variations, as many rate structures do. While learning algorithms may have successful applications in more sophisticated devices like energy management systems (EMSes), SCE does not believe learning algorithms are a viable option for mass market residential devices where up-front device costs drive purchasing decisions. Even with a sophisticated EMS, the devices it controls will be simple devices that require a relative price signal. In other words, the EMS proxies the price to the other HAN devices and becomes the trusted source described below. Southern California Edison 2010 7

4.2.3 Trusted Source SCE believes the trusted source method is the most appropriate method of communicating relative price signals for the mass market adoption of HAN devices presently being developed to take advantage of. In the traffic analogy, users of the SigAlert traffic service trust it to accurately calculate the nominal speed readings (e.g., 30 mph) obtained from the sensor network and simplify it into an easily understood relative signal (e.g., yellow) for the driver. Under the trusted source method of communicating price signals, an entity would similarly transmit a relative price signal based on the active nominal price. To accomplish this, the trusted source defines a scale with a number of relative levels and provides the current active level. Table 1 provides an example of a 24-hour schedule for electricity with four relative tiers. Time (24-hr) Nominal Price Active Relative Price Level Total Number of Relative Price Levels 00.00 10.59 $0.11 / kwh 1 4 11.00 14.59 $0.25 / kwh 3 4 15.00 17.59 $0.40 / kwh 4 4 18.00 19.59 $0.19 / kwh 2 4 20.00 23.59 $0.11 / kwh 1 4 Table 1 A 24-hour example of relative price levels Note that higher relative levels signal peak electricity system conditions. With active relative price level and total number of price levels, a HAN device can easily and readily understand the higher cost of the current operating period and change its behavior. This has the advantage of working within the processing constraints of embedded consumer devices and across a wide range of electricity prices throughout the world. The trusted source could theoretically be any source the consumer trusts. In practice, it is likely to be the electric service provider, utility, regional transmission operator (RTO), independent system operator (ISO), or a trusted third party who obtains the data from one of the aforementioned sources. The definition of relative price levels must be done in a transparent manner and facilitated by Southern California Edison 2010 8

regulatory agencies. Energy service providers under different regulatory regimes have different incentives when it comes to providing transparent information that could drive energy conservation or peak load shifting. Whatever the source of the signals, they must be transparent and free of perceptions of gaming by the source to the detriment of consumers. Failure to do so would erode public support for. 5. Control-Like Effects on Device Behavior of Price Signals In a connected world where consumer devices can be programmed to respond to price signals and automatically adjust their behavior, price signals assume control-like characteristics similar to demand response or load control signals. For example, electric utility customers enrolled in a time-of-use (TOU) rate plan, in which they pay varying prices for electricity used at different times, may preset their appliances to minimize usage during higher cost, on-peak periods and defer operation to lower cost, off-peak periods. A device s default response settings can be pre-programmed by the manufacturer for user convenience and to allow devices with unsophisticated user interfaces to have some response capability. For example, a refrigerator might disable its ice maker and suspend the defrost cycle during higher cost periods. In this way, price responsiveness serves as a softer form of demand response that avoids the prescriptive nature of direct load control and allows consumer preferences to drive consumption behavior. Consumers would be free to modify the factory default settings or override responses according to their preferences, but the default options provide convenient, out-of-box consumer benefits. For further discussion of price response strategies and appliances, see the Association of Home Appliance Manufacturer s (AHAM) Smart Grid White Paper published December 2009, pages 8-9. Southern California Edison 2010 9

6. Requirements to Enable a National Plug-and-Play Market for HAN Devices Capable of Price Responsiveness In order for consumer devices to easily respond to the variety of price signals and utility rate structures represented across the country, they must be able to determine how relatively expensive or inexpensive a nominal price is, in the range of possible prices for that consumer s rate plan (i.e., they need a method to determine the relative price). For example, a nominal price of $0.13/kWh is considered low for California, but high for Kansas. AHAM has developed several requirements for enabling a reliable and consumer-friendly HAN that scales nationally or internationally: Clear standards are required to describe dynamic pricing information across the United States. A fragmented system of tariff structures across the more than 3,000 utilities would present an impediment to the interstate commerce and use of consumer products. The pricing structure must allow manufacturers to build devices or appliances that are capable of managing this benefit and provide consumers with the proper incentives. The consumer must be able to easily set rules defining their preferences to govern their usage of electricity in the home. 4 Relative price signals demonstrate their versatility when the out-of-the-box appliance is capable of responding to the variety of rate and price structures in the United States without customization or extensive configuration by the consumer. While it is unlikely that the wide variety of retail electricity rate structures will be standardized in the near term, relative price signals offer a readily available solution for communicating price signals that are not specific to a particular electricity rate structure. Southern California Edison 2010 10

7. Implications Based on SCE s experience in developing HAN-enabled appliances and devices with partners, SCE believes there are important implications for device manufacturers, service providers, policy-makers, and regulatory organizations to consider when designing and implementing. 7.1 Nominal Price Signals Are Not Enough Informing consumers of their real-time cost of electricity (i.e., Price multiplied by Usage) requires nominal price signals to provide energy consumption information in monetary terms that consumers understand and use to manage their energy use. However, enabling convenient management of HAN devices and driving price responsiveness requires methods that inform the appliance or device of the relative price. The easiest and least complicated method to achieve this is by providing relative signals from a trusted source. 7.2 Price Signals Require Authentication Because price signals will likely have control-like effects on the behavior of consumer devices, careful consideration should be given to the public broadcast of price signals. Unsecured price broadcasts in which devices do not have an authenticated source for price information could lead to spoofing of price signals and nefarious or malicious behavior against consumers HANs. The consumer backlash this could create would be a significant setback to achieving the nation s Smart Grid policy goals. To prevent this, policy makers must ensure an authenticated link with the price signal provider, which can typically be accomplished through a unique customer passcode (e.g., pre-shared key similar to how broadband service providers configure modems with embedded wireless routers) or registration of the client device with the price provider using certificates. HAN security has been thoroughly investigated and documented by a variety of Smart Grid industry groups like the OpenSG Users Group s AMI Security Task Force and NIST. Southern California Edison 2010 11

7.3 Keep It Simple: Devices Can Only Do So Much For most residential users, the concept of prices-to-devices (i.e., nominal retail prices provided directly to devices) without a way to determine the relative price level is not particularly meaningful for achieving price responsiveness in devices. Consistent with the law of diminishing returns in other fields, there are limits to how much appliances can change their behavior in response to a relative price signal. Beyond three or four total relative price levels, additional relative price levels do not provide substantial consumption reduction or load shifting for most residential applications. Complexity increases uncertainty and consumer resistance to the changes enabled by. Electric service providers and their oversight commissions should carefully consider the structure of the rates they design and consider how devices would interpret them. 7.4 Time-of-Use Delta Is Crucial to the Consumer Value Proposition Beyond event-specific demand response programs, the value proposition of smart appliances and other devices depends on the underlying rate structures. The greater the difference between the on-peak and off-peak prices, the greater the value proposition to the consumer purchasing a price responsive smart appliance. The duration of the on-peak period also has a strong effect on the payback period of the upfront premium of the smart appliance. Upfront rebate incentives also play a role, but ongoing operational incentives require TOU rates or other strategies (e.g., in the case of relative but no nominal price) that pay down the upfront cost of enabling communications in smart appliances. 7.5 Smart Grid-Compatible Devices Require Smart Grid-Compatible Policies and Rate Structures Today s rate structures are not, for the most part, Smart Grid-compatible. SCE is not the first to point out that time-differentiated rates are required to maximize the societal benefit of HANs and. This is an important point for regulators and policy-makers who seek to encourage the adoption of price responsive HAN devices. In the absence of default time-differentiated rates, it is unlikely that consumers will see the value in paying for the additional costs Southern California Edison 2010 12

involved in making an appliance smart. Consumers buying smart appliances for the green factor will not sustain the market beyond the current generation of prototypes and field trials. 5 Most residential electricity consumers do not see the connection between the retail rate or tariff they are charged and the actual wholesale cost of electricity. This is because most retail electric rates are based on a flat rate where the volatility of the wholesale market cost is averaged on an annual basis to calculate electric rates for different customer segments. This rate design can also include social engineering mechanisms to achieve policy objectives. While relative price signals can be provided without nominal price signals, it is unclear why consumers would program their appliances to respond beyond their desire to promote societal good. Without some coupling of retail rates to wholesale prices, other incentive schemes will have to be developed. These are sure to be complex and present a consumer education challenge likely to lead to confusion and disillusionment with. Consideration should be given to creating simple rate structures that are understandable by consumers and actionable by HAN devices. Additionally, in situations where wholesale and retail electricity rates are not correlated, the potential for consumer confusion is high and could lead to increased complaints about perceived bill discrepancies. The implication of this section is that policy-makers and regulators must design rates that achieve the federal and state Smart Grid objectives and make sure they apply to a critical mass of the population. This will ensure the value proposition of HAN devices creates a sustainable retail market for price responsive devices and ultimately achieves the promise of. Southern California Edison 2010 13

8. Appendix 8.1 Rate Structure Examples 8.1.1 California s Tiered Schedule-D Rate Structure (Inclining Block Tariff) California s Investor Owned Utilities under the jurisdiction of the California Public Utilities Commission (CPUC) have a tiered rate structure for the vast majority of residential customers as outlined in Table 2. The more one uses, the more one pays: Tier Delivery Charge Generation Nominal Total Baseline Service $0.046 $0.133 $0.179 101% - 130% of Baseline $0.065 $0.133 $0.198 131% - 200% of Baseline $0.159 $0.133 $0.292 201% - 300% of Baseline $0.194 $0.133 $0.327 Over 300% of Baseline $0.229 $0.133 $0.362 Table 2 Typical California IOU Residential Tiered Rate Structure (all prices per kwh) California residential rates are structured to be higher for customers using greater amounts of electricity with the intent of changing energy consumption behaviors and driving conservation. The price one pays at the beginning of the billing period increases as consumption increases throughout the billing period. The baseline service calculation differs depending on which climate zone the customer s premises are located in and the season. California s higher use rate customers shoulder a greater share of the cost of providing service because under Assembly Bill 1-X, post-2001 rates are frozen for the first two tiers (baseline and 101-130 percent of baseline). Increased generation costs, such as those experienced in 2006-2008, and electric system improvements and expansion have been funded by customers in tiers three through five. California s rate structures present unique challenges for communicating prices to devices. Relative price signals via manual programming and learning algorithm methods are very complex because the nominal price changes are not Southern California Edison 2010 14

based on time, but on usage and geographic climate zone baseline allocation. California s TOU rate option is even more complex because it overlays an onand off-peak rate into the inclining tier structure shown in Table 2. 8.1.2 Time-of-Use Rate Structure TOU rates vary throughout the day at known intervals and provide a nominal price signal that typically reflects some measure of underlying wholesale market conditions. In most TOU schemes only the nominal price for that TOU interval is communicated to the device as illustrated in Table 3. Time (24-hr) Interval (not typically communicated to Price (per kwh) the device today) 00.00 10.59 Off-peak $0.13 11.00 13.59 Mid-peak $0.20 14.00 19.00 On-peak $0.30 19.00 23.59 Off-peak $0.13 Table 3 Time-of-Use Rate Structure Example While many utilities offer a TOU rate, customer apprehension and lack of awareness are barriers to widespread adoption. See Appendix Section 8.2 for additional discussion on how TOU and relative price signals can be effectively communicated to price responsive devices. 8.1.3 Real-Time or Hourly Price Rate Structure Real-time price rates attempt to more closely align the retail price an electricity consumer pays with the actual wholesale price of electricity. The assumption is that exposing consumers to the actual spot price leads to greater conservation of electricity during peak times by modifying behaviors so more energy is consumed off-peak. Generally, the rate price is not updated in real-time, instead it is communicated on a day-ahead basis with prices provided at least hourly - possibly every 15- minutes. Historically, RTP rates are only applied to sophisticated commercial Southern California Edison 2010 15

and industrial consumers capable of investing in the people and technologies to minimize their cost of electricity input to production. Time (24-hr) Nominal Price (per kwh) 00.00 00.59 $0.0134 01.00 01.59 $0.0301 10.00 10.59 $0.0928 11.00 11.59 $0.2059 14.00 14.59 $0.3523 15.00 15.59 $0.4219 16.00 16.59 $0.2264 21.00 21.59 $0.0876 22.00 22.59 $0.0410 23.00 23.59 $0.0223 Table 4 Real-Time Price Rate Structure Example 8.2 Rate Structure Examples Matched with Relative Price Signals 8.2.1 Time-of-Use Rates with Relative Price Signals TOU price signals imply that a nominal price for a given time period reflects relative system price conditions; however, enabling an effective national marketplace for smart devices and appliances requires utilizing an explicit relative price signal. HAN communication standards must be developed with this requirement in mind. Table 5 shows an example of the data attributes required. All attributes could be communicated to devices, but in order for relative price signals to be effective, both the active relative price level and total number of relative price levels must be communicated. Southern California Edison 2010 16

Time (24-hr) Interval (not communicated to devices) Nominal Price (per kwh) Active Relative Price Level Total Number of Relative Price Levels 00.00 10.59 Off-peak $0.13 1 3 11.00 13.59 Mid-peak $0.20 2 3 14.00 19.00 On-peak $0.30 3 3 19.00 23.59 Off-peak $0.13 1 3 Table 5 Time-of-Use Rate Structure with Relative Price Signals 8.2.2 Real-time Price Rate with Relative Price Signals Relative price signals can include real-time price structures as well. The price signal provider chooses a relatively small number of relative price tiers to map the hourly variations in nominal price. This can be based on established rules or definitions agreed upon by the appropriate stakeholders and regulatory bodies. An example is shown in Table 6: Time (24-hr) Nominal Price (per kwh) Active Relative Price Level Total Number of Relative Price Levels 00.00 00.59 $0.0134 1 4 01.00 01.59 $0.0301 1 4 10.00 10.59 $0.0928 2 4 11.00 11.59 $0.2059 3 4 14.00 14.59 $0.3523 4 4 15.00 15.59 $0.4219 4 4 16.00 16.59 $0.2264 3 4 21.00 21.59 $0.0876 2 4 22.00 22.59 $0.0410 1 4 23.00 23.59 $0.0223 1 4 Table 6 Hourly Real-Time Price Structure with Relative Price Signals (abridged) Southern California Edison 2010 17

9. References 1 Effects of In-Home Displays on Energy Consumption: A Summary of Pilot Results, The Brattle Group, Peak Load Management Alliance Webinar, 6 April 2010. 2 Anderson, Will and White, Vicki, The Smart Way to Display, Energy Saving Trust <http://www.energysavingtrust.org.uk/corporate/corporate-and-mediasite/library/publications-and-reports/the-smart-way-to-display> p26.nomi 3 http://www.zigbee.org/markets/zigbeesmartenergy/overview.aspx 4 AHAM Smart Grid White Paper, December 2009, p10. 5 Mert, Wilma, et al., Consumer Acceptance of Smart Appliances, Smart Domestic Appliances in Sustainable Energy Systems (Smart-A), December 2008 <http://smart-a.org/wp5_5_consumer_acceptance_18_12_08.pdf>. Southern California Edison 2010 18