Inflation Target Of The Lunda Krona



Similar documents
Adjusting to a Changing Economic World. Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It s a pleasure to be with you here in Montréal today.

PROJECTION OF THE FISCAL BALANCE AND PUBLIC DEBT ( ) - SUMMARY

The EMU and the debt crisis

X. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT 1/

Joint Economic Forecast Spring German Economy Recovering Long-Term Approach Needed to Economic Policy

Economic Commentaries

Lars Nyberg: The Riksbank's monetary policy strategy

GUIDELINES FOR CENTRAL GOVERNMENT DEBT MANAGEMENT 2016

Jarle Bergo: Monetary policy and the outlook for the Norwegian economy

EUROSYSTEM STAFF MACROECONOMIC PROJECTIONS FOR THE EURO AREA

INFLATION REPORT PRESS CONFERENCE. Thursday 4 th February Opening remarks by the Governor

GUIDELINES FOR CENTRAL GOVERNMENT DEBT MANAGEMENT 2015

Supplemental Unit 5: Fiscal Policy and Budget Deficits

Estonia and the European Debt Crisis Juhan Parts

Project LINK Meeting New York, October Country Report: Australia

2.5 Monetary policy: Interest rates

Monetary policy rules and their application in Russia. Economics Education and Research Consortium Working Paper Series ISSN

Strategy Document 1/03

Forecasting Chinese Economy for the Years

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

Errors and omissions in the balance of payments statistics a problem?

THE GREAT DEPRESSION OF FINLAND : causes and consequences. Jaakko Kiander Labour Institute for Economic Research

Lars Heikensten: The krona, Sweden and EMU

Lars Osberg. Department of Economics Dalhousie University 6214 University Avenue Halifax, Nova Scotia B3H 3J5 CANADA

Introduction on monetary policy

Why is inflation low?

Fiscal Unruliness: Checking the Usual Suspects for Jamaica's Debt Buildup

Reg. no 2014/ September Central government debt management

Time to improve the inflation target?

The global economy Banco de Portugal Lisbon, 24 September 2013 Mr. Pier Carlo Padoan OECD Deputy Secretary-General and Chief Economist

Why a Floating Exchange Rate Regime Makes Sense for Canada

The Employment Crisis in Spain 1

Statement by. Janet L. Yellen. Chair. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Financial Services

The Balance of Payments, the Exchange Rate, and Trade

The following text represents the notes on which Mr. Parry based his remarks. 1998: Issues in Monetary Policymaking

Low inflation and high indebtedness expansionary monetary policy makes demands of other policy areas

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11

Commentary: What Do Budget Deficits Do?

Monetary policy assessment of 13 September 2007 SNB aiming to calm the money market

Reg. no 2015/ September Central government debt management

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Bank of Finland and Finland s economic internationalization. Turku

Monetary Policy Report

HEAD OFFICE ANKARA, 28 January 2014

Finland and Sweden in a cross country comparison. What are the lessons?

How To Know How The Falling Oil Price Affects The Global Economy And Inflation

A BRIEF HISTORY OF BRAZIL S GROWTH

Answer: C Learning Objective: Money supply Level of Learning: Knowledge Type: Word Problem Source: Unique

Debt, consolidation and growth

Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices

A New Effective Exchange Rate Index for the Canadian Dollar

Theories of Exchange rate determination

Price projection 2013

ANNEX 1 - MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS FOR ITALY OF ACHIEVING COMPLIANCE WITH THE DEBT RULE UNDER TWO DIFFERENT SCENARIOS

Economic Outlook for Europe and Finland

percentage points to the overall CPI outcome. Goods price inflation increased to 4,6

East Midlands Development Agency/Bank of England Dinner, Leicester 14 October 2003

East Asia - A Case Study in the Global Economy

Statement to Parliamentary Committee

Meeting with Analysts

South African Reserve Bank. Statement of the Monetary Policy Committee. Issued by Lesetja Kganyago, Governor of the South African Reserve Bank

Euro Zone s Economic Outlook and What it Means for the United States

Meeting with Analysts

UK Economic Forecast Q1 2015

PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVINGS ACCOUNT INVESTMENT REPORT

Chapter 11. International Economics II: International Finance

Statement by Dean Baker, Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research (

Assessment of the Fulfilment of the Maastricht Convergence Criteria and the Degree of Economic Alignment of the Czech Republic with the Euro Area

Explanation beyond exchange rates: trends in UK trade since 2007

FLEXIBLE EXCHANGE RATES

Sweden 2013 Article IV Consultation: Concluding Statement of the Mission Stockholm May 31, 2013

Kjell-Olof Feldt, EMU the best choice for Sweden (1998)

CANADA AND U.S. AUTO SALES: ROOM FOR FUR- THER GROWTH? October Factors supporting the U.S. sales outlook: Employment Growth

UK Economic Forecast Q3 2014

South African Trade-Offs among Depreciation, Inflation, and Unemployment. Alex Diamond Stephanie Manning Jose Vasquez Erin Whitaker

Note: This feature provides supplementary analysis for the material in Part 3 of Common Sense Economics.

Objectives for Chapter 9 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

5 Comparison with the Previous Convergence Programme and Sensitivity Analysis

Svein Gjedrem: The economic situation in Norway

Vittorio Corbo: Monetary policy in emerging countries the view from Chile

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

The Case for a Tax Cut

11/6/2013. Chapter 16: Government Debt. The U.S. experience in recent years. The troubling long-term fiscal outlook

Per Jansson: Some aspects of the economic situation

U.S. Inflation Developments. Remarks by. Stanley Fischer. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Statistics Netherlands. Macroeconomic Imbalances Factsheet

6. Economic Outlook. The International Economy. Graph 6.2 Terms of Trade Log scale, 2012/13 average = 100

FUNDS TM. G10 Currencies: White Paper. A Monetary Policy Analysis FUNDS. The Authority on Currencies

Current account deficit -10. Private sector Other public* Official reserve assets

EUROPEAN MONETARY SYSTEM

The Fiscal Policy and The Monetary Policy. Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. Russian Federation Concluding Statement for the 2012 Article IV Consultation Mission. Moscow, June 13, 2012

Section 2 Evaluation of current account balance fluctuations

CAN INVESTORS PROFIT FROM DEVALUATIONS? THE PERFORMANCE OF WORLD STOCK MARKETS AFTER DEVALUATIONS. Bryan Taylor

Pre-Test Chapter 11 ed17

THE US DOLLAR, THE EURO, THE JAPANESE YEN AND THE CHINESE YUAN IN THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS

GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC OBJECTIVES AND POLICIES. Textbook, Chapter 26 [pg ]

The history of the Bank of Russia s exchange rate policy

The Year An Inflation Risk

The U.S. Economy after September pushing us from sluggish growth to an outright contraction. b and there s a lot of uncertainty.

Transcription:

Inflation Targeting The Swedish Experience Lars Heikensten We in Sweden owe a great debt of thanks to the Bank of Canada for all the help we have received in recent years. We have greatly benefited from Canada s experiences with a floating exchange rate. Not only is our policy framework influenced by Canada s, but so is much of our more detailed work, for instance on the modelling side. In my remarks I take the basic inflation-targeting framework as given. On the whole it has, in my opinion, served us well. I deal here with three topics or questions that have been raised by current developments in Sweden. First, how should one look at the speed of adjustment to a set target? A trade-off with the growth of output is involved here. Perhaps more important in practice is how to treat problems of uncertainty and credibility. These are factors that have influenced our policy. Second, for small open economies a particularly important factor for inflation is the exchange rate. How to treat the effects of changes in this variable, given the uncertainty surrounding it, has been one of our main concerns. Finally, there is the problem of how to specify the target itself. There might be some useful experiences to draw from our recent history. Before dealing with these questions, however, let me present a brief background on what has happened in Sweden during the last few years. 1 History In November 1992, after a heroic defence, the fixed exchange rate regime collapsed. A few months later, in January 1993, the Governing Board 281

282 Heikensten of the Riksbank adopted a new monetary policy regime based on a floating exchange rate and an inflation target. In 1991-93, Sweden experienced the most severe recession since the 1930s. Since then the economy has recovered substantially, growing at more than 2.5 per cent a year, which is above the average for recent decades. In 1996 growth slowed significantly, but now the economy is set to expand at a steady, strong rate in the years ahead (Figure 1). Public finances deteriorated rapidly during the recession but a marked improvement has now been achieved thanks to the stronger economy as well as substantial budget consolidation measures totalling around 8 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP) between 1994 and 1998 (Figure 2). The recession in the early 1990s brought inflation down to around 2 per cent (Figure 3). The path of inflation has continued to be good during the subsequent years of strong growth. This has been accompanied by a substantial downward revision of inflation expectations (Figure 4). A blot on our record is unemployment, which is stubbornly high and far above historical standards. The problems here have to do with the structure of wage-setting and the labour market. 2 The Speed of Adjustment to the Target I turn now to my first topic the speed of adjustment to the target and the output-inflation trade-off. Our Governing Board s original decision contains just a brief reference to output and employment. As a general argument for adopting the new strategy, the decision states that price stability is a prerequisite for sustained economic growth as well as full employment. It refers, in other words, only to the view that in the long run the relationship, if there is one, between the rate of inflation and the rate of unemployment has a positive slope. The more relevant question concerns the role of output and employment stabilization in the actual conduct of monetary policy in the short to medium term. The issue might be considered simple as long as the central bank has only one objective, price stabilization. Given the lags in the effects of monetary policy, the strongest impact on inflation does not occur until perhaps one to two years after policy has been changed. If the inflation forecast for the coming two years indicates that the inflation target will be missed, monetary policy should be adjusted to bring the inflation forecast back into line with the target. However, the world is not quite that simple.

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 283 Figure 1 Composition of Growth, Sweden, 1993-98, Percentage Contributions 5 4 3 2 1 0 Per cent 1 2 Net exports 3 Stock building 4 Gross capital formation 5 Consumption 6 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Source: Statistics Sweden; 1997-98 forecast by National Institute of Economic Research.

284 Heikensten Debt-to-GDP ratio Figure 2 General Government Debt and Deficit, Sweden, 1990-98, Per Cent of GDP 6 4 2 Deficit-to-GDP ratio Debt-to-GDP ratio 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 Source: Statistics Sweden; 1997-98 forecast by National Institute of Economic Research. 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Deficit-to-GDP ratio

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 285 Figure 3 CPI, Sweden, 1985-97, 12-Month Percentage Change 14 12 10 8 6 Per cent 4 2 0 1 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Source: Statistics Sweden.

286 Heikensten Figure 4 Money Market Agents Inflation Expectations, Sweden, 1994-2001 5 4 3 2 1 CPI 0 October 1994 October 1995 May 1996 December 1996 February 1997 Per cent 1 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Sources: Statistics Sweden and Prospera Research.

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 287 First, no central bank is an inflation nutter that is, concerned only with inflation. For all practical purposes it is concerned about output and employment variability. In other words, it assigns a positive weight to output stabilization. In the example above, instead of trying to adjust the two-year inflation forecast all the way to the inflation target, the central bank could let it return gradually to the long-run inflation target. The greater the weight given to output stabilization, the more gradual the adjustment of the inflation forecast towards the target ( flexible inflation targeting ). The target bands that are a typical component of an inflation target regime can be interpreted as an implicit way of assigning weight to output stabilization. Second, the question of how in this framework to deal with uncertainty has been very important in practice. Uncertainty can stem from many factors. Not knowing the exact model of the economy is obviously one. Another is how to evaluate shocks to the economy or new information in general. If, for example, the central bank were to overestimate the inflation forecast s deviation from the target, or underestimate the effect of a change in its policy interest rate, it would risk raising the rate too much. Then the policy would eventually appear excessively restrictive and the central bank would have to reverse its stance. This could create instability and magnify cyclical movements. Thus, there are reasons to proceed with caution in changing the policy stance. Hence, central banks would tend to move the policy interest rate in rather small steps. A third issue of practical importance has to do with credibility and tactics. If a central bank is worried that its policy suffers from low credibility, this ought to affect the speed with which the rate is cut. Drastic cuts can lead to an increase in inflation expectations, affecting the room for further cuts. In this case the central bank may have to keep its policy interest rate higher than the forecast would seem to require. Developments in 1996 illustrate policy effects resulting from uncertainty and worries about lack of credibility. At the beginning of the year the Riksbank concluded that activity was weakening and inflationary pressures were abating. Both the demand situation and indicators of inflation expectations pointed in the same direction (Figure 4). However, forecasts from private sector actors were still not in line with the Riksbank s target, and neither were expectations, although they were coming down rapidly. Nevertheless, at the Riksbank we began to ease monetary policy. Initially we chose to cut the repo rate at fairly regular intervals, in steps of 25 basis points (Figure 5). We were not sure of our forecasts. Our concern was also that the easing would be interpreted by the markets as evidence that the Riksbank was giving in to pressures for an easier monetary

288 Heikensten Figure 5 Actual and Expected Repo Rate, Sweden, 1995-97 10 9 8 Repo 7 6 95-12-27 96-03-25 Per cent 5 96-10-15 97-04-14 4 97-01-07 3 1995-1 1995-5 1995-10 1996-3 1996-8 1997-1 1997-6 Year-month Source: The Riksbank.

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 289 stance, with possible negative effects on the krona in particular. The series of small cuts in the repo rate continued until the end of the year. By then we had lowered the repo rate by altogether 4.8 percentage points. With the benefit of hindsight, it might be argued that we had more credibility than we thought and could have made larger cuts during the spring. However, not even this argument is self-evident since credibility was strengthened during the spring by new information on the budget and inflation. 3 The Exchange Rate In small open economies the exchange rate is clearly one of the factors most strongly correlated with inflation. At the same time, in recent years this variable has fluctuated a great deal for reasons that are not always easy to understand. How to handle exchange rate movements in current policy depends above all on what caused the movement and how it is expected to affect the future rate of inflation. Different causes can be distinguished. First, a nominal depreciation could be initiated by a need for a real exchange rate depreciation due to a real disturbance. This situation is easy to deal with, since it does not normally require any policy action. In practice, however, real developments have not been important for the exchange rate fluctuations of recent years. Second, a nominal depreciation could also result from a revision by the market of its views on the credibility of the Riksbank s inflation policy. Such a revision could stem from a loss of operational credibility that is, the ability of the Riksbank to fulfil the declared monetary policy target, primarily affected by the conduct of monetary policy. This case is also relatively easy to deal with, at least in principle. Probably interest rates will have to be raised. More difficult to deal with is a third situation in which the exchange rate depreciates as a consequence of a reduction in political credibility in a more general sense. Investors expectations of the probability of a regime shift, whereby the present price-stability target would be abandoned, may have risen, at least temporarily. In Sweden during the 1990s this has probably been the most common reason behind the frequent periods of currency turbulence. Public finances have been the focus of attention. In these situations monetary policy cannot do the job by itself. In fact, raising rates can even be counterproductive in the short run, making budget consolidation even more difficult. Nevertheless, the only alternative might be to react and raise rates to demonstrate that the central bank will do what it can. At the same time, we must do everything possible to influence fiscal policy in the right direction.

290 Heikensten A fourth, often complementary, reason for a change in the nominal exchange rate could be a financial disturbance in the foreign exchange or capital markets. If such a disturbance is believed to be purely a market phenomenon, it need not affect the central bank s credibility. But this is not usually the case. What we have seen as after the bond market crash of 1994 or during the turbulence caused by the Mexican and the Barings situations in 1995 is an interaction of market developments in a more limited sense and poor public finances or other credibility problems. Higher international rates or currency weakness made the public finance problems more severe, moving an economy such as Sweden s from virtuous to vicious circles. And finally, since the exchange rate is a relative price, a fifth possible reason is of course that something may happen in another country that affects the bilateral exchange rate with the krona. Our experience during the last half year is a good illustration of the problem of identifying the reasons for movements in the exchange rate. At present, economic developments in Sweden suggest that there is room for an appreciation of the krona. We have a large current-account surplus, favourable information about future inflation, and considerably better government finances than before. We are, in fact, one of the relatively few European Union countries likely to satisfy the Maastricht budget criterion this year with some margin. Despite this, between October 1996 and May 1997 the krona has depreciated in effective terms by some 6 per cent. Probably there are effects related to the business cycle and the stance of monetary policy. In recent months the dollar and sterling have appreciated relative to other currencies, including the krona (Figure 6). In the United States and the United Kingdom, monetary policies have been relatively tight. The krona has also been affected, however, by unrest connected with the process of European economic and monetary union (EMU), particularly as the Swedish position vis-à-vis the EMU is not clear. At the same time, the future long-term direction of fiscal policy has been questioned despite the drastic turnaround during the last two years. How should monetary policy handle a situation such as this? We can use open-mouth operations, giving an assessment of what has happened, and try to convince the market that we are serious in the pursuit of price stability. However, even if the market believes the Riksbank, the krona could continue to weaken, which could affect inflation expectations. If a depreciation tendency cannot be reversed, the Riksbank will ultimately have to consider a tightening of monetary policy.

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 291 Krona/ and Krona/$US Figure 6 The Swedish Exchange Rate Versus U.S. Dollar, German Mark, and U.K. Sterling, 1994-96 5.5 5.3 Krona/ 5.1 4.9 4.7 4.5 Krona/DM 4.3 4.1 3.9 Krona/$US 3.7 3.5 1994-1 1994-8 1995-3 1995-10 1996-5 1996-12 Year-month Source: The Riksbank. 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 Krona/DM

292 Heikensten 4 The Choice of Index Our inflation target is expressed as the change in the official consumer price index. The advantages of the CPI are well understood: it is familiar, published monthly with a short time lag, and rarely subject to revision. Using the CPI eases communication with the general public and promotes transparency. A problem with the use of the CPI is that it includes the effects of indirect taxes and subsidies as well as imputed interest costs for owneroccupied homes. Inflation could thus be strongly influenced in a perverse direction by our own policy actions in the short run. More generally, transitory movements in the market prices of particular goods may mask a different tendency in the general price level. The CPI has been much more variable than any of the measures of underlying inflation (Figure 7). It is notable, for example, that the CPI rose in late 1994 and early 1995, while all the underlying measures were essentially flat or declining. This was a period of monetary policy tightening and generally high interest rates, and the imputed interest component in the CPI contributed to inflation s higher measured rate. For a brief period the rate of inflation was in excess of the upper limit (3 per cent) of the tolerance interval. In situations such as this there is a risk at least in the short run that interest rate tightening, contrary to intentions, raises inflation expectations. Similarly, during the period of monetary easing in 1996, the CPI inflation rate fell much more sharply than underlying inflation; again this reflected, in part, movements in the imputed interest rate cost. This time the annual average rate of inflation was for some months substantially below the tolerance interval s lower limit. In contrast, all the indicators of underlying inflation appear to have settled around the lower limit of the tolerance band that is, at 1 per cent. Obviously, this has led to communication problems. Time and again at the Riksbank, we have had to explain why we have missed our target in the short run by moving interest rates as required to achieve our target in the long run. In practice, as when the target was first decided, we now have a choice of four different strategies: 1. We could continue to use the CPI as a target variable. From an overall credibility point of view, there is a case for sticking to this strategy for the time being. The currently fashionable issue of a possible bias in the CPI appears not to be a great problem in Sweden. No estimate of the total bias is available, but we believe it is smaller than in, for example, the United States.

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 293 Figure 7 CPI and Underlying Inflation, Sweden, 1992-97, 12-Month Percentage Change 5 4 Underlying domestic inflation CPI UND1 CPI less taxes and subsidies 3 2 Per cent 1 0 1 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Sources: Statistics Sweden and the Riksbank.

294 Heikensten 2. We could specify clearly in advance which causes of deviations from the CPI target are acceptable. This could contribute to greater transparency. However, the precise definition of the target variable would become less clear. Moreover, it would be difficult to foresee all the possibilities that might arise, and difficult to quantify the exact price effects of the disturbances. Finally, the fact that the analysis of the situation was made by the Riksbank itself could have an adverse effect on credibility. 3. We could use a measure of underlying inflation as a target. On the one hand, this would have the advantage over option 2 of providing an unambiguous definition of the target variable. On the other hand, it would present similar difficulties to option 2 with regard to the definition and quantification of the effects of disturbances. 4. Finally, we could combine the CPI with one or several measures of underlying inflation. The CPI could continue to be the target variable, but it would be made clear that policy actually aims at influencing the underlying inflation because these measures give a better picture of the inflation process. In the long run, hitting the rates of the underlying inflation would lead to hitting a CPI target. In fact, we have been moving gradually towards the last option. The Riksbank has noted that there are price effects that cannot be accommodated within the band and cannot be fully contained with monetary policy measures. Attempts to do so would have destabilizing effects on the economy. Thus, in case of major unforeseen disturbances, as well as when indirect taxes and subsidies are altered in connection with a major reform of tax and transfer systems, we must provide scope for price effects. Temporary deviations from the targeted rate of inflation may accordingly occur, particularly in view of the fact that price stability does not refer to isolated monthly figures. However, any secondary effects should be contained so that inflation would be quickly returned to a rate consistent with the target. In practice the Riksbank has been dealing with the problem of price shocks through what has been referred to as caveats. But these caveats have not been specified in advance in any systematic fashion. Consequently, the price shocks and the resulting CPI variability continue to present us with a communication problem. 5 Summary During the last four to five years, the financial markets have been extremely turbulent, with both the exchange rate and interest rates showing substantial volatility due largely to fiscal problems. How to handle uncertainties in general and the exchange rate in particular has been the

Round Table: The Swedish Experience 295 main practical problem for monetary policy. This problem has been accentuated by the change to a new policy framework and also by the lack of monetary policy credibility and indeed of confidence in the Riksbank itself after the currency crisis in 1992. Nevertheless, growth in recent years has been relatively high, 2.5 to 3 per cent, while inflation has been low. These, by Swedish standards, are good figures. Gradually, the acceptance of a policy oriented towards price stability has increased. In May 1997, a five-party agreement was made in Parliament concerning future legislation to regulate the role and work of the Riksbank. According to the agreement, the Riksbank is to be one of the most independent central banks in Europe. A greater understanding of what the Riksbank is doing has also developed within the markets and among the general public. The transparency of the policy framework has been useful in this context.