Robin Greenwood and Dimitri Vayanos Price pressure in the government bond market



Similar documents
Yield Curve September 2004

Research. What Impact Will Ballooning Government Debt Levels Have on Government Bond Yields?

Understanding Fixed Income

nderlying_data.pdf

Principles and Trade-Offs when Making Issuance Choices in the UK

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Use of fixed income products within a company's portfolio

This document introduces the principles behind LDI, how LDI strategies work and how to decide on an appropriate approach for your pension scheme.

Chap 3 CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

STATEMENT 7: ASSET AND LIABILITY MANAGEMENT

Investment insight. Fixed income the what, when, where, why and how TABLE 1: DIFFERENT TYPES OF FIXED INCOME SECURITIES. What is fixed income?

LOCKING IN TREASURY RATES WITH TREASURY LOCKS

Understanding Fixed Income Returns: Past, Present and Future by Stephen Kroah,CFA

Learning Curve Interest Rate Futures Contracts Moorad Choudhry

CHAPTER 3 THE LOANABLE FUNDS MODEL

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

FLOW AND STOCK EFFECTS OF LARGE-SCALE TREASURY PURCHASES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

THE POTENTIAL MACROECONOMIC EFFECT OF DEBT CEILING BRINKMANSHIP

Hot Topics in Financial Markets Lecture 1: The Libor Scandal

The Collateral Damage of Today s Monetary Policies: Funding Long-Term Liabilities

Pioneer Bond Fund. Performance Analysis & Commentary September Fund Ticker Symbols: PIOBX (Class A); PICYX (Class Y) us.pioneerinvestments.

The Impact of Interest Rates on Real Estate Securities

The Case for a Custom Fixed Income Benchmark. ssga.com/definedcontribution REFINING THE AGG

Recovery plans. Assumptions and triggers

Risk and Return in the Canadian Bond Market

Redefining Risk in Fixed Income

Fixed Income 2015 Update. Kathy Jones, Senior Vice President Chief Fixed Income Strategist, Schwab Center for Financial Research

Fixed Income Arbitrage

Rethinking Fixed Income

Why ECB QE is Negative for Commodities. Investment Research & Advisory. Deltec International Group

CREATING A CORPORATE BOND SPOT YIELD CURVE FOR PENSION DISCOUNTING DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF ECONOMIC POLICY WHITE PAPER FEBRUARY 7, 2005

The recent volatility of high-yield bonds: Spreads widen though fundamentals stay strong

Money Market. The money market is the market for low-risk, short-term debt.

Part F. Reforms in Pensions and in the Taxation of the Capital Market. 1. The Pension Reform

MEASUREMENTS OF FAIR VALUE IN ILLIQUID (OR LESS LIQUID) MARKETS

When rates rise, do stocks fall?

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s

12.1 Introduction The MP Curve: Monetary Policy and the Interest Rates 1/24/2013. Monetary Policy and the Phillips Curve

How credit analysts view and use the financial statements

Diminished Liquidity in the Corporate Bond Market: Implications for Fixed Income Investors

Lecture 12/13 Bond Pricing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

FLOW AND STOCK EFFECTS OF LARGE-SCALE TREASURY PURCHASES

Seix Total Return Bond Fund

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

Answers to Review Questions

Banks Funding Costs and Lending Rates

Inverse Floaters and the Income Stability of a Debt Securities Investment Portfolio

High interest rates have contributed to a stronger currency

VALUATION OF PLAIN VANILLA INTEREST RATES SWAPS

Presented to the National Association of Insurance Commissioners Life Risk-Based Capital Working Group March 2001 Nashville, TN

The Master Statement of Investment Policies and Objectives of The Lower Colorado River Authority Retirement Plan and Trust. Amended June 16, 2015

GOVERNMENT DEBT MANAGEMENT AT THE ZERO LOWER BOUND

Rising Insurance Premiums: A New Impetus for Voluntary Funding of Corporate Defined Benefit Plans

Pricing and Strategy for Muni BMA Swaps

Current Issues. I n recent years, the U.S. Treasury Department has. Who Buys Treasury Securities at Auction? Michael J. Fleming

Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits

Fixed Income Liquidity in a Rising Rate Environment

STRIKING A BALANCE. How balanced funds help investors gain exposure to upside potential and mitigate downside risk

Federal Home Loan Bank of San Francisco Announces Second Quarter Operating Results

INFORMATION NOTE. The development of government bond market in Singapore

Oil Speculation by Jussi Keppo July 8, 2008

Bond investing in a rising rate environment

STATEMENT BY STEPHEN S. GARDNER, VICE CHAIRMAN BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM BEFORE THE

Long duration bond benchmarks for corporate pension plans

Chapter 4 Valuing Bonds

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 5 Mar 2016

Financial Markets and Institutions Abridged 10 th Edition

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

Session 6 Estimating a Liquidity Risk Premium from Fixed Income Yields. Ivor Krol

BERYL Credit Pulse on High Yield Corporates

PRESENT DISCOUNTED VALUE

What Investors Should Know about Money Market Reforms

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

EAST AYRSHIRE COUNCIL CABINET 21 OCTOBER 2009 TREASURY MANAGEMENT ANNUAL REPORT FOR 2008/2009 AND UPDATE ON 2009/10 STRATEGY

Rethinking fixed income. By Trevor t. Oliver

FIN 684 Fixed-Income Analysis From Repos to Monetary Policy. Funding Positions

Introduction to Equity Derivatives

Whither Oil Prices and Volatility?

Introduction. example of a AA curve appears at the end of this presentation.

Reg. no 2015/ September Central government debt management

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Changes to National Accounts: The Impact of the Changes to the Treatment of Pensions in the National Accounts

Making capital structure support strategy

Bond Market Insights July 15, 2015

Chapter 14. Money, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

The Effects of Funding Costs and Risk on Banks Lending Rates

FIN 683 Financial Institutions Management Interest-Rate Risk

Risk Control and Equity Upside: The Merits of Convertible Bonds for an Insurance Portfolio

MARATHON CLUB STATEMENT ISSUES REQUIRING CHANGES IN THE ACCOUNTING OF PENSION FUNDS

ALLOCATION STRATEGIES A, C, & I SHARES PROSPECTUS August 1, 2015

Gross Borrowing Requirements and Funding Plan

Using liability-driven investing to derisk corporate pension plans

Model for. Eleven factors to consider when evaluating bond holdings. Passage of time

ECON 4311: The Economy of Latin America. Debt Relief. Part 1: Early Initiatives

Chapter 17. Preview. Introduction. Fixed Exchange Rates and Foreign Exchange Intervention

3 MARKET RISK MANAGEMENT IN A LOW INTEREST RATE ENVIRONMENT

Term Structure of Interest Rates

Absolute return investments in rising interest rate environments

The package of measures to avoid artificial volatility and pro-cyclicality

Transcription:

Robin Greenwood and Dimitri Vayanos Price pressure in the government bond market Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Greenwood, Robin and Vayanos, Dimitri (2010) Price pressure in the government bond market. American economic review, 100 (2). pp. 585-590. ISSN 0002-8282 DOI: 10.1257/aer.100.2.585 2010 American Economic Association This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/28618/ Available in LSE Research Online: August 2010 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author s final manuscript accepted version of the journal article, incorporating any revisions agreed during the peer review process. Some differences between this version and the published version may remain. You are advised to consult the publisher s version if you wish to cite from it.

COVER PAGE Paper title: Price Pressure in the Government Bond Market First author: Robin Greenwood, Harvard Business School and NBER. Address: Harvard Business School, Baker Library 267, Soldiers Field, Boston MA 02116, USA, Tel: +1-617-495-6979, Fax: +1-617-496-8443, E-mail: rgreenwood@hbs.edu Second author: Dimitri Vayanos, London School of Economics, CEPR and NBER. Address: Department of Finance A350, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE, UK, Tel: +44-20-7723-7224, Fax: +44-20-7849-4647, E-mail: d.vayanos@lse.ac.uk Corresponding author: Dimitri Vayanos Session title: Demand and Supply for Government Bonds Session chair: Dimitri Vayanos Session discussants: Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh (New York University), Annette Vissing- Jorgensen (Northwestern University), Arvind Krishnamurthy (Northwestern University)

Price Pressure in the Government Bond Market Robin Greenwood and Dimitri Vayanos * January 2009 What determines the term structure of interest rates? Standard economic theory links the interest rate for maturity T to the willingness of a representative agent to substitute consumption between times 0 and T. The standard model contrasts sharply with a more informal view based on investors preferred habitat, proposed by John Culbertson (1957) and Franco Modigliani and Richard Sutch (1966). According to the preferred-habitat view, there are investor clienteles with preferences for specific maturities, and the interest rate for a given maturity is influenced by the demand of the corresponding clientele and the supply of bonds with that maturity. For example, the typical clientele for long-term bonds are pension funds. An increase in their demand would be expected to raise prices of long-term bonds and thus lower long-term interest rates. In short, preferred habitat implies that there is price pressure in the bond market. While the preferred-habitat view has intuitive appeal, it has not entered into the academic mainstream, typically being relegated to a paragraph in MBA-level textbooks. One reason for this is the mixed findings in early empirical studies of the term structure. Specifically, between 1962 and 1964, the US Treasury and Federal Reserve raised the supply of short-term government debt while simultaneously lowering the supply of long-term debt. This program, known as Operation Twist, aimed to raise short-term interest rates, and so improve the balance of payments, while also lowering long-term rates to stimulate private investment. A number of papers evaluated Operation Twist, and while they reached different conclusions, none found * Greenwood: Harvard Business School, Baker Library 267, Soldiers Field, Boston MA 02116, USA (email: rgreenwood@hbs.edu), and NBER; Vayanos: Department of Finance A350, London School of Economics, London WC2A 2AE, UK (email: d.vayanos@lse.ac.uk), CEPR and NBER. We are grateful to Michael Fleming, Joseph Gagnon, Kenneth Garbade, Moyeen Islam, Andrei Shleifer, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen for helpful comments. -1-

strong evidence that the operation was effective in flattening the term structure (e.g., Modigliani and Sutch (1966), Myron Ross (1966)). This lack of evidence reflected poorly on the preferredhabitat view, on which the success of the program was predicated. A second reason why the preferred-habitat view has not received much academic attention is theoretical. An extreme version of preferred habitat is that the interest rate for a given maturity evolves independently of other maturities. If interest rates for nearby maturities were very different, then arbitrageurs could realize unbounded profits by exploiting these differences (John Cox, Jonathan Ingersoll and Stephen Ross (1985)). In this paper we argue for the relevance of the preferred-habitat view by presenting two recent episodes that strongly support it: the UK pension reform of 2004, and the US Treasury s buyback program of 2000-2002. 1 Building on our other work (Robin Greenwood and Dimitri Vayanos (2010), Vayanos and Jean-Luc Vila (2009)), we then explain how these episodes can be understood within a modern theory of preferred habitat. We conclude by discussing the relevance of preferred habitat for central bank policies during the 2007-2009 financial crisis. In the episodes that we consider, long-term interest rates experienced large and long-lasting shifts because of a regulation-induced change in the demand of a long-maturity clientele in one case, and a government-induced change in the supply of long-term bonds in the other. Thus, a broader message of our analysis is that term-structure movements cannot always be understood in terms of changes in expected short-term interest rates, inflation or other macroeconomic variables, but that shifts to clientele demand and bond supply are also an important driver. I. The UK Pension Reform of 2004 1 Our account of the buyback episode draws on Kenneth Garbade and Matthew Rutherford (2007), who provide a general discussion of Treasury buybacks in historical context. -2-

Pension reform in the UK over the past twenty years evolved in two major stages. The first stage was motivated by the failure of a large corporate pension fund during the early 1990s. The Pensions Act of 1995 instituted minimum funding requirements, to ensure that pension plan members could be paid in full even if the sponsoring firm went bankrupt. The funding requirements coincided with accounting reforms that linked the valuation of pension liabilities to market-based discount rates. The combination of the funding requirements and the accounting change created demand for long-dated assets, lowering bond yields. Because this exposed weakness in many pension plans, the act was perceived as exerting undue influence on plans investment policy. At the behest of the pension industry, the regulations were ultimately abandoned in the early 2000s. We focus on the second stage of reform: the Pensions Act of 2004. This legislation created a government fund which would serve as a lifeboat for bankrupt schemes. At the same time, a new pensions regulator was given the power to take over funds that were perceived to be at risk of not meeting their obligations. One of the criteria used by the regulator to determine whether intervention was necessary was a plan s accounting deficit, the difference between the market values of a plan s assets and its liabilities. Because pension benefits were fixed and could be expected to grow with inflation, the present value of pension liabilities was linked to the price, and thus the prevailing yields, of long-term inflation-linked government bonds. Pension funds running an accounting deficit were said to be underfunded. The best hedge for pension liabilities is the asset providing the discount rate used to calculate the value of these liabilities. Thus, underfunded pension plans could reduce the volatility of the gap in value between their assets and liabilities by buying government bonds. The Pensions Act -3-

of 2004 instituted fines for underfunded pension plans, providing strong incentives to buy more long-term government bonds. Figure 1 shows that as a consequence of the reform, pension funds increased their exposure to long-term government bonds and reduced that to equities. Between the first quarter of 2005 and the last quarter of 2006, pension funds bought approximately 11 billion of inflation-linked bonds and bonds with maturities longer than 15 years. This understates their demand for longdated assets, however, as pension funds swapped as much as 50 billion of interest rate exposure in 2005 and 2006 to increase the duration of their assets. 2 The net increase in pension funds demand for long-dated assets is substantial compared to approximately 73 billion of net government issuance of inflation-linked and long-term bonds between April 2005 and March 2007. 30 20 Net Purchases (billions) 10 0-10 - 20-30 - 40-50 Dec-02 Dec-03 Dec-04 Dec-05 Dec-06 Cumulative Net Purchases of: Short-term Bonds Long-term Bonds Equities Figure 1. Pension funds cumulative net purchases of long-term government bonds, short-term government bonds, and equities. Notes: Bonds with less than 15-years of remaining maturity are classified as short-term. Bonds with 15-years or more of remaining maturity, and inflation-linked bonds, are classified as long-term. 2 The numbers for the debt market are compiled from quarterly releases of UK National Statistics, release MQ5. The estimate for the swap activity is from a Barclays Capital report by Moyeen Islam (2007), p.57. -4-

Figure 2 shows that the effects of pension-fund demand on the shape of the term structure were dramatic. The figure plots yields to maturity on a variety of inflation-linked government bonds. The spread between the 2035 and 2016 bonds turned negative in October 2003, and decreased throughout 2004 and 2005 to reach an all time low of -0.49% in January 2006. At that time, the 2035 and 2055 bonds were yielding 0.72% and 0.48%, respectively, which are extremely low relative to the historical average of 3% of long real rates in the UK. This inversion of the term structure is hard to rationalize based on the expectations hypothesis: one would have to argue that expectations about short-term interest rates past 2016 dropped sharply during 2004 and 2005, and to levels below 0.5%. The spread between the 2035 and 2016 bonds reached a new all time low of -0.68% in December 2006. A similar inversion appeared in the nominal term structure. 2.50 2055 Bond 2035 Bond 2009 Bond 2016 Bond 2.00 Yield (% Real) 1.50 1.00 0.50 0.00 Dec-02 Dec-03 Dec-04 Dec-05 Dec-06 Figure 2. Real yields on selected U.K. inflation-linked government bonds, December 2002-December 2006. In response to the change in yields, pension-fund managers lobbied the government to expand the supply of long-term debt, claiming that long-term interest rates reflected a pension- -5-

fund demand-driven bubble. The U.K. Debt Management Office appears to have agreed with this assessment it attributed the drop in long-term yields to structural demand, and acknowledged that long conventional yields fell to 50-year lows reportedly reflecting sustained purchases of long-dated gilts by the pension industry. 3 In 2005, the government agreed to issue nominal and inflation-linked bonds with initial maturities of up to 50 years, simultaneously shifting the overall mix of maturities: 55% of total bond sales between April 2005 and March 2006, and 68% of total bond sales between April 2006 and March 2007, were long-term or inflation-linked, compared to 45% between April 2004 and March 2005, and 36% between April 2003 and March 2004. II. Treasury Buybacks of 2000-2001 The US Treasury announced during the fall of 1999 that it was considering a program to buy back long-term bonds. The impetus for this decision was that following a few years of budget surpluses, reduced government financing requirements had led to smaller and fewer new bond listings. And because short-term debt had been retiring without being replaced, the average maturity of outstanding debt had increased. Treasury officials argued that buybacks would enhance our ability to exert greater control over the maturity structure of outstanding debt [and] will provide us the option of managing the maturity structure of the debt by selectively targeting the maturities of debt to be repurchased. 4 The final rule was adopted on January 19, 2000, although Treasury Secretary Summers announced its arrival a few days sooner, on January 13, 2000. 3 UK Debt Management Office Annual Review 2005-06, p.4. 4 U.S. Treasury Press Release August 4, 1999. http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/ls43.htm. -6-

Between March 2000 and December 2001 the Treasury conducted 42 buybacks covering 42 long-term bonds with a combined face value of $63.5 billion. This was approximately 10% of the December 1999 outstanding value of marketable long-term government bonds of $644 billion, and approximately 2% of all marketable interest-bearing government debt. The weighted-average remaining maturity of repurchased bonds was approximately 18 years, ranging from the 11.75% 2010 bond to the 6.125% 2027 bond. Figure 3 shows the dramatic effects of the buybacks on the term structure. Prior to the announcement of the final rule, on January 18, the spread between the 20- and the 5-year spot rates was 0.26%. Three weeks later, on February 8, the spread had decreased to -0.39%, a drop of 0.65%. The sharp drop in the spread was mainly driven by the 20-year spot rate, which fell by -0.58%; the 5-year spot rate rose by 0.07%. 7.00 6.80 Yield (%) 6.60 6.40 6.20 6.00 5.80 3-Jan 10-Jan 17-Jan 24-Jan 31-Jan 7-Feb 14-Feb 21-Feb 28-Feb 6-Mar 13-Mar 20-Mar 27-Mar 1-year bond 5-year bond 10-year bond 20-year bond Figure 3. Yields on 1-year, 5-year, 10-year, and 20-year zero-coupon bonds, January March 2000. While the buybacks targeted only bonds with maturities of 9 years or longer, they appear to have impacted the yields on intermediate-term bonds as well. The spread between the 5- and the 1-year spot rates dropped from 0.43% on January 18, to 0.33% on February 8, then to -0.11% on -7-

March 31. Thus, while the buybacks had larger and more immediate effects on long-term interest rates, they appear to have contributed to a more general inversion of the term structure. III. Theory The episodes described in Sections I and II are hard to rationalize within the standard representative-agent model: to explain the decrease in long-term interest rates, one would have to argue that the UK pension reform or the US Treasury buybacks signaled significant drops in aggregate consumption 20-30 years into the future. 5 On the other hand, both episodes support the preferred-habitat view: the UK pension reform was a positive shock to the demand for long-term bonds, while the US Treasury buybacks were a negative shock to the supply of long-term bonds. Consistent with the preferred-habitat view, long-term rates fell relative to short-term rates. A salient feature of these episodes is that the effects of demand and supply shocks were not isolated to the specific maturities of the shocks location. For example, while the Treasury buybacks targeted only bonds with maturities of 9 years or more, their effect on rates extended to the 5-year maturity. Similarly, while the effects of the UK pension reform were most pronounced for the longer maturities, the spread between the yields of intermediate- and short-term bonds narrowed as well. One would expect such effects because bonds with nearby maturities are close substitutes therefore arbitrageurs transmit shocks local to one maturity to nearby maturities. Characterizing how demand and supply shocks manifest themselves in an arbitrage-free term structure requires a formal model of preferred habitat. Vayanos and Vila (2009) develop such a model, which Greenwood and Vayanos (2010) extend to accommodate shocks to debt maturity structure. The term structure in the model is determined through the interaction between investor clienteles who prefer bonds with specific maturities, and risk-averse arbitrageurs. Without 5 Or, in the spirit of the expectations hypothesis of the term structure, one would have to argue that these episodes signaled significant drops in short-term interest rates in the distant future. -8-

arbitrageurs, the term structure would exhibit extreme segmentation: the yield for a given maturity would be influenced only by the demand of the corresponding clientele, and would evolve independently of other maturities. Such segmentation does not happen in equilibrium, however. Arbitrageurs intermediate across maturity markets, buying bonds with maturities for which clientele demand is low, and selling bonds with maturities for which demand is high. Their presence ensures that bonds with nearby maturities trade at similar prices. In bridging markets across different maturities, arbitrageurs face both fundamental and nonfundamental risk. The fundamental risk is that the short-term interest rate rises (falls) in the future, thereby flattening (steepening) the term structure. The non-fundamental risk is that there will be shocks to the demand for bonds with particular maturities. Because arbitrageurs are risk averse, they receive compensation for accommodating demand shocks. If arbitrageurs risk aversion is low, then changes in short-term interest rates are the dominant source of risk, and demand shocks affect the term structure by altering the market price of short-rate risk. This in turn implies that the specific location of demand effects is unrelated to that of the underlying shocks: bonds most sensitive to the shocks are those most sensitive to changes in the market price of short-rate risk. If arbitrageurs risk aversion is high, however, then multiple risk factors become relevant. In this case, arbitrageurs are less able to intermediate across maturity markets, and demand effects become more local. IV. Policy Implications The preferred-habitat view of the term structure is particularly relevant in the context of recent central bank policies. In the midst of the global financial crisis of 2007-2009, central banks around the world conducted unprecedented open-market purchases of long-term securities all with the hope of influencing long-term bond yields. The largest of these programs -9-

was the Federal Reserve s asset purchase program, which initially targeted government-backed agency securities and agency-backed mortgage-backed securities, and later expanded to include long-term government bonds. Remarkably, the motivation for these government purchase programs was similar to that of Operation Twist, suggesting a revival of policy interest in the preferred-habitat view. For example, the December 2008 minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) outline Board members view that purchases would reduce interest rates on long-term instruments, which in turn would stimulate private borrowing and investment. 20-year yield - 1-year yield (%) 3.50 3.40 3.30 3.20 3.10 3.00 2.90 2.80 2.70 2.60 2.50 March 18, 2009 November 25, 2008 December 15, 2008-2 -1 +0 +1 +2 Days from Announcement Figure 4. Yield spreads between 20- and 1-year bonds on days surrounding Federal Reserve announcements. Bond market responses to the Federal Reserve s asset purchase program suggest that it had the desired effect. Figure 4 plots the yield spread between the 20-year bond and the 1-year bill during a two-day window around three announcements: the initial announcement of the asset purchase program on November 25, 2008; the FOMC announcement on December 16, 2008 that purchases might extend to government bonds; and the announcement on March 18, 2009 that up to $300 billion of government bonds would be purchased as well. All three events were -10-

accompanied by a drop in the spread, with the average drop being 0.30%. Moreover, the drop was mainly driven by the 20-year yield, which fell by an average of 0.33%. While a theory of preferred habitat is useful for evaluating these recent central bank interventions, there remain important empirical challenges. First, developing precise quantitative estimates of the price impact of supply and demand shocks on the term structure is difficult because shifts to the supply and demand for bonds are infrequent, and because the availability of arbitrageur capital may fluctuate over time. A second and related challenge is that the desirability of central bank intervention depends in large part on whether supply shocks have transitory or permanent effects on interest rates. If the effects are only transitory, then government actions to alter the term structure are expensive. Yet, to distinguish between transitory and permanent effects would require the econometrician to identify numerous exogenous shocks to bond supply or demand. A third challenge is that one must account for segmentation not only across maturities, but also across types of bonds, e.g., Treasuries, mortgage-backed and corporate. For example, announcement effects of the Federal Reserve buybacks differed between mortgagebacked securities and Treasury bonds, suggesting segmentation between the two markets (Xavier Gabaix, Arvind Krishnamurthy and Olivier Vigneron (2007), Krishnamurthy and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2009)). -11-

References Cox, John C., Jonathan Ingersoll and Stephen A. Ross. 1985. A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Econometrica 53(2): 385-408. Culbertson, John. 1957. ` The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Quarterly Journal of Economics 71(4): 485-517. Gabaix, Xavier, Arvind Krishnamurthy and Olivier Vigneron. 2007. Limits of Arbitrage: Theory and Evidence from the Mortgage Backed Securities Market. Journal of Finance 62(2): 557-595. Garbade, Kenneth, and Matthew Rutherford. 2007. Buybacks in Treasury Cash and Debt Management. Staff Report 304, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Greenwood, Robin, and Dimitri Vayanos. 2010. Bond Supply and Excess Bond Returns. Working Paper, Harvard Business School. Islam, Moyeen. 2007. The State that I am in Chapter 5 in Equity Gilt Study 2007, Barclays Capital.. Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen. 2009. The Aggregate Demand for Treasury Debt. NBER Working paper 12881. Modigliani, Franco and Richard Sutch. 1966. Innovations in Interest-Rate Policy. American Economic Review 56(1/2): 178-197. Ross, Myron. 1966. Operation Twist : A Mistaken Policy? Journal of Political Economy 74(2): 195-199. Vayanos, Dimitri, and Jean-Luc Vila. 2009. A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. NBER Working Paper 15487. -12-