November 2011 Preliminary and Incomplete

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "November 2011 Preliminary and Incomplete"

Transcription

1 Average Expectations, Liquidity, Liquidity, and Short-term and Short-term Trading* Trading Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives November 2011 Preliminary and Incomplete Preliminary Abstract In a market with short term investors and heterogeneous information, when liquidity trading displays persistence, asset prices reflect average expectations about both fundamentals and liquidity trading, and multiple, self-fulfilling equilibria arise. If asset prices are driven by average expectations about fundamentals, they heavily rely on public information and the market displays low liquidity; if they are driven by average expectations about liquidity trading, prices rely less on public information and the market displays high liquidity. Along the equilibrium with high liquidity, the volume of informational trading is high, and momentum arises at short horizons. Conversely, along the equilibrium with low liquidity the volume of informational trading is low and short term returns tend to revert. At long horizons reversal occurs. Keywords: Expected returns, multiple equilibria, average expectations, reliance on public information, momentum and reversal, Beauty Contest, High Frequency Trading. JEL Classification Numbers: G10, G12, G14 A previous version of this paper was circulated under the title Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading. We thank Bruno Biais, Marcelo Fernandes, Peter Hoffmann, Harrison Hong, Peter Kondor, Stephen Morris, Richard Payne, Ioanid Roşu, and seminar participants in the Econometrics Workshop at Queen Mary University of London, ESSEC, Paris Dauphine, the IESEG workshop on Asset Pricing (IESEG, May 2010), the 2010 European Finance Association meeting (Frankfurt), the ELSE-UCL Workshop in Financial Economics (UCL, September 2010), the 2011 ESSET (Gerzensee), the 2011 SED meeting (Gent), and the CNMV conference on Securities Markets: The Crisis and the Challenges Ahead, Madrid (11/11) for their comments. Cespa acknowledges financial support from ESRC (grant n. ES/J00250X/1). Vives acknowledges financial support from the European Research Council under the Advanced Grant project Information and Competition (no ). Cass Business School, CSEF, and CEPR. 106, Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK. giovanni.cespa@gmail.com IESE Business School, Avinguda Pearson, Barcelona, Spain. xvives@iese.edu 1

2 Introduction We study the drivers of asset prices in a two-period market where short-term, informed, competitive, risk-averse agents trade on account of private information and to accommodate liquidity supply, facing a persistent demand from liquidity traders. Assuming that the demand of liquidity traders displays persistence and that informed investors have short horizons captures an important feature of High Frequency Trading (HFT). Due to persistence in liquidity trading informed investors can use their private signals to help them infer the demand of liquidity traders from the order flow to anticipate the impact this will have on the price at which they will unwind their positions. This allows high frequecny traders to move ahead of liquidity traders. We show that this has important consequences for the properties of the market. HFT represents a sizeable proportion of the trades carried out in today s exchanges. 1 HFTs use computer algorithms to detect arbitrage opportunities by typically scanning order flow data, and rapidly reacting to such opportunities to lock in profitable trades (the latency between the time at which the information is obtained by the computer and the time at which the trade is executed at the exchange is in the order of milliseconds and even microseconds). The debate on the merits and flaws of HFT is intense both at the academic and policy levels. While a number of authors find that HFT substantially boosts market quality, in particular enhancing price efficiency and improving depth (see, e.g. Hendershott, Menkveld, and Jones (2011), and Hendershott and Riordan (2011)), others argue that it can exacerbate extreme price movements, to the detriment of market stability (Kirilenko, Kyle, Mehrdad, and Tugkan (2010)). We find that with heterogeneous information and short horizons, liquidity trading persistence yields multiple equilibria. The intuition is as follows. With risk averse investors and heterogeneous information, the price accounts for adverse selection and inventory risk, reflecting the market expectations about the fundamentals and liquidity traders demand. Due to persistence, liquidity traders positions in the first and second period are positively correlated. Thus, informed investors use their private signals on the fundamentals also to infer the demand of liquidity traders from the first period price, to anticipate the impact that liquidity traders have on the price at which they unwind their positions (thus exploiting a private learning channel from the price as in Amador and Weill (2010) and Manzano and Vives (2011)). Suppose first period investors anticipate that the second period price is more correlated to the fundamentals. In this case, they speculate more aggressively on their private information, making the first period price reflect more the fundamentals, and less the demand of liquidity traders. This, in turn, leads them to put more weight on the private signal to extrapolate the demand of liquidity traders from the price, increasing the informativeness of the first and second period prices. In this case, this self-reinforcing loop leads investors to escalate their response to private information. Suppose instead that first period investors anticipate that the second period price is less correlated to the fundamentals. In this case, they speculate less aggressively 1 According to Tabb Group, in 2010 HFT accounted for roughly two thirds of all equity trades in the US and slightly more than one third in Europe. 2

3 on their private information, making the first period price reflect less the fundamentals, and more the demand of first period liquidity traders. This lowers the weight investors put on their private signals to infer the demand of liquidity traders from the price, yielding less informative first and second period prices. In this case, the self-reinforcing loop leads investors to dampen their response to private information. The above described equilibria have strikingly different features. Along the former equilibrium, prices are more informative about the fundamentals, and the market is thicker. Conversely, along the latter equilibrium, prices are less informative about the fundamentals and the market is thinner. Studying the stability of the equilibrium solutions, we show that the high liquidity-high price efficiency equilibrium is however unstable according to the best reply dynamics. Therefore, HFT may induce fragility in that it creates multiple equilibria with one unstable equilibrium. This paper is related to the growing literature on HFT. Hendershott and Riordan (2011) find that HFTs orders have a permanent price impact which is larger than that of slow human traders. This allows the price to adjust more rapidly toward the (informationally) efficient price. Based on this evidence, Biais, Foucault, and Moinas (2011) assume that HFTs are able to process information before slow traders. This imposes an adverse selection cost on the latter, creating a negative externality which is responsible for excessive investment in HFT compared to a utilitarian welfare-maximization benchmark. We provide an explanation for HFTs superior ability to impound fundamentals information. In the high liquidity equilibrium due to the the private learning channel from prices HFTs escalate their response to private information, making prices more (informationally) efficient. Our results are also related to the literature that studies the ability of the non-informational component of total imbalances to predict stock returns (see, e.g. Coval and Stafford (2007), and Hendershott and Seasholes (2009)). Hendershott and Seasholes (2009) trace such ability either to adverse selection or to inventory risk and derive and test empirical predictions to identify which of these two provide a better explanation for it. Our paper shows that when the non-informational component of order imbalances is predictable, multiple equilibria where return regularities arise, emerge. However, the informational content of prices substantially differs across the two equilibria. Therefore, while due to persistence in liquidity trading and dealers limited risk bearing capacity, returns become predictable, the arbitrage opportunities that such regularities imply can vary dramatically. The paper is also related to the literature that investigates the relationship between the impact of short-term information on prices and investors reaction to their private signals (see, e.g. Singleton (1987), Brown and Jennings (1989), Vives (1995), Cespa (2002), Albagli (2011) and Vives (2008) for a survey). Several authors have argued that when private information is related to an event which occurs beyond the date at which investors liquidate their positions, the latter act on their signals only if they expect them to be reflected in the price at which they liquidate (see, e.g., Dow and Gorton (1994) and Froot, Scharfstein, and Stein (1992)). In our context too a similar mechanism is at work. However, due to persistence, the first period demand of liquidity traders impacts both the first and second period order flows, which gives 3

4 private information two different roles: the one of predicting the fundamentals and the one of predicting liquidity traders demand. Finally, the paper is related to a growing literature that points out the relevance of Higher Order Expectations (HOEs) (that is average expectations of average expectations... of average expectations of the fundamentals) in influencing asset prices. It is a basic tenet of this literature (e.g., Allen, Morris, and Shin (2006)) that when prices are driven by HOEs about fundamentals, they underweight private information (with respect to the optimal statistical weight) and are farther away from fundamentals compared to consensus. This result holds when liquidity trading is transient, in which case a unique equilibrium arises. Instead, when liquidity trading displays persistence, we find that the price also reflects investors average expectations about liquidity trading. In this case, along the equilibrium with high liquidity the price is actually more strongly tied to fundamentals compared to consensus, and overweights average private information (compared to the optimal statistical weight). 2 Along the equilibrium with low liquidity, however, the opposite happens. Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2008) study the role of higher order beliefs in asset prices in an infinite horizon model showing that higher order expectations add an additional term to the traditional asset pricing equation, the higher order wedge, which captures the discrepancy between the price of the asset and the average expectations of the fundamentals. Kondor (2009), in a model with short-term Bayesian traders, shows that public announcements may increase disagreement, generating high trading volume in equilibrium. Nimark (2007), in the context of Singleton (1987) s model, shows that under some conditions both the variance and the impact that expectations have on the price decrease as the order of expectations increases. Other authors have analyzed the role of higher order expectations in models where traders hold different initial beliefs about the liquidation value. Biais and Bossaerts (1998) show that departures from the common prior assumption rationalise peculiar trading patterns whereby traders with low private valuations may decide to buy an asset from traders with higher private valuations in the hope to resell it later on during the trading day at an even higher price. Cao and Ou-Yang (2005) study conditions for the existence of bubbles and panics in a model where traders opinions about the liquidation value differ. 3 Banerjee, Kaniel, and Kremer (2009) show that in a model with heterogeneous priors, differences in higher order beliefs may induce price drift. Ottaviani and Sørensen (2009), in a static model of a binary prediction market where agents hold heterogeneous prior beliefs and are wealth constrained (either exogenously, by the rules of the market, or because of their attitude towards risk), show that the fully revealing REE price underweights aggregate private information. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section we analyze the static benchmark. In the following section, we study the two-period extension and present the multiplicity result, relating it to liquidity traders persistence. In the following section we relate our results to the literature on Higher Order Expectations. We then draw the implications of 2 In a related paper, we show that a similar conclusion holds in a model with long term investors (see Cespa and Vives (2011)). 3 Kandel and Pearson (1995) provide empirical evidence supporting the non-common prior assumption. 4

5 our analysis for the literature on HFT, return regularities, and volume. In the final section we summarize our results discuss their empirical implications. Most of the proofs are relegated to the appendix. 1 The static benchmark Consider a one-period stock market where a single risky asset with liquidation value v, and a riskless asset with unitary return are traded by a continuum of risk-averse, informed investors in the interval [0, 1] together with liquidity traders. We assume that v N( v, τ 1 v ). Investors have CARA preferences (denote with γ the risk-tolerance coefficient) and maximize the expected utility of their wealth: W i = (v p)x i. 4 Prior to the opening of the market every informed investor i obtains private information on v, receiving a signal s i = v + ɛ i, ɛ i N(0, τ 1 ɛ ), and submits a demand schedule (generalized limit order) to the market X(s i, p) indicating the desired position in the risky asset for each realization of the equilibrium price. 5 Assume that v and ɛ i are independent for all i, and that error terms are also independent across investors. Liquidity traders submit a random demand u (independent of all other random variables in the model), where u N(0, τ 1 u ). Finally, we make the convention that, given v, the average signal 1 s 0 idi equals v almost surely (i.e. errors cancel out in the aggregate: 1 ɛ 0 idi = 0). 6 We denote by E i [Y ], Var i [Y ] the expectation and the variance of the random variable Y formed by an investor i, conditioning on the private and public information he has: E i [Y ] = E[Y s i, p], Var i [Y ] = Var[Y s i, p]. Finally, we denote by Ē[v] = 1 0 E i[v]di investors average opinion (the consensus opinion) about v. In the above CARA-normal framework, a symmetric rational expectations equilibrium (REE) is a set of trades contingent on the information that investors have, {X(s i, p) for i [0, 1]} and a price functional P (v, u) (measurable in (v, u)), such that the following two conditions hold: 1. Investors in [0, 1] optimize X(s i, p) arg max x i E [ exp { W i /γ} s i, p]. (1) 2. The market clears: 1 0 x i di + u = 0. (2) Given the above definition, it is easy to verify that a unique, symmetric equilibrium in linear strategies exists in the class of equilibria with a price functional of the form P (v, u) (see, e.g. Admati (1985), Vives (2008)). The equilibrium strategy of an investor i is given by X(s i, p) = a α E (E i [v] p), 4 We assume, without loss of generality with CARA preferences, that the non-random endowment of rational investors is zero. 5 The unique equilibrium in linear strategies of this model is symmetric. 6 See Section 3.1 in the Technical Appendix of Vives (2008) for a justification of the convention. 5

6 where a = γτ ɛ, (3) denotes the responsiveness to private information, τ i (Var i [v]) 1, and α E = τ ɛ /τ i is the optimal statistical (Bayesian) weight to private information. equilibrium price is given by where E[u p] = a(v E[v p]) + u, and Imposing market clearing the p = Ē[v] + α E a u (4) = E[v p] + ΛE[u p], (5) Λ = Var i1[v]. (6) γ Equations (4), and (5) show that the price can be given two alternative representations. According to the first one, the price reflects the consensus opinion investors hold about the liquidation value plus the impact of the demand from liquidity traders (multiplied by the risk-tolerance weighted uncertainty over the liquidation value). Indeed, in a static market owing to CARA and normality, an investor s demand is proportional to the expected gains from trade E i1 [v] p. As the price aggregates all investors demands, it reflects the consensus opinion Ē1[v] shocked by the orders of liquidity traders. According to (5), the anticipated impact of liquidity traders demand moves the price away from the semi-strong efficient price. Indeed, as investors are risk averse, when they accommodate an expectedly positive demand of liquidity traders, they require a compensation against the possibility that the liquidation value is higher than the public expectation (if instead E[u p] < 0, investors require to pay a price lower than E[v p] to cover the risk that v < E[v p]). Such a compensation is larger, the higher is the uncertainty investors face (captured by Λ) and the wider is their expected exposure to the liquidity traders shock (their expected inventory, E[u p]). Therefore, Λ captures the inventory related component of market liquidity. According to (5), $1-increase in liquidity traders demand has an additional impact on the price, through the effect it produces on E[v p]. This latter effect comes from the signal extraction problem dealers face in this market: since a > 0, if investors on average have good news they buy the asset, and the efficient price increases, reflecting this information. However, this effect cannot be told apart from the buying pressure of liquidity traders, which also makes the efficient price increase. This adverse selection effect adds to the inventory effect, implying that the (reciprocal of the) liquidity of the market is measured by dp/du: where τ = 1/Var[v p] = τ v + a 2 τ u. λ = Λ + (1 α E ) aτ u τ, Finally, note that the private signal in this case only serves to forecast the liquidation value v. In the next section we will argue that due to persistence, liquidity traders demand impacts the order flow across different trading dates. In this case, instead, investors also use their private 6

7 signals to extrapolate the demand of liquidity traders and anticipate the impact this has on future prices. This additional use of private information will be responsible for equilibrium multiplicity. 2 A two-period market with short term investors Consider now a two-period extension of the market analyzed in the previous section. At date 1 (2), a continuum of short-term investors in the interval [0, 1] enters the market, loads a position in the risky asset which it unwinds in period 2 (3). An investor i has CARA preferences (denote with γ the common risk-tolerance coefficient) and maximizes the expected utility of his short term profit π in = (p n+1 p n )x in, n = 1, 2 (we set p 0 = v and p 3 = v). 7 An investor i who enters the market in period 1 receives a signal s i = v + ɛ i which he recalls in the second period, where ɛ i N(0, τ 1 ɛ ), v and ɛ i are independent for all i. We make the convention that, given v, the average signal 1 s 0 idi equals v almost surely (i.e., errors cancel out in the aggregate 1 ɛ 0 idi = 0). We also assume that informed investors observe equilibrium prices and submit a linear demand schedule (generalized limit order): X 1 (s i, p 1 ) = a 2 s i ϕ 1 (p 1 ), and X 2 (s i, p 1, p 2 ) = a 2 s i ϕ 2 (p 1, p 2 ), indicating the desired position in the risky asset for each realization of the equilibrium price. The constant a n denotes the private signal responsiveness, while ϕ n ( ) is a linear function of the equilibrium prices. The position of liquidity traders is assumed to follow an AR(1) process: θ 1 = u 1 θ 2 = βθ 1 + u 2, (7) where β [0, 1] and {u 1, u 2 } is an i.i.d. normally distributed random process (independent of all other random variables in the model) with u n N(0, τ 1 u ). 8 If β = 1, {θ n } 2 n=1 follows a random walk and we are in the usual case of independent liquidity trade increments: u 2 = θ 2 θ 1 is independent from u 1 (e.g., Kyle (1985), Vives (1995)). If β = 0, then liquidity trading is i.i.d. across periods (this is the case considered by Allen et al. (2006)). 9 This random process could be interpreted in the following way. Denote by x n the aggregate position of informed investors at time n: x n = 1 0 x indi. In the first period, informed investors clear the position of liquidity traders: x 1 + θ 1 = 0. Suppose 0 < β < 1, then in the second period market clearing involves (i) the reverting position of first period informed investors x 1, (ii) the position of second period informed investors x 2, (iii) a fraction 1 β of the first period liquidity traders position θ 1 (who revert), 7 We assume, without loss of generality, that the non-random endowment of investors is zero. 8 The AR(1) assumption for liquidity traders demand is not new in the literature. For instance, He and Wang (1995) and Cespa and Vives (2011) consider a model with long term investors in which liquidity trading is generated by an AR(1) process. 9 For empirical evidence on the persistence in liquidity traders demand see Chordia and Subrahmanyam (2004), Easley et al. (2008), and Hendershott and Seasholes (2009). 7

8 and (iv) the new generation of liquidity traders with demand u 2. Letting x 2 x 2 x 1, θ 2 θ 2 θ 1 = u 2 (1 β)θ 1, market clearing implies x 2 x 1 + u 2 (1 β)θ 1 = 0 x 2 + θ 2 = 0 x 2 + βθ 1 + u 2 = 0. Hence, at date 2 a fraction (1 β)θ 1 of first period liquidity trades reverts. The lower is β, the higher is the fraction of reverting first period liquidity trades. Thus, assuming persistence in liquidity trades allows to model in a parsimonious way the possibility that agents in the market have different horizons: when β = 0 each generation of informed investors and liquidity traders have the same investment horizon; as β grows, investment horizons become increasingly different (see Table 1). Please insert Table 1 here. We denote by E in [Y ] = E[Y s i, p n ], E n [Y ] = E[Y p n ], Var in [Y ] = Var[Y s i, p n ], and Var n [Y ] = Var[Y p n ], respectively the expectation and variance of the random variable Y formed by a trader conditioning on the private and public information he has at time n, and that obtained conditioning on public information only. The variables τ n and τ in denote instead the precisions of the investors forecasts of v based only on public and on public and private information: τ n = (1/Var n [v]), and τ in = (1/Var in [v]). More in detail, consider a candidate linear (symmetric) equilibrium x i1 = a 1 s i ϕ 1 (p 1 ), x i2 = a 2 s i ϕ 2 (p 1, p 2 ). Letting x n 1 0 x indi, and imposing market clearing in the first period implies (due to our convention): x 1 + θ 1 = 0 a 1 v + θ } {{ } 1 = ϕ 1 (p 1 ), (8) z 1 where the intercept of the first period aggregate demand z 1 a 1 v + θ 1 denotes the informational content of the first period order flow. In the second period the market clearing condition is x 2 + βθ 1 + u 2 = 0 x 2 βx 1 + u 2 = 0 a 2 v ϕ 2 (p 1, p 2 ) β(a 1 v ϕ 1 (p 1 )) + u 2 = 0 a 2 v + u } {{ } 2 = ϕ 2 (p 1, p 2 ) βϕ 1 (p 1 ), (9) z 2 where in the second line we use (8), while in the third we let a 2 a 2 βa 1, and denote by z 2 a 2 v + u 2 the informational content of the second period order flow. From (8) and (9) it is easy to see that the sequence {z 1, z 2 } is observationally equivalent to {p 1, p 2 }. Therefore, E n [v] = τ 1 n (τ v + τ n u t=1 a tz t ), Var n [v] = (τ v + τ n u t=1 ( a t) 2 ) 1, E in [v] = τ 1 in (τ ne n [v] + τ ɛ s i ), and Var in [v] = (τ n + τ ɛ ) 1. The consensus opinion about the fundamentals at time n is denoted by Ēn[v] 1 E 0 in[v]di. Letting α En = τ ɛ /τ in, we have E in [v] = α En s in + (1 α En )E n [v], and due to our convention Ē n [v] = α En v + (1 α En )E n [v]. 8

9 2.1 Equilibrium analysis We start by giving a general description of the equilibrium. The following proposition characterises equilibrium prices: Proposition 1. At a linear equilibrium of the market the price is given by ( p n = α Pn v + θ ) n + (1 α Pn )E n [v], (10) a n where θ n = u n + βθ n 1, and a n, α Pn, respectively denote the responsiveness to private information displayed by investors and by the price at time n. The price impact is measured by dp n /du n : λ n = α P n + (1 α Pn ) a nτ u. (11) a n τ n According to (10), at period n the equilibrium price is a weighted average of the market expectation about the fundamentals v, and the (noisy) average private information held by investors. Manipulating this expression we can separate the total impact of news from that of past information in the second period price: p 2 = α P 2 (a 2 v ± βa 1 v + θ 2 ) + (1 α P2 )E 2 [v] a 2 = ( αp2 a 2 + (1 α P2 ) a 2τ u τ 2 Similarly, in the first period we have p 1 = ( αp1 a 1 + (1 α P1 ) a 1τ u τ 1 which together with (12) justifies the expression in (11). A different rearrangement of (10) yields ) z 2 + βα P 2 a 2 z 1 + (1 α P2 ) τ 1 τ 2 E 1 [v]. (12) ) z 1 + (1 α P1 ) τ v τ 1 v, (13) p n E n [v] = α P n a n (a n (v E n [v]) + θ n ) (14) = Λ n E n [θ n ], where Λ n α Pn /a n, implying that there is a discrepancy between p n and E n [v] which, as in (5), captures a premium which is proportional to the expected stock of liquidity trading that investors accommodate at n. The assumption of short-term investment horizons, together with that of persistence in liquidity trading have important implications for the equilibrium of the market. We analyze these implications in the following results: Corollary 1. At a linear equilibrium, the price incorporates a premium above the semi-strong efficient price: where p n = E n [v] + Λ n E n [θ n ], (15) Λ 1 = Var i1[p 2 ] γ + βλ 2 (16) Λ 2 = Var i2[v]. (17) γ 9

10 Comparing (16) with (6), shows that short term trading affects the inventory component of liquidity. In a static market when investors absorb the demand of liquidity traders, they are exposed to the risk coming from the randomness of v. In a dynamic market, short term investors at date 1 face instead the risk due to the randomness of the following period price (at which they unwind). As liquidity trading displays persistence, second period informed investors absorb part of first period liquidity traders position and this contributes to first period investors uncertainty over p 2, yielding (16). Our assumptions on investors horizons also allows us to capture an important feature of High Frequency Trading. Indeed, as liquidity traders demand displays persistence, first period informed investors can infer it from the observation of the order flow using their private signals, to anticipate the impact this will have on the price at which they will unwind their positions. This allows them to trade ahead of liquidity traders. 10 Indeed, using (10) and (14): [ ( E i1 [p 2 ] = E i1 α P2 v + θ ) ] 2 + (1 α P2 )E 2 [v] a 2 ( = α P2 + (1 α P2 ) ( a ) 2) 2 τ u E i1 [v] + βλ 2 E i1 [θ 1 ] + (1 α P2 ) τ 1 E 1 [v]. (18) τ 2 τ 2 According to the above expression, when β > 0 the private signal serves two objectives: it allows to predict the impact of fundamentals on p 2, but it also creates a private learning channel from the first period price that allows investors to recover information on θ 1 from the observation of p 1 to predict the impact of θ 2 on p 2 (as in Amador and Weill (2010), and Manzano and Vives (2011)). This yields multiple equilibria: Proposition 2. Linear equilibria always exist. In equilibrium, a 2 = γτ ɛ, and a 1 is implicitly defined by the equation φ(a 1 ) a 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 ) γ 2 τ u a 2 τ ɛ = 0 If β (0, 1]: 1. There are two equilibria a 1, a 1, where a 1 < a 1 (see (A.17), and (A.18), in the appendix for explicit expressions). 2. When a 1 = a 1, a 2 βa 1 > 0, and λ 2 > 0, while when a 1 = a 1, a 2 βa 1 < 0, and λ 2 < 0. Furthermore, λ 2 < λ 2, and prices are more informative along the equilibrium with high second period liquidity. If β = 0, the equilibrium is unique: a 1 = lim β 0 a 1 = γa2 2τ u 1 + γa 2 τ u. (19) Due to persistence, liquidity traders positions in the first and second period are positively correlated. Thus, informed investors use their private signals on the fundamentals also to infer the demand of liquidity traders from the first period price, to anticipate the price at which they 10 This type of inference is a well documented feature of High Frequency Trading who use specific algorithms to detect the large orders that liquidity traders split across several trading rounds, in an attempt to minimize price impact, and profitably exploit them (see, e.g., Scott Patterson (June 30, 2010). Fast Traders Face Off with Big Investors Over Gaming, Wall Street Journal.) 10

11 unwind their positions. The more the second period price is correlated to the fundamentals, the more aggressively first period investors speculate on private information. As a consequence, the first period price reflects more the fundamentals, and less the demand of liquidity traders. This, in turn, leads first period investors to put more weight on the private signal to extrapolate the demand of liquidity traders from the price, making the first and second period price more related to fundamentals. In this case, this self-reinforcing loop leads investors to escalate their response to private information. Similarly, the less correlated is the second period price with the fundamentals, the less aggressively first period investors speculate on their private information. But then, the first period price reflects less the fundamentals, and more the demand of first period liquidity traders. This lowers the weight investors put on their private signals to infer the demand of liquidity traders from the price, and makes the first and second period price less related to fundamentals. In this case, instead, the self-reinforcing loop leads investors to dampen their response to private information (see Figure 1). Along the former equilibrium, prices are more informative about the fundamentals and the second period market is thicker. Conversely, along the latter equilibrium, prices are more informative about the demand of liquidity traders, and the second period market is thinner. When β = 0, liquidity trading is transient, and first period investors cannot use their information on θ 1 to forecast p 2. This eliminates the private learning channel from the first period price and yields a unique equilibrium. Note that along the equilibrium with high liquidity λ 2 < 0, implying that a positive realization of the news in the order flow (z 2 > 0) leads to a decrease in the second period price. The reason for this result is that a 1 > a 2 /β, and thus ( a 2 ) = a 2 βa 1 < 0, so that in the second period, informed investors reduce their exposure to the risky assed based on private information. As a consequence, if z 2 = ( a 2 ) v + u 2 > 0, it could be that v < 0 or that u 2 > 0, which leads the market to update downwards its assessment of the fundamentals, and negatively update the price. Please insert figure 1 here. The next result characterizes investors strategies: Corollary 2. At a linear equilibrium, a rational investor s strategies are given by X 1 (s i, p 1 ) = a 1 α E1 (E i1 [v] p 1 ) + α P 1 α E1 α E1 E 1 [θ 1 ] (20) X 2 (s i, p 2 ) = a 2 α E2 (E i2 [v] p 2 ). (21) When β (0, 1] and (i) a 1 = a 1, α P1 α P1 < α E1. < α E1, and when (ii) a 1 = a 1, α P1 > α E1. For β = 0, According to (21), in the second period an investor acts like in a static market. In the first period, instead, he loads his position anticipating the second period price, and scaling it down according to the uncertainty he faces on p 2 : X 1 (s i, p 1 ) = γ E i1[p 2 ] p 1. Var i1 [p 2 ] 11

12 In this case, his strategy can be expressed as the sum of two components (see (20)). The first component captures the investor s activity based on his private estimation of the difference between the fundamentals and the n-th period equilibrium price. This may be seen as akin to long-term speculative trading, aimed at taking advantage of the investor s superior information on the liquidation value of the asset, since p 2 is correlated with v. The second component captures the investor s activity based on the extraction of order flow, i.e. public, information. This trading is instead aimed at timing the market by exploiting short-run movements in the asset price determined by the evolution of the future aggregate demand. Indeed, using the expressions in Corollary 1: E 1 [p 2 p 1 ] = Var i1[p 2 ] E 1 [θ 1 ], (22) γ which implies that based on public information the investor expects reversion. However, the position he takes depends on the difference α P1 α E1 : when α P1 α E1 < 0 he engages in market making (thereby accommodating the aggregate demand), when α P1 α E1 > 0 he chases the trend (and thus follows the market). To fix ideas, suppose that E 1 [θ 1 ] > 0. Given that E 1 [θ 1 ] = a 1 (v E 1 [v]) + θ 1, an investor s reaction to this observation depends on whether he believes it to be driven by liquidity trades or fundamentals information. According to Proposition 2, when a 1 = a 1, the first period price reflects less the fundamentals (and thus more the demand of liquidity traders), which leads to infer that E 1 [θ 1 ] > 0 is due to the impact of liquidity traders orders. As a consequence α P1 < α E1, and investors speculate on reversion. When instead a 1 = a 1, the first period price reflects more the fundamentals (and thus less the demand of liquidity traders). In this case, E 1 [θ 1 ] > 0 is more likely to reflect the average private signal of informed investors, α P1 > α E1, and investors speculate on continuation. As the persistence in liquidity trading increases, in both equilibria first period informed investors speculate less aggressively on their private information. Indeed, in this case the first period price is more informative about θ 2, which leads investors to lower the weight to private information in both equilibria: Corollary 3. At equilibrium for all β (0, 1), a 1 / β < 0. Proof. The equation that yields the first period responsiveness to private information is given by: φ(a 1 ) λ 2 τ i2 a 1 γ a 2 τ u τ ɛ = 0. The result then follows immediately, since from implicit differentiation of the above with respect to β: a 1 β = γτ u a 1 (a 2 a 1 ) (1 + γτ u a 2 ) + γβτ u (a 2 a 1 ) < 0, independently of the equilibrium that arises; in the low liquidity equilibrium we have βa 1 < a 1 < a 2 γτ ɛ, and in the high liquidity equilibrium a 1 > a 2 /β > a 2 and 1 + γτ u a 2 < 0. 12

13 We conclude this section, showing that absent private information, equilibrium multiplicity disappears when β > 0. In this case prices are invertible in the demand of liquidity traders, and the model is akin to Grossman and Miller (1988): Corollary 4. When τ ɛ = 0, β [0, 1] there exists a unique equilibrium where Λ 2 = Var[v]/γ, and p n = v + Λ n θ n (23) X n (θ n ) = Λ 1 n (p n v), (24) Λ 1 = Var 1[p 2 ] γ + βλ 2. According to (24), rational investors always take the other side of the order flow, buying the asset at a discount when θ n < 0, and selling it at a premium otherwise. For a given realization of the innovation in liquidity traders demand u n, the larger is Λ n, the larger is the adjustment in the price rational investors require in order to absorb it. Therefore, Λ n proxies for the liquidity of the market. Uniqueness follows from the absence of private information. Indeed, in this case prices are invertible in the demand of liquidity traders and the feedback loop responsible for equilibrium multiplicity disappears. 2.2 Stability In this section we analyze the stability of the equilibrium solutions. We start by defining the best response function which determines the equilibrium responsiveness to private information of a first period investor, given the decision made by the other first period investors. From the expression for φ(a 1 ) in Proposition 2, an equilibrium obtains as a solution to the following fixed point equation a 1 = ψ(a 1 ) γ a 2 a 2 τ u. (25) 1 + γτ u a 2 Analizing the best response function ψ(a 1 ) it is possible to see that it is discontinuous for a 1 = (γτ u β) 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 ): lim ψ(a 1) = (26) a 1 ((γτ uβ) 1 (1+γτ ua 2 )) lim ψ(a 1) =, (27) a 1 ((γτ uβ) 1 (1+γτ ua 2 )) + and that the decisions on the weights investors put on private information are always strategic substitutes: ψ(a 1 ) βa 2 τ u = < 0. (28) a 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 ) 2 The reason for the existence of this discontinuity is that with persistence, first period investors unwind their position against the second period aggregate demand x 2 + u 2, and thus their average private information impacts both the first and second period order flows. Indeed, recall from (8) and (9) that z 1 = a 1 v + u 1, z 2 = a 2 v + u 2, 13

14 where a 2 = a 2 βa 1. This, in turn, has implications for the inference the market makes from the second period order flow. At equilibrium a large value of a 1 has two effects: first (according to the first of the above expressions), it increases the impact of fundamentals information vis-àvis that of liquidity trades in the first period price; second, if β > 0 it also changes the impact that the fundamentals information in the second period order flow has on the second period price (see the second expression above). This can potentially reduce the uncertainty faced by first period investors. Indeed, we have that Cov i1 [E 2 [v], E 2 [θ 2 ]] = a 2τ u (τ 2 a 2 a 2 τ u ) Var τ 2 i1 [z 2 ], (29) 2 and since along the equilibrium with high liquidity a 2 < 0, Cov i1 [E 2 [v], E 2 [θ 2 ]] < 0 Var i1 [p 2 ] < Var i1 [E 2 [v]] + Λ 2 2Var i1 [E 2 [θ 2 ]]. (30) Therefore, by speculating aggressively on their private information, first period investors can make the (conditional) correlation across the two components of the second period price negative, reducing the risk to which they are exposed when clearing the market. In fact, according to (30), a positive shock from liquidity traders (u 2 > 0) has two countervailing impacts on p 2 : first, a positive one, due to its effect on the expected inventory of the second period investors; second, a negative one due to the impact it has on the second period market expectation about the fundamentals. When a 1 = (γτ u β) 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 ) Var i1 [E 2 [v]] + Λ 2 2Var i1 [E 2 [θ 2 ]] = 2Λ 2 Cov i1 [E 2 [v], E 2 [θ 2 ]], so that the second period price is entirely determined by first period information, and Var i1 [p 2 ] = 0. Plotting ψ(a 1 ) together with the 45-degree line, and using (26), (27), and (28) we see that the solution space of the fixed point equation is divided in two intervals: the first one is (0, (γτ u β) 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 )), and the second one is ((γτ u β) 1 (1 + γτ u a 2 ), ). The equilibrium with low (high) liquidity falls in the first (second) region (see Figure 2). Please insert Figure 2 here. To analyze stability, consider the following argument. Assume that the market is at an equilibrium point â 1, so that â 1 = ψ(â 1 ). Suppose now that a small perturbation to â 1 occurs, which makes the first period price informationally equivalent to z 1 = â 1v+u 1. As a consequence, first period investors modify their weights to private information so that the aggregate weight becomes â 1 = ψ(â 1). If the market goes back to the original â 1 according to the best reply dynamics with the best response function ψ( ), then the equilibrium is stable. Otherwise it is unstable. Formally, we have the following definition: Definition 1. An equilibrium is stable (unstable) if and only if its corresponding value for a 1 is a stable (unstable) fixed point for the best response function ψ( ) (i.e., if and only if its corresponding value for a 1 satisfies ψ (a 1 ) < 1 ). 14

15 With this definition it is immediate to verify that ψ (a 1) < 1, ψ (a 1 ) > 1, (31) implying that the equilibrium with high responsiveness to private information and high liquidity is unstable according to the best reply dynamics. 3 Average expectations and reliance on public information In this section we show that persistence makes the first period price driven by investors HOEs about fundamentals and by their average expectations about liquidity trading. This, in turn, has implications for price reliance on public information. Starting from the second period, and imposing market clearing yields 1 Due to CARA and normality, we have 0 X 2 (s i2, z 2 )di + θ 2 = 0. (32) X 2 (s i2, z 2 ) = γ E i2[v] p 2. Var i2 [v] Replacing the above in (32) and solving for the equilibrium price we obtain p 2 = Ē2[v] + Λ 2 θ 2, where Λ 2 = Var i2 [v]/γ. Similarly, in the first period, imposing market clearing yields: 1 and solving for the equilibrium price we obtain 0 X 1 (s i1, z 1 )di + θ 1 = 0, Substituting the above obtained expression for p 2 in (33) yields p 1 = Ē1[p 2 ] + Var i1[p 2 ] θ 1. (33) γ ] Var i1 [p 2 ] p 1 = [Ē2 Ē1 [v] + Λ 2 θ 2 + θ 1 γ = [Ē2 Ē1 [v] ] + βλ 2 Ē 1 [θ 1 ] + Var i1[p 2 ] θ 1. (34) γ According to (34), there are three terms that form the second period price: investors second order average expectations over the liquidation value (Ē1[Ē2[v]]), the risk-adjusted impact of the first period stock of liquidity trades (θ 1 ), and investors average expectations over first period liquidity trades (Ē1[θ 1 ]). As liquidity trades are persistent, rational investors anticipate unwinding a fraction β of their inventory (θ 1 ) to second period investors, thereby affecting their exposure to the risky asset and thus p 2. Using their private signals, first period investors can 15

16 estimate θ 1 from the observation of the order imbalance, which makes p 1 reflect the first period market consensus over the size of liquidity traders demand. Expression (34) implies that due to persistence in liquidity trading, the weight placed by the price on investors average information is the sum of two terms: the first term captures the impact of HOEs on v, the second term reflects the impact of investors average expectations over θ 1. Computing where Ē 1 [Ē2 [v] ] = ᾱ E1 v + (1 ᾱ E1 ) E 1 [v] Ē 1 [θ 1 ] = a 1 (1 α E1 )(v E 1 [v]) + θ 1, ( ᾱ E1 = α E1 1 τ ) 1 (1 α E2 ), τ 2 which implies that the total weight the price places on average private information is given by α P1 = ᾱ E1 + βλ 2 a 1 (1 α E1 ). Note that β, ᾱ E1 < α E1. This implies that when liquidity trading is transient (β = 0) the first period price places a larger weight on public information than the optimal statistical weight. This finding is in line with Morris and Shin (2002), and Allen et al. (2006). The latter prove that with heterogeneous information, prices reflect investors HOEs about the final payoff. In this case, the law of iterated expectations does not hold, and investors forecasts overweight public information because these anticipate the average market opinion knowing that this also depends on the public information observed by other investors. The price is then systematically farther away from fundamentals compared to investors consensus. However, as shown above when β > 0, the price also reflects investors average expectations about the impact that the demand of first period liquidity traders has on the second period price. Thus, an additional term adds to ᾱ E1 a 1 > which for α E1 βλ 2 (1 α E1 ), can increase the weight placed on average private information above the optimal statistical weight. Due to Corollary 2 we then have Corollary 5. At equilibrium, 1. When β (0, 1], if { a 1, then α P1 < α E1, and Cov[p 1, v] < Cov[Ē1[v], v] a 1 = a 1, then α P1 > α E1, and Cov[p 1, v] > Cov[Ē1[v], v]. 2. When β = 0, α P1 < α E1 and Cov[p 1, v] < Cov[Ē1[v], v]. With persistence liquidity traders positions in the first and second period are positively correlated. Thus, investors use their private signals to infer the demand of liquidity traders 16

17 from the order flow, anticipating the impact this has on the next period price. As private signals are informative about the fundamentals, this increases the weight the first period price assigns to the average private information. Along the equilibrium with high liquidity, investors escalate their response to private information. In this case the extra weight that adds to ᾱ E1 is high enough to draw the price closer to fundamentals compared to consensus. In view of the results obtained in Section 2.2 this equilibrium is, however, unstable. Along the equilibrium with low liquidity the price is farther away from fundamentals compared to consensus. This equilibrium, which shares the same properties of the one found by Allen et al. (2006), is instead stable. 4 Implications In this section we discuss several implications of our results. 4.1 High Frequency Trading Our model can shed light on the impact that heterogeneous trading frequencies have on market liquidity. In particular, when β > 0, we can interpret the informed traders as HFTs that are able to turn around their positions at a higher speed compared to liquidity traders. The case β = 0 captures the extreme situation in which the technological features of HFT are available to all liquidity traders too, whereas when β = 1 the technological gap between HFT and liquidity trading is maximal. Formally, the sequence of events for the first period liquidity traders is illustrated in Figure 3. Please insert Figure 3 here. The expected profit that first period liquidity traders obtain is given by Π θ1 E[βθ 1 (v p 1 ) + (1 β)θ 1 (p 2 p 1 )] ( ( )) τ i1 τ v = βλ 1 + (1 β)λ 2 a 2 τ 1 u < 0. (35) a 1 τ i1 It is easy to see that along the high liquidity equilibrium lim β 0 Π θ1 = 0, since in this case the first period signal responsiveness diverges at β = 0 (see Corollary 3). On the contrary, along the equilibrium with low liquidity lim Π θ 1 = Π θ1 < 0. β 0 a1 = γa2 2 τu,β=0 1+γa 2 τu In general, plotting (35) along the two equilibria that arise with β > 0 one obtains Figure 4. Please insert Figure 4 here. Depending on parameters values the two plots intersect or not (we need τ v high for them to intersect), but the bottomline is that for β small, liquidity traders expected losses are always 17

18 smaller along the high liquidity equilibrium (in the second period the conclusion is immediate given the properties of the equilibrium). Several authors suggest that the introduction of algorithmic trading and high frequency trading have generated a large improvement in market liquidity accompanied by a reduction in adverse selection risk (see, e.g. Hendershott, Menkveld, and Jones (2011)). This finding would be consistent with the high liquidity equilibrium where, short of profitable speculative opportunities, informed investors in the second period lower their exposure to the risky asset (see Proposition 2), adverse selection decreases across the two periods, and the first period price under-relies on public information (and thus over-relies on private information, see Corollary 5). 11 Our model sheds light on the issue of whether HFT increases or decreases liquidity. both equilibria we see that a higher technological advantage of HFT (higher β) leads to higher expected losses of first period liquidity traders. A further implication of our model is that with differential information, the existence of a discrepancy in the speed at which different types of investors can turn around their positions can be responsible for indeterminacy. The presence of HFTs leads to equilibrium multiplicity with the outcome of either instability at a high liquidity equilibrium, or a stable equilibrium with low liquidity. 4.2 Momentum and reversal In this section we compute the autocovariance of returns at different trading horizons. A first implication of our model is that return autocorrelation depends on trading horizons, and on the equilibrium on which investors coordinate: Corollary 6. At equilibrium: 1. For all β [0, 1], Cov[p 2 p 1, p 1 v] < For β (0, 1], Cov[v p 2, p 1 v] < 0. For β = 0, Cov[v p 2, p 1 v] = For β (0, 1], along the equilibrium with high liquidity Cov[v p 2, p 2 p 1 ] > 0. Along the equilibrium with low liquidity, for τ v < ˆτ v, there exists a value ˆβ such that for all β > ˆβ, Cov[v p 2, p 2 p 1 ] > 0 (the expression for ˆτ v is given in the appendix, see equation (A.31)). If β = 0, Cov[v p 2, p 2 p 1 ] < 0. According to the above result, along the equilibrium with high liquidity, momentum occurs at short horizons (close to the end of the trading horizon), whereas at a longer horizon, returns 11 If we measure adverse selection at time n via the OLS conditional regression coefficient of the liquidation value over the time n informational addition (that is the term multiplying (1 α Pn ) in the adverse selection component of liquidity at n), we can verify that along the high liquidity equilibrium adverse selection decreases between periods 1 and 2. To see this, note that along the high liquidity equilibrium adverse selection at time 1 is a 1 τ u /τ 1, whereas at time 2 we have (a 2 βa 1 )τ u /τ 2. As in this case a 2 < 0, we look at the absolute value and check that a 1 /τ 1 > a 1 /τ 2 > a 2 /τ 2. The first inequality is trivially always satisfied, whereas the second one requires a 1 > a 2 /(1 + β), a condition that is always satisfied along the equilibrium with high liquidity. In 18

19 display reversal. 12 This is in line with the empirical findings on return anomalies that document the existence of positive return autocorrelation at short horizons (ranging from six to twelve months, see Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)), and negative autocorrelation at long horizons (from three to five years, see De Bondt and Thaler (1985)). It is interesting to relate this result with Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998) who assume that overconfident investors underestimate the dispersion of the error term affecting their signals and overreact to private information. This, in turn, generates long term reversal and, in the presence of confirming public information which due to biased self attribution boosts investors confidence, also lead to short term positive return autocorrelation. This pattern of overreaction, continuation, and correction is likely to affect stocks which are more difficult to value (e.g., growth stocks). In such a context, momentum is thus a symptom of mispricing and hence related to prices wandering away from fundamentals (conversely, reversal is identified with price corrections). In our model, along the equilibrium with high liquidity, investors rationally react more strongly to their private signals compared to the static benchmark, in contrast to the overreaction effect of the behavioral literature. 13 However, this heavy reaction to private information leads to stronger information impounding and to prices that track better the fundamentals (see Proposition 2). Momentum at short horizons in this case is therefore associated with a rapid convergence of the price to the full information value. To illustrate this fact, in Figure 5 we plot the mean price paths along the equilibrium with low liquidity (thick line), with high liquidity (thin line), and along the static equilibrium, that is the one that would obtain if investors reacted to information as if they were in a static market (dotted line). From the plot it is apparent that in the equilibrium with high liquidity the price displays a faster adjustment to the full information value than in the equilibrium with low liquidity (and the static equilibrium). This shows that the occurrence of momentum is not at odds with price efficiency. Please insert figure 5 here. As stated in the corollary, momentum can also occur along the equilibrium with low liquidity, provided that investors are sufficiently uncertain about the liquidation value prior to trading (that is, τ v is low) and that liquidity trading is sufficiently persistent (β high). In that equilibrium, investors respond less to private information, information impounding is staggered, and prices adjust more slowly to the full information value (see Figure 2). However, if sufficiently persistent, liquidity trading exerts a continuous price pressure which can eventually outweigh the former effect. Therefore, along this equilibrium momentum arises with slow convergence to the full information value, implying that the occurrence of a positive autocorrelation at short horizons per se does not allow to unconditionally identify the informational properties of prices. 12 The fact that Cov[p 2 p 1, p 1 v] < 0 is due to the initial effect, p 0 = v. Numerical simulations show that in a model with three periods, in the equilibrium with high liquidity, both Cov[v p 3, p 3 p 2 ] and Cov[p 3 p 2, p 2 p 1 ] are positive. 13 Indeed, the static solution calls for a 1 = γτ ɛ (see, e.g, Admati (1985), or Vives (2008)), and it is easy to verify that 0 < a 1 < γτ ɛ < a 1. In Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998) overconfident investors overweight private information in relation to the prior. 19

20 Finally, at long horizons, the effect of private information on the correlation of returns washes out and the only driver of the autocovariance is the persistence in liquidity trading, which generates reversal. 4.3 Expected volume and return predictability In this section we investigate the implications of our results for the expected volume of informational trading and the predictability of returns along the two equilibria. We show that the expected volume of informational trading is high (low) along the high (low) liquidity equilibrium. This implies that a high volume of informational trading predicts momentum, in line with the evidence presented by Llorente, Michaely, Saar, and Wang (2002). However, as we have argued in the previous section, also along the equilibrium with low liquidity momentum can occur, provided liquidity trading displays sufficiently strong persistence (and the ex-ante uncertainty about the liquidation value is sufficiently high). This implies that a low volume of informational trading can also predict continuation. In this case, though, momentum is a signal of slow price convergence to the liquidation value. In sum, momentum is compatible with both a high and a low volume of informational trading, but the implications that return continuation has for price informativeness are markedly different in the two situations. We start by defining the volume of informational trading as the expected traded volume in the market with heterogeneous information net of the expected volume that obtains in the market with no private information analyzed in Corollary 4. This yields: 14 and V 2 = = π V 1 = = π 1 E [ X 1 (s i1, z 1 ) ] di E [ X 1 (θ 1 ) ] di π Var [X 1(s i1, z 1 )]di 0 π Var [X 1(θ 1 )]di ( a 2 1τ 1 ɛ + τ 1 u ) τ 1 u, (36) 1 E [ X2 (s i2, z 2 ) X 1 (s i1, z 1 ) ] di E [ X 2 (θ 2 ) X 1 (θ 1 ) ] di π Var [X 2(s i2, z 2 ) X 1 (s i1, z 1 )]di 0 π Var [X 2(θ 2 ) X 1 (θ 1 )]di ( (a a 2 2)τ 1 ɛ + (1 + (β 1) 2 )τ 1 u ) (1 + (β 1) 2 )τ 1 u. (37) We measure the total volume of informational trading with V 1 + V 2, and obtain Corollary 7. At equilibrium, for all β (0, 1] the expected volume of informational trading is higher along the high liquidity equilibrium. When β = 0 only the equilibrium with a low volume of informational trading survives. 14 This is consistent with He and Wang (1995). 20

Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading

Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading Giovanni Cespa 1 and Xavier Vives 2 1 Cass Business School, and CEPR 2 IESE Business School Introduction Liquidity and asset pricing: role

More information

Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading

Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading Higher Order Expectations, Illiquidity, and Short-term Trading Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives February 2011 Abstract We propose a theory that jointly accounts for an asset illiquidity and for the asset

More information

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives November 2012 Abstract Multiple equilibria arise in a finite horizon market whenever risk averse traders have incentives

More information

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek Review of Economic Studies 2012 79, 539 580 doi: 10.1093/restud/rdr040 The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Review of Economic Studies Limited. Advance access publication

More information

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives January 2014 Abstract We consider a two-period market with persistent liquidity trading and risk averse privately informed

More information

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading draft under revision

Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading draft under revision Expectations, Liquidity, and Short-term Trading draft under revision Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives September 03 Abstract We consider a two-period market with persistent liquidity trading and risk averse

More information

The Beauty Contest and Short-Term Trading

The Beauty Contest and Short-Term Trading WORKING PAPER NO. 383 The Beauty Contest and Short-Term Trading Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives November 2014 University of Naples Federico II University of Salerno Bocconi University, Milan CSEF - Centre

More information

News Trading and Speed

News Trading and Speed News Trading and Speed Thierry Foucault, Johan Hombert, and Ioanid Rosu (HEC) High Frequency Trading Conference Plan Plan 1. Introduction - Research questions 2. Model 3. Is news trading different? 4.

More information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information

On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Notes on On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock Markets Where Traders Have Diverse Information by Sanford Grossman This model shows how the heterogeneous information

More information

News Trading and Speed

News Trading and Speed News Trading and Speed Thierry Foucault, Johan Hombert, Ioanid Roşu (HEC Paris) 6th Financial Risks International Forum March 25-26, 2013, Paris Johan Hombert (HEC Paris) News Trading and Speed 6th Financial

More information

Toxic Arbitrage. Abstract

Toxic Arbitrage. Abstract Toxic Arbitrage Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan Wing Wah Tham Abstract Arbitrage opportunities arise when new information affects the price of one security because dealers in other related securities are

More information

Financial Market Microstructure Theory

Financial Market Microstructure Theory The Microstructure of Financial Markets, de Jong and Rindi (2009) Financial Market Microstructure Theory Based on de Jong and Rindi, Chapters 2 5 Frank de Jong Tilburg University 1 Determinants of the

More information

Short-Term Investment and Equilibrium Multiplicity.

Short-Term Investment and Equilibrium Multiplicity. Short-Term Investment and Equilibrium Multiplicity. Giovanni Cespa First draft: June 2000 This draft: June 2002 Abstract I study the effects of the heterogeneity of traders horizons in a 2-period NREE

More information

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow

Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow Goal Market Maker Pricing and Information about Prospective Order Flow EIEF October 9 202 Use a risk averse market making model to investigate. [Microstructural determinants of volatility, liquidity and

More information

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek Giovanni Cespa and Xavier Vives First Version: October 2006 September 2007 Abstract We investigate the dynamics of prices, information and expectations

More information

Algorithmic trading Equilibrium, efficiency & stability

Algorithmic trading Equilibrium, efficiency & stability Algorithmic trading Equilibrium, efficiency & stability Presentation prepared for the conference Market Microstructure: Confronting many viewpoints Institut Louis Bachelier Décembre 2010 Bruno Biais Toulouse

More information

News Trading and Speed

News Trading and Speed News Trading and Speed Thierry Foucault Johan Hombert Ioanid Roşu September 5, 01 Abstract Informed trading can take two forms: (i) trading on more accurate information or (ii) trading on public information

More information

Information Asymmetry, Price Momentum, and the Disposition Effect

Information Asymmetry, Price Momentum, and the Disposition Effect Information Asymmetry, Price Momentum, and the Disposition Effect Günter Strobl The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania October 2003 Job Market Paper Abstract Economists have long been puzzled by

More information

Stock Returns Following Profit Warnings: A Test of Models of Behavioural Finance.

Stock Returns Following Profit Warnings: A Test of Models of Behavioural Finance. Stock Returns Following Profit Warnings: A Test of Models of Behavioural Finance. G. Bulkley, R.D.F. Harris, R. Herrerias Department of Economics, University of Exeter * Abstract Models in behavioural

More information

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns

Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Discussion of Momentum and Autocorrelation in Stock Returns Joseph Chen University of Southern California Harrison Hong Stanford University Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) document individual stock momentum:

More information

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Markets. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Financial Markets Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Trading and Price Formation This line of the literature analyzes the formation of prices in financial markets in a setting

More information

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders

Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Understanding pricing anomalies in prediction and betting markets with informed traders Peter Norman Sørensen Økonomi, KU GetFIT, February 2012 Peter Norman Sørensen (Økonomi, KU) Prediction Markets GetFIT,

More information

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion *

A Simple Model of Price Dispersion * Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper No. 112 http://www.dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0112.pdf A Simple Model of Price Dispersion

More information

Complementarities in information acquisition with short-term trades

Complementarities in information acquisition with short-term trades Theoretical Economics (007), 441 467 1555-7561/0070441 Complementarities in information acquisition with short-term trades CHRISTOPHE CHAMLEY Paris-Jourdan Sciences Économiques and Department of Economics,

More information

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans

Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Life Cycle Asset Allocation A Suitable Approach for Defined Contribution Pension Plans Challenges for defined contribution plans While Eastern Europe is a prominent example of the importance of defined

More information

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model

Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 422 March 2009 Momentum Traders in the Housing Market: Survey Evidence and a Search Model Monika Piazzesi Stanford University and National

More information

Equilibrium High Frequency Trading

Equilibrium High Frequency Trading Equilibrium High Frequency Trading B. Biais, T. Foucault, S. Moinas Fifth Annual Conference of the Paul Woolley Centre for the Study of Capital Market Dysfunctionality London, June 2012 What s High Frequency

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

News Trading and Speed

News Trading and Speed Preliminary and Incomplete Please do not quote! News Trading and Speed Thierry Foucault Johan Hombert Ioanid Roşu April 1, 1 Abstract Adverse selection occurs in financial markets because certain investors

More information

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models

CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, and Linear Factor Models CAPM, Arbitrage, Linear Factor Models 1/ 41 Introduction We now assume all investors actually choose mean-variance e cient portfolios. By equating these investors

More information

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices

Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices Asset Management Contracts and Equilibrium Prices ANDREA M. BUFFA DIMITRI VAYANOS PAUL WOOLLEY Boston University London School of Economics London School of Economics September, 2013 Abstract We study

More information

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in

The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates. In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in The relationship between exchange rates, interest rates In this lecture we will learn how exchange rates accommodate equilibrium in financial markets. For this purpose we examine the relationship between

More information

Lecture 8: Stock market reaction to accounting data

Lecture 8: Stock market reaction to accounting data Lecture 8: Stock market reaction to accounting data In this lecture we will focus on how the market appears to evaluate accounting disclosures. For most of the time, we shall be examining the results of

More information

High frequency trading

High frequency trading High frequency trading Bruno Biais (Toulouse School of Economics) Presentation prepared for the European Institute of Financial Regulation Paris, Sept 2011 Outline 1) Description 2) Motivation for HFT

More information

Information Sales and Insider Trading

Information Sales and Insider Trading Information Sales and Insider Trading Giovanni Cespa June 15, 2005 Abstract Fundamental information resembles in many respects a durable good Hence, the effects of its incorporation into stock prices depend

More information

High-frequency trading and execution costs

High-frequency trading and execution costs High-frequency trading and execution costs Amy Kwan Richard Philip* Current version: January 13 2015 Abstract We examine whether high-frequency traders (HFT) increase the transaction costs of slower institutional

More information

Giffen Goods and Market Making

Giffen Goods and Market Making Giffen Goods and Market Making Giovanni Cespa First draft: April, 2002 This draft: May, 2003 Abstract This paper shows that information effects per se are not responsible for the Giffen goods anomaly affecting

More information

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk

Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk Research Summary Saltuk Ozerturk A. Research on Information Acquisition in Markets and Agency Issues Between Investors and Financial Intermediaries An important dimension of the workings of financial markets

More information

Financial Market Efficiency and Its Implications

Financial Market Efficiency and Its Implications Financial Market Efficiency: The Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) Financial Market Efficiency and Its Implications Financial markets are efficient if current asset prices fully reflect all currently available

More information

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider

Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model. Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider Momentum traders in the housing market: survey evidence and a search model Monika Piazzesi and Martin Schneider This paper studies household beliefs during the recent US housing boom. The first part presents

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault March, 06 Abstract Investors can acquire either raw or processed information about the payoff of risky assets. Information

More information

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran

Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests. Aswath Damodaran Market Efficiency: Definitions and Tests 1 Why market efficiency matters.. Question of whether markets are efficient, and if not, where the inefficiencies lie, is central to investment valuation. If markets

More information

liquidity Spillovers

liquidity Spillovers Learning from Prices, Liquidity Spillovers, and Market Segmentation Giovanni Cespa and Thierry Foucault December 2011 Abstract We describe a new mechanism that explains the transmission of liquidity shocks

More information

News Trading and Speed

News Trading and Speed News Trading and Speed THIERRY FOUCAULT, JOHAN HOMBERT, and IOANID ROŞU June 30, 2015 Abstract We compare the optimal trading strategy of an informed speculator when he can trade ahead of incoming news

More information

Where is the Value in High Frequency Trading?

Where is the Value in High Frequency Trading? Where is the Value in High Frequency Trading? Álvaro Cartea and José Penalva November 5, 00 Abstract We analyze the impact of high frequency trading in financial markets based on a model with three types

More information

Product Market Competition, Insider Trading. And Stock Market Efficiency

Product Market Competition, Insider Trading. And Stock Market Efficiency Product Market Competition, Insider Trading And Stock Market Efficiency Joel Peress INSEAD J. Peress Product Market Competition, Insider Trading and Stock Market Efficiency 1 Evidence Share turnover Insider

More information

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC

The Effects ofVariation Between Jain Mirman and JMC MARKET STRUCTURE AND INSIDER TRADING WASSIM DAHER AND LEONARD J. MIRMAN Abstract. In this paper we examine the real and financial effects of two insiders trading in a static Jain Mirman model (Henceforth

More information

Trading Frenzies and Their Impact on Real Investment

Trading Frenzies and Their Impact on Real Investment Trading Frenzies and Their Impact on Real Investment Itay Goldstein University of Pennsylvania Wharton School of Business Emre Ozdenoren London Business School and CEPR Kathy Yuan London School of Economics

More information

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage

Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Online Appendix Feedback Effects, Asymmetric Trading, and the Limits to Arbitrage Alex Edmans LBS, NBER, CEPR, and ECGI Itay Goldstein Wharton Wei Jiang Columbia May 8, 05 A Proofs of Propositions and

More information

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY

CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY CHAPTER 11: ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY 1. The revised estimate of the expected rate of return on the stock would be the old estimate plus the sum of the products of the unexpected change in each factor times

More information

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible

Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management. P roponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk 1 This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. 1 Jonathan B. Berk Haas School

More information

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Emily Polito, Trinity College In the past two decades, there have been many empirical studies both in support of and opposing

More information

Option Value of Cash. Jialin Yu Columbia Business School. April 20, 2010

Option Value of Cash. Jialin Yu Columbia Business School. April 20, 2010 Option Value of Cash Jialin Yu Columbia Business School April 20, 2010 Motivation Positive price-volume correlation Low market is illiquid market (Shleifer & Vishny (92)) e.g., US S&P/Case-Shiller home

More information

High-frequency trading: towards capital market efficiency, or a step too far?

High-frequency trading: towards capital market efficiency, or a step too far? Agenda Advancing economics in business High-frequency trading High-frequency trading: towards capital market efficiency, or a step too far? The growth in high-frequency trading has been a significant development

More information

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Moral Hazard. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania Moral Hazard Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1 Principal-Agent Problem Basic problem in corporate finance: separation of ownership and control: o The owners of the firm are typically

More information

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET

IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET IS MORE INFORMATION BETTER? THE EFFECT OF TRADERS IRRATIONAL BEHAVIOR ON AN ARTIFICIAL STOCK MARKET Wei T. Yue Alok R. Chaturvedi Shailendra Mehta Krannert Graduate School of Management Purdue University

More information

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence

Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from Certainty Equivalence Zeldes, QJE 1989 Background (Not in Paper) Income Uncertainty dates back to even earlier years, with the seminal work of

More information

Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Not Only What But also When: A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Ilan Guttman, Ilan Kremer, and Andrzej Skrzypacz Stanford Graduate School of Business September 2012 Abstract The extant theoretical

More information

Instructor s Manual Chapter 12 Page 144

Instructor s Manual Chapter 12 Page 144 Chapter 12 1. Suppose that your 58-year-old father works for the Ruffy Stuffed Toy Company and has contributed regularly to his company-matched savings plan for the past 15 years. Ruffy contributes $0.50

More information

Computational Finance Options

Computational Finance Options 1 Options 1 1 Options Computational Finance Options An option gives the holder of the option the right, but not the obligation to do something. Conversely, if you sell an option, you may be obliged to

More information

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain

Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain 1) Introduction Marketing Mix Modelling and Big Data P. M Cain Big data is generally defined in terms of the volume and variety of structured and unstructured information. Whereas structured data is stored

More information

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS

CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS CHAPTER 11: THE EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS PROBLEM SETS 1. The correlation coefficient between stock returns for two non-overlapping periods should be zero. If not, one could use returns from one period

More information

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU The t -Test If x 1,..., x n are independent and identically distributed with mean 0, and n is not too small, then t = x 0 s n has a standard

More information

Fast Trading and Prop Trading

Fast Trading and Prop Trading Fast Trading and Prop Trading B. Biais, F. Declerck, S. Moinas (Toulouse School of Economics) December 11, 2014 Market Microstructure Confronting many viewpoints #3 New market organization, new financial

More information

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves

C(t) (1 + y) 4. t=1. For the 4 year bond considered above, assume that the price today is 900$. The yield to maturity will then be the y that solves Economics 7344, Spring 2013 Bent E. Sørensen INTEREST RATE THEORY We will cover fixed income securities. The major categories of long-term fixed income securities are federal government bonds, corporate

More information

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12

Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance. Chapter 12 Market Efficiency and Behavioral Finance Chapter 12 Market Efficiency if stock prices reflect firm performance, should we be able to predict them? if prices were to be predictable, that would create the

More information

A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability

A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability Anat R. Admati Paul Pfleiderer Stanford University This article develops a theory in which concentrated-trading patterns arise endogenously as

More information

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds

Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Betting Strategies, Market Selection, and the Wisdom of Crowds Willemien Kets Northwestern University w-kets@kellogg.northwestern.edu David M. Pennock Microsoft Research New York City dpennock@microsoft.com

More information

HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING, ALGORITHMIC BUY-SIDE EXECUTION AND LINGUISTIC SYNTAX. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services 2011

HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING, ALGORITHMIC BUY-SIDE EXECUTION AND LINGUISTIC SYNTAX. Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services 2011 HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING, ALGORITHMIC BUY-SIDE EXECUTION AND LINGUISTIC SYNTAX Dan dibartolomeo Northfield Information Services 2011 GOALS FOR THIS TALK Assert that buy-side investment organizations engage

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Technical Trading and Strategic. Liquidity Provision

Technical Trading and Strategic. Liquidity Provision Technical Trading and Strategic Liquidity Provision Ming Guo and Chun Xia Abstract We study heterogeneous investors roles in liquidity provision and corresponding asset pricing implications over short

More information

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity

The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity Chapter 5 How to Value Bonds and Stocks 5A-1 Appendix 5A The Term Structure of Interest Rates, Spot Rates, and Yield to Maturity In the main body of this chapter, we have assumed that the interest rate

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

ABSTRACT. Essays on Asset Pricing Su Li, Doctor of Philosophy, 2012. Professor Albert Pete Kyle Department of Finance

ABSTRACT. Essays on Asset Pricing Su Li, Doctor of Philosophy, 2012. Professor Albert Pete Kyle Department of Finance ABSTRACT Title of dissertation: Dissertation directed by: Essays on Asset Pricing Su Li, Doctor of Philosophy, 2012 Professor Albert Pete Kyle Department of Finance This dissertation consists of three

More information

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics

Session IX: Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo. Module: Economics of Financial Markets. MSc. Financial Economics Session IX: Stock Options: Properties, Mechanics and Valuation Lecturer: Dr. Jose Olmo Module: Economics of Financial Markets MSc. Financial Economics Department of Economics, City University, London Stock

More information

Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies

Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies Nelson Lacey (USA), Qiang Bu (USA) Market sentiment and mutual fund trading strategies Abstract Based on a sample of the US equity, this paper investigates the performance of both follow-the-leader (momentum)

More information

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2

Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 Current Accounts in Open Economies Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 2 1 Consumption with many periods 1.1 Finite horizon of T Optimization problem maximize U t = u (c t ) + β (c t+1 ) + β 2 u (c t+2 ) +...

More information

Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk

Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk Using Currency Futures to Hedge Currency Risk By Sayee Srinivasan & Steven Youngren Product Research & Development Chicago Mercantile Exchange Inc. Introduction Investment professionals face a tough climate.

More information

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management

How To Understand The Theory Of Active Portfolio Management Five Myths of Active Portfolio Management Most active managers are skilled. Jonathan B. Berk Proponents of efficient markets argue that it is impossible to beat the market consistently. In support of their

More information

UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS

UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS UNIVERSITÀ DELLA SVIZZERA ITALIANA MARKET MICROSTRUCTURE AND ITS APPLICATIONS Course goals This course introduces you to market microstructure research. The focus is empirical, though theoretical work

More information

Execution Costs. Post-trade reporting. December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1

Execution Costs. Post-trade reporting. December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1 December 17, 2008 Robert Almgren / Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance Execution Costs 1 Execution Costs Execution costs are the difference in value between an ideal trade and what was actually done.

More information

INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS

INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS INTRODUCTION TO OPTIONS MARKETS QUESTIONS 1. What is the difference between a put option and a call option? 2. What is the difference between an American option and a European option? 3. Why does an option

More information

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING

THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ARBITRAGE PRICING 1. Introduction The Black-Scholes theory, which is the main subject of this course and its sequel, is based on the Efficient Market Hypothesis, that arbitrages

More information

Volatility: A Brief Overview

Volatility: A Brief Overview The Benefits of Systematically Selling Volatility July 2014 By Jeremy Berman Justin Frankel Co-Portfolio Managers of the RiverPark Structural Alpha Fund Abstract: A strategy of systematically selling volatility

More information

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1,

I.e., the return per dollar from investing in the shares from time 0 to time 1, XVII. SECURITY PRICING AND SECURITY ANALYSIS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET Consider the following somewhat simplified description of a typical analyst-investor's actions in making an investment decision. First,

More information

Department of Economics and Related Studies Financial Market Microstructure. Topic 1 : Overview and Fixed Cost Models of Spreads

Department of Economics and Related Studies Financial Market Microstructure. Topic 1 : Overview and Fixed Cost Models of Spreads Session 2008-2009 Department of Economics and Related Studies Financial Market Microstructure Topic 1 : Overview and Fixed Cost Models of Spreads 1 Introduction 1.1 Some background Most of what is taught

More information

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy

6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 2012 6. Budget Deficits and Fiscal Policy Introduction Ricardian equivalence Distorting taxes Debt crises Introduction (1) Ricardian equivalence

More information

2. Information Economics

2. Information Economics 2. Information Economics In General Equilibrium Theory all agents had full information regarding any variable of interest (prices, commodities, state of nature, cost function, preferences, etc.) In many

More information

Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market Model

Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market Model Agent-Based Computational Economics Overview of the Santa Fe Artificial Stock Market Model Leigh Tesfatsion Professor of Economics and Mathematics Department of Economics Iowa State University Ames, IA

More information

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market

Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Entry Cost, Tobin Tax, and Noise Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market Kang Shi The Chinese University of Hong Kong Juanyi Xu Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Simon Fraser University November

More information

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model

Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model Chapter 21: The Discounted Utility Model 21.1: Introduction This is an important chapter in that it introduces, and explores the implications of, an empirically relevant utility function representing intertemporal

More information

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model

Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model Finance 400 A. Penati - G. Pennacchi Market Micro-Structure: Notes on the Kyle Model These notes consider the single-period model in Kyle (1985) Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading, Econometrica 15,

More information

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance *

Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Regret and Rejoicing Effects on Mixed Insurance * Yoichiro Fujii, Osaka Sangyo University Mahito Okura, Doshisha Women s College of Liberal Arts Yusuke Osaki, Osaka Sangyo University + Abstract This papers

More information

Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns

Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns Autocorrelation in Daily Stock Returns ANÓNIO CERQUEIRA ABSRAC his paper examines the roles of spread and gradual incorporation of common information in the explanation of the autocorrelation in daily

More information

Equilibrium High Frequency Trading 1

Equilibrium High Frequency Trading 1 Equilibrium High Frequency Trading 1 Bruno Biais Toulouse School of Economics 1 Allée de Brienne 31000 Toulouse, France bruno.biais@univ-tlse1.fr Thierry Foucault HEC, Paris 1 rue de la Liberation 78351

More information

Liquidity Cycles and Make/Take Fees in Electronic Markets

Liquidity Cycles and Make/Take Fees in Electronic Markets Liquidity Cycles and Make/Take Fees in Electronic Markets Thierry Foucault (HEC, Paris) Ohad Kadan (Washington U) Eugene Kandel (Hebrew U) April 2011 Thierry, Ohad, and Eugene () Liquidity Cycles & Make/Take

More information

The Evolution of Market Mechanism in a Nutshell

The Evolution of Market Mechanism in a Nutshell RAND Journal of Economics, forthcoming A comparison of stock market mechanisms Giovanni Cespa I analyze a multi-asset market under two trading mechanisms. In the first (the unrestricted system), traders

More information

Key-words: return autocorrelation, stock market anomalies, non trading periods. JEL: G10.

Key-words: return autocorrelation, stock market anomalies, non trading periods. JEL: G10. New findings regarding return autocorrelation anomalies and the importance of non-trading periods Author: Josep García Blandón Department of Economics and Business Universitat Pompeu Fabra C/ Ramon Trias

More information

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

CHAPTER 15: THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES Chapter - The Term Structure of Interest Rates CHAPTER : THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES PROBLEM SETS.. In general, the forward rate can be viewed as the sum of the market s expectation of the future

More information

Dynamics of Small Open Economies

Dynamics of Small Open Economies Dynamics of Small Open Economies Lecture 2, ECON 4330 Tord Krogh January 22, 2013 Tord Krogh () ECON 4330 January 22, 2013 1 / 68 Last lecture The models we have looked at so far are characterized by:

More information