TO the extent that there exist price and wage rigidities, or

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "TO the extent that there exist price and wage rigidities, or"

Transcription

1 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler, and J. David López-Salido* Abstract We present a simple theory-based measure of the variations in aggregate economic efficiency: the gap between the marginal product of labor and the household s consumption leisure tradeoff. We show that this indicator corresponds to the reciprocal of the markup of price over social marginal cost, and give some evidence in support of this interpretation. We then show that, with some auxiliary assumptions, our gap variable may be used to measure the efficiency costs of business fluctuations. We find that the latter costs are modest on average. However, to the extent that the flexible price equilibrium is distorted, the gross efficiency losses from recessions and gains from booms may be large. Indeed, we find that the major recessions involved large efficiency losses. These results hold for reasonable parameterizations of the Frisch elasticity of labor supply, the relative risk aversion, and steady-state distortions. I. Introduction TO the extent that there exist price and wage rigidities, or possibly other types of market frictions, the business cycle is likely to involve inefficient fluctuations in the allocation of resources. Specifically, the economy may oscillate between expansionary periods when the volume of economic activity is close to the social optimum, and recessions that feature a significant drop in production relative to the first best. In this paper we explore this hypothesis by developing a simple measure of aggregate inefficiency and examining its cyclical properties. The measure we propose which we call the inefficiency gap, or the gap, for short is based on the size of the wedge between the marginal product of labor and the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure. Deviations of this gap from 0 reflect an inefficient allocation of employment. By constructing a time series measure of the inefficiency gap, we are able to obtain some insight into both the nature and the welfare costs of business cycles. From a somewhat different perspective, we show that the inefficiency gap corresponds to the reciprocal of the markup of price over social marginal cost. Procyclical movements in the inefficiency gap accordingly mirror countercyclical movements in this markup. Our approach, however, differs from much of the recent literature on business cycles and markups by using the household s marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure to measure the Received for publication October 29, Revision accepted for publication November 1, * CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra, New York University, and Federal Reserve Board and CEPR, respectively. We thank Jeff Amato, Susanto Basu, Bob Hall, Andy Levin, Casey Mulligan, Jonathan Parker, Julio Rotemberg, and several anonymous referees for helpful comments, as well as participants in seminars at LSE, Bocconi, IIES, UPF, Bank of Spain, Bank of England, NBER Summer Institute, CERGE, EUI, CEU, UAB, and the ECB Workshop on DSGE Models. Galí is thankful to CREA-Barcelona Economics, the Bank of Spain, the MCYT, and DURSI for financial support. Gertler acknowledges the support of the NSF and the C. V. Starr Center. The opinions expressed here are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of anyone else associated with the Federal Reserve System. price of labor, as opposed to wages. 1 As a matter of theory, of course, the household s consumption leisure tradeoff is the appropriate measure of the true social cost of labor. Wage data are not appropriate if either wages are not allocative or labor market frictions are present that drive a wedge between market wages and the labor supply curve. As we demonstrate, our markup construct is highly countercyclical. In addition, it also leads directly to a measure of aggregate efficiency costs at each point in time. Our approach builds on a stimulating paper by Hall (1997) that analyzes the cyclical behavior of the neoclassical labor market equilibrium. Specifically, Hall first demonstrates that the business cycle is associated with highly procyclical movements in the difference between the observable component of the household s marginal rate of substitution and the marginal product of labor. He then presents some evidence to suggest that this difference is of central importance to employment fluctuations. Also relevant is Mulligan (2002), who examines essentially the same measure of the labor market wedge, though focusing on its low-frequency movements. Specifically, he constructs an annual series of this variable, using data spanning more than a century. He finds that marginal tax rates correlate well at low frequencies with this labor market wedge. Finally, Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2004) find that the labor market wedge plays a critical role in accounting for the drop in employment during the Great Depression. As with Hall, we focus on the behavior of the labor market wedge at the business cycle frequency. We differ in several important ways, however. First, his framework treats this wedge simply as an exogenous driving force, interpretable, for example, as reflecting shifts in preferences. 2 We instead stress countercyclical markup variations as the key factor accounting for the cyclical fluctuations in this variable and present evidence in support of this general hypothesis. Second, given our markup interpretation, we are able to use the Hall residual as the basis for a measure of the efficiency costs of business cycles. In particular, with some auxiliary assumptions, it is possible to derive a measure of the lost surplus in the labor market at each point in time, based directly on movements 1 See Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) for a survey of the literature on business cycles and countercyclical markups. 2 To organize his approach, Hall (1997) modeled the labor market residual as an unobserved preference shock, though he did not take this hypothesis literally, but rather as a starting point for subsequent analysis. There has been a tendency in subsequent literature, however, (for example, Holland & Scott, 1998; Francis & Ramey, 2001; Uhlig, 2002) to interpret this residual as an exogenous preference shock. Earlier literature as well offered a similar interpretation (for example, Baxter & King, 1991). Our analysis will suggest that this residual cannot simply reflect exogenous preference shifts. The Review of Economics and Statistics, February 2007, 89(1): by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology

2 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 45 in our gap variable. Fluctuations generate efficiency costs on average because, as we show, the surplus lost from a decline in employment below its natural level exceeds the gain from a symmetric rise above its natural level. In this respect, our approach differs significantly from that of Lucas (1987, 2003), who examines the welfare costs of consumption variability associated with the cycle. Whereas the Lucas measure does not really take account of the sources of fluctuations, our measure instead isolates the costs associated with the inefficient component of fluctuations. Accordingly, our metric may give a better sense of the potential gains from improved stabilization policy. A significant additional feature is that our approach permits not only a measure of the costs of fluctuations on average, but also an assessment of the costs of particular episodes. We find, for example, that although the efficiency costs of fluctuations are not large when averaged across booms and recessions, the gross gains from booms and losses from recessions can indeed be quite large. Indeed, as we show, our methodology suggests that the U.S. economy experienced large efficiency costs during both the and the recession. This consideration is highly relevant because it may be that the main benefit from good stabilization policies may be to avoid severe recessions. To the extent that central banks have had either good skill or good luck in keeping to a minimum the number of severe downturns, it may be that on average the costs of fluctuations are not large. This kind of unconditional calculation, however, masks the kind of losses that can emerge if luck and/or skill suddenly turn bad. For this reason, an examination of episodes where matters clearly did seem to go awry can shed light on the importance of good policy management. In section II we develop a framework for measuring the inefficiency gap in terms of observables, conditional on some reasonably conventional assumptions about preferences and technology. We also show that it is possible to decompose the gap into price and wage markup components. In section 3 we present empirical measures of this variable for the postwar U.S. economy. The inefficiency gap exhibits large procyclical swings. In addition, under the assumption that wages are allocational, most of its variation is associated with countercyclical movements in the wage markup. 3 The price markup shows, at best, a weak contemporaneous correlation. Under some alternatives to our baseline case, the price markup does move countercyclically. However, movements in the wage markup still dominate the overall movements in the gap. In section IV we consider the possibility that purely exogenous factors (such as unobserved preference shifts) 3 In this respect our results are consistent with recent evidence in Sbordone (2000, 2002), Galí and Gertler (1999), Galí, Gertler and López- Salido (2001), and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1997, 1999, 2005) that in somewhat different contexts similarly points to an important role for wage rigidity. underlie the variation in our gap measures. Specifically, we present evidence that suggests that our gap variable is endogenous and thus cannot simply reflect exogenous variation in preferences. The evidence is instead consistent with our maintained hypothesis that endogenous variation in markups is largely responsible for the movement in the inefficiency gap. In section 5 we then use this link to examine both the unconditional efficiency costs of recessions and the conditional costs associated with the major boom-bust episodes. Concluding remarks are in section VI. II. FIGURE 1. THE GAP: ADIAGRAMMATIC EXPOSITION The Gap and Its Components: Theory Let the inefficiency gap (henceforth, the gap) be defined as follows: gap t mrs t mpn t, (1) where mrs t and mpn t denote, respectively, the (log) marginal product of labor and the (log) marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure. As illustrated by figure 1, our gap variable can be represented graphically as the vertical distance between the perfectly competitive labor supply and labor demand curves, evaluated at the current level of employment (or hours). In much of what follows we assume that our gap variable follows a stationary process with a (possibly nonzero) constant mean, denoted by gap (without any time subscript). The latter represents the steady-state deviation between mrs t and mpn t. Notice that these assumptions are consistent with both mrs t and mpn t being nonstationary, as is likely to be the case in practice as well as in the equilibrium representation of a large class of dynamic business cycle models. We next relate the gap to the markups in the goods and labor markets. Under the assumption of wage-taking firms, and in the absence of labor adjustment costs, the nominal marginal cost is given by w t mpn t, where w t is (log) compensation per additional unit of labor input (including nonwage costs). Accordingly, we define the aggregate price markup as follows: tp p t w t mpn t (2)

3 46 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS mpn t w t p t. (3) The aggregate wage markup is given by tw w t p t mrs t, (4) that is, it corresponds to the difference between the wage and the marginal disutility of work, both expressed in terms of consumption. Notice that the wage markup should be understood in a broad sense, including the wedge created by efficiency wages, payroll taxes paid by the firm and labor income taxes paid by the worker, search frictions, and so on. A variety of frictions (perhaps most prominently, wage and price rigidities) may induce fluctuations in the markups: it is in this respect that these frictions are associated with inefficient cyclical fluctuations, or more precisely, with variations in the aggregate level of (in)efficiency. In particular, given that the marginal rate of substitution is likely to be procyclical, rigidities in the real wage resulting either from nominal or real rigidities will give rise to countercyclical movements in the wage markup. 4 Similar rigidities may give rise, in turn, to a countercyclical price markup in response to demand shocks; for holding productivity constant, the marginal product of labor is countercyclical. 5 Alternatively, procyclical movements in competitiveness could induce a countercyclical price markup, as in Rotemberg and Woodford (1996), for example. To formalize the link between markup behavior and the gap, we first express equation (1) as gap t mpn t w t p t w t p t mrs t. (5) Combining equations (3), (4), and (5) then yields a fundamental relation linking the gap to the wage and price markups: gap t tp tw. (6) In the steady state, further, gap p w 0, (7) 4 Models with countercyclical wage markups due to nominal rigidities include Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987) and Erceg, Henderson, and Levin (2000). Alexopolous (2004) develops a model with a real rigidity due to efficiency wages that can generate a countercyclical wage markup. Alternatively, Hall (1997) stresses the possible role of countercyclical search frictions to account for the behavior of the labor market residual. 5 With productivity shocks, the markup could be procyclical (because the marginal product of labor moves procyclically in that instance). where variables without time subscripts denote steady-state values. It is natural to assume that p t 0 and w t 0 for all t, implying gap t 0 for all t. In this case the level of economic activity is inefficiently low (that is, the gap is always negative), so that (small) increases in our gap measure will be associated with a smaller distortion (that is, an allocation closer to the perfectly competitive one). Notice also that countercyclical movements in these markups imply that the gap is high in booms and low in recessions. To the extent that we can measure the two markups (or, at least their variation), we can characterize the behavior of the gap, as well as its composition. Constructing our gap variable requires some assumptions about technology and preferences. Below we consider a baseline case with reasonably conventional assumptions. Decomposing the resulting gap variable between wage and price markups requires an additional assumption, namely, that the observed wages used in the construction of the markup reflect the shadow cost of hiring an additional unit of labor. Because this assumption is likely to be more controversial, it is important to keep in mind that it is not necessary in order to measure the gap as a whole, but it is only used in computing its decomposition between the two markups. Under the assumption of a technology with constant elasticity of output with respect to hours (say, ), we have (up to an additive constant): mpn t y t n t, (8) where y t is output per capita and n t is hours per capita. 6 We assume that the (log) marginal rate of substitution for a representative consumer can be written (up to an additive constant) as mrs t c t n t t, (9) where c t is consumption per capita and t is a low-frequency preference shifter. The parameter rameter is related to the coefficient of relative risk aversion, and measures the curvature of the disutility of labor. 7 Following Hall (1997), we allow for the possibility of low-frequency shifts in preferences over consumption versus leisure, as represented by movements in t. These preference shifts may be interpreted broadly to include institutional or demographic changes that affect the labor market, but which are unlikely to be of relevance at business cycle frequencies. We differ from Hall, though, by restricting these shifts to the low frequency. In section IV we provide evidence to justify this assumption. 6 Under certain assumptions, that specification is compatible with variable labor utilization particularly, if labor effort moves roughly proportionately with hours per worker, and the latter is highly positively correlated with aggregate hours (per capita), as the evidence suggests. See, for example, Basu and Kimball (1997) for a detailed discussion. 7 The parameter measures the curvature of the utility function under the standard assumption that labor supply adjusts along the intensive margin (that is, over hours). As we show in appendix A, however, under certain assumptions our framework also allows for labor supply adjustment to occur instead over the extensive margin (that is, over participation). Finally, this log linear representation of the mrs has been reconciled with balanced growth in a model with household production (see Baxter and Jermann 1999), or in a generalized indivisible labor model (see King and Rebelo, 1999).

4 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 47 Under the above assumptions our gap variable is thus given by gap t c t n t t y t n t. (10) Furthermore, we can combine the above assumptions with the definition of the price markup to obtain tp y t n t w t p t (11) s t. (12) Hence the price markup can be measured (up to an additive constant) as minus the (log) real unit labor costs, denoted by s t. Similarly, the wage markup is given by tw w t p t c t n t t. (13) III. The Gap and Its Components: Evidence We now use the theoretical relations in the previous section to construct measures of the gap and its two main components: the price and wage markups. Our evidence is based on quarterly postwar U.S. data over the sample period 1960:I 2004:IV. 8 A. Baseline Case Identification of gap and wage markup variations requires that we make an assumption on the coefficient of relative risk aversion and on, a parameter that corresponds to the inverse of the (Frisch) wage elasticity of labor supply. A vast amount of evidence from microdata suggests a labor supply elasticity mostly concentrated in the range of On the other hand, the business cycle literature tends to use values of unity and higher, using balanced-growth considerations as a justification, as opposed to direct evidence (see, for example Cooley & Prescott, 1995). We use as a baseline value 1, which we view as a reasonable compromise between the values suggested in the micro and macro literature. In addition, because it will turn out that the costs of fluctuations vary inversely with the Frisch labor 8 The data used to construct the gap variable and its components were drawn from the USECON database commercialized by Estima in Rats format. The time series used (with corresponding mnemonics shown in brackets) include compensation per hour (LXNFC), hours all persons (LXNFH), and real and nominal output (LXNFO and LXNFI), all of which refer to the nonfarm business sector. We also make use of the NIPA series for nondurable and services consumption (CNH GSH). In addition we also use population over sixteen (POP16) to express variables in per capita terms, real GDP (GDPQ), implicit GDP deflator (GDPD), the Fed funds rate (FFED), the spread between the 10-year government bond yield (FCM10) and the 3-month Treasury bill rate (FTB3), and a commodity price index (PSCOM) for our VAR exercise in figure 4. 9 In his survey of the literature, Card (1994) concludes that the intertemporal elasticity of labor supply is surely no higher than 0.5 and probably no higher than 0.2. However, whether it is appropriate to use the existing micro evidence to calibrate the intertemporal elasticity of labor supply is a matter of considerable controversy, particularly to the extent that employment adjusts along the extensive margin as well as the intensive margin [see, for example, the discussion in Mulligan (1998)]. supply elasticity, we are biasing our analysis against finding large welfare costs by choosing an elasticity that is above most of the direct estimates in the literature. The efficiency costs are also increasing in the coefficient of relative risk aversion, because this parameter also affects the steepness of the labor supply curve. There is, however, a similar controversy over the value of this parameter, which equals the inverse intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Direct estimates of the latter tend to fall in the range This evidence suggests a value of that varies from 10 to On the other hand, balanced-growth considerations lead the macro literature to a value of unity (again, see Cooley & Prescott, 1995). We will use unity as our baseline case, again opting to bias our parameterization against finding large efficiency costs. In addition, we need to make an assumption to identify the low-frequency shifter t. Let tw (w t p t ) ( c t n t ) be the observable component of the wage markup (conditional on values for and ). It follows that tw tw t. (14) From this perspective, the wage markup t w is the cyclical component of tw, and t is (minus) the trend component. We approximate the low-frequency movements of the wage markup by fitting a third-order polynomial of time to tw. 11 Finally, before proceeding, we note that the relationships derived in the previous section hold only up to an additive constant. Accordingly, our framework allows us to identify the variations over time in the markup and its components, but not their levels. Identification of the level requires that we calibrate the steady-state markup gap ( p w ), an issue to which we turn below. Our baseline results thus employ measures of the price and wage markups and the gap constructed using, respectively, equations (6), (12), and (13), expressed in terms of deviations from their respective sample means. Figure 2 presents the time series measure of our gap variable under our baseline assumptions of 1 and 1. Notice that this variable comoves strongly with the business cycle, displaying large declines during NBERdated recessions (represented by the shaded areas in the graph). We next decompose the movements of the gap into its wage and price markup components. The wage markup measures were constructed using equation (13). 12 The price markup corresponds to minus the log of real unit labor costs, as implied by equation (12). Figure 3 shows the behavior of 10 Using microdata, Barsky et al. (1997) estimate an intertemporal elasticity of substitution of 0.18, implying a coefficient of relative risk aversion slightly above 5. Using macrodata, Hall (1988) concludes that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (1/ ) is likely below Because we use the gap measure in subsequent time series analysis, we opt for a high-order polynomial instead of a bandpass filter to detrend the data. 12 The results are robust to simple adjustments for compositional bias of the real wage, based on Barsky, Parker, and Solon, (1994).

5 48 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS FIGURE 2. THE GAP: BASELINE CALIBRATION ( 1, 1) the gap against the wage markup (both relative to their means). To facilitate visual inspection, we plot the inverse wage markup (that is, minus the log wage markup). By definition, the difference between the gap and the inverse wage markup is the inverse price markup. What is striking about the pictures is the strong comovement between the gap and the (inverse) wage markup. Put differently, our evidence suggests that the inefficiency gap seems to be driven largely by countercyclical movements in the wage markup As a somewhat cleaner way to illustrate the strong countercyclical relation between the gap and the wage markup, we show later that this pattern also holds conditional on a shock to monetary policy. FIGURE 3. THE GAP AND THE WAGE MARKUP: BASELINE CALIBRATION

6 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 49 TABLE 1. BASIC STATISTICS: BASELINE CALIBRATION: ( 1, 1) Variable SD (%) GDP Gap Price Mkup Wage Mkup GDP Gap Price markup Wage markup Note: Column labeled GDP corresponds to the CBO output gap measure. Cross-Correlation To be clear, our conclusion that countercyclical wage markup variation drives the variation in the gap rests on the assumption that wages are allocational and can thus be used to construct a relevant cost measure. 14 Though this assumption is standard in the literature on business cycles and markups (for example, Rotemberg & Woodford, 1999), it is not without controversy. Notice, however, that even if observed wages are not allocational, our gap variable is still appropriately measured, because its construction does not require the use of wage data. Thus our welfare analysis, which depends on the overall gap and not its decomposition, is not affected by this issue. Table 1 reports some basic statistics that support the visual evidence in figure 3. In particular, the table reports a set of second moments for the gap and its two components (the wage and price markups) and also for detrended (log) GDP, a common indicator of the business cycle. Note first that the percentage standard deviation of the gap is large (relative to detrended output) and that departures of the gap from steady state are highly persistent. In addition, the wage markup is nearly as volatile as the overall gap, and is strongly negatively correlated with the latter, as well as with detrended GDP. This confirms the visual evidence that movements in the gap are strongly associated with countercyclical movements in the wage markup. On the other hand, the price markup is less volatile than the wage markup and does not exhibit a strong contemporaneous correlation with the gap. 15 B. Robustness to Alternative Specifications of Technology and Costs We next investigate the robustness of our results to the use of alternative specifications of technology and costs. Our baseline case assumes constant elasticity of output with respect to hours and takes the observed average wage as the relevant cost of hiring additional labor. We consider four alternatives to this baseline proposed by Rotemberg and 14 Some indirect evidence that wages are allocational is found by Sbordone (2002) and Galí and Gertler (1999), who show that firms appear to adjust prices in response to measures of marginal cost based on wage data. In turn, as shown in Galí (2001), they do not respond to marginal cost measures that employ the household s marginal rate of substitution in place of the wage, as would be appropriate if wages were not allocational. 15 However, the relatively weak comovement of the price markup with detrended output is useful for understanding the dynamics of inflation and the recent evidence on the New Keynesian Phillips curve. See Sbordone (2002) and Galí and Gertler (1999). Woodford (1999) in their analysis of cyclical markup behavior. The specific formulations and (subsequent calibrations) we use follow their analysis closely. Each of the alternatives to the baseline enhances the countercyclical movement in the price markup by making marginal cost more procyclical. The first alternative model assumes a CES production function, thus relaxing the assumption of a constant elasticity of output with respect to labor. The second model allows for overhead labor. The third model, which is based on Bils (1987), allows for the marginal wage to differ from the average wage due to an overtime premium. Finally, the fourth model allows for convex costs of adjusting labor. In appendix B we present a detailed exposition of how each case affects the measure of the gap and its markup components. We also discuss the calibration. As the appendix makes clear, the CES, overhead labor, and adjustment cost models all alter the marginal product of labor. They accordingly affect the measures of both the overall gap and the price markup. However, they do not affect the measure of the wage markup. On the other hand, the marginal wage model alters only the composition of the gap between the price and wage markups at each point in time, without influencing the gap variable itself (for it affects neither the marginal product of labor nor the household marginal rate of substitution.) The different panels of table 2 report basic statistics for the alternative measures of the gap and its components, analogous to those reported in table 1 for the baseline case. Overall, the central results from our baseline case are robust to all the alternatives. Both the volatility and persistence of the gap are very similar across all cases. It also remains true in all cases that most of the variation in the gap is due to the variation in the wage markup as opposed to the price markup. The only significant difference is that the price markup tends to display a stronger countercyclical movement than in the baseline case. In contrast to the baseline model, the price markup in the CES, overhead labor, and marginal wage models is negatively correlated with the output gap. In all the alternative models, further, the negative comovement of the price markup with our gap variable is larger than in the baseline case. In panel A of figure 4 we show that the historical movement in the gap is robust to the alternative cases. We plot the time series of the gap for the baseline case against all the alternatives except the marginal wage model (for which the

7 50 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS TABLE 2. BASIC STATISTICS: ROBUSTNESS: ALTERNATIVE MEASURES OF REAL MARGINAL COST Variable SD (%) GDP Gap Price Mkup Gap: CES Overhead Adj. cost Bils Price markup: CES Overhead Adj. cost Bils Wage markup: CES Overhead Adj. cost Bils Note: See table 1. Cross-Correlation measure of the overall gap is the same as for the baseline). Clearly, the gap measures move very tightly together in all cases. Finally, though the gap measure in the marginal model is the same as in the baseline case, the division into price and wage markup movements differs. Accordingly, in panel B of figure 4 we plot the wage markup for the marginal model (Bils adjustment) relative to the baseline case. As the figure shows, the broad pattern in the movement of the wage markup is very similar across the two cases. To summarize: the results thus far suggest that the business cycle is associated with large coincident movements in the efficiency gap. Thus, under our framework, the evidence suggests that countercyclical markup behavior is potentially an important feature of the business cycle. A decomposition of the gap further suggests that the countercyclical movement in the wage markup is by far the most important source of overall variations in the gap. Thus, to the extent that wages are allocational, some form of wage rigidity, either real or nominal, may be central to business fluctuations. IV. Labor Supply Shifts and the Gap We have proceeded under the interpretation that our measured gap between the marginal rate of substitution and the marginal product of labor reflects countercyclical markup behavior. In his baseline identification scheme, however, Hall modeled this gap as an unobserved preference shock, though he was clear to state that he did not take this hypothesis literally. Subsequent literature, however (for example, Holland & Scott, 1998; Francis & Ramey, 2001; Uhlig, 2002) has indeed interpreted this residual as reflecting either exogenous labor supply shifts or some other unspecified exogenous driving force. In this section we show that the high-frequency movements in the gap cannot be simply due to exogenous preference shifts. Rather, the evidence is instead compatible with our countercyclical markup interpretation. Let us follow Hall (1997) in assuming that the marginal rate of substitution is now augmented with a preference shock t that contains a cyclical component t, as well as a trend component t : with mrs t c t n t t (15) t t t, where we maintain our baseline assumption that the coefficient of relative risk aversion,, is unity. Hall then defines the residual x t as the difference between the observable component of the marginal rate of substitution, c t n t, and the marginal product of labor, y t n t : x t c t n t y t n t. (16) The issue then is how exactly to interpret the movement in Hall s residual. Using the augmented specification (15) of the marginal rate of substitution allowing for preference shocks, together with equation (8) and the definition (1) of the inefficiency gap, it is possible to express x t as follows: x t mrs t mpn t t (17) tp tw t. (18) Hall s assumption of perfect competition in both goods and labor markets implies t p t w 0. This allows him to interpret the variable x t as a preference shock, for under this assumption x t t. 16 Notice that under these circumstances the efficiency gap is 0, as there are no imperfections in either goods or labor markets. On the other hand, if preferences are not subject to shocks ( t 0, all t), and we allow 16 See also Baxter and King (1991). Holland and Scott (1998) construct similar measures for the United Kingdom.

8 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 51 FIGURE 4. (A) THE GAP: ALTERNATIVE MEASURES, BASELINE CALIBRATION ( 1, 1), (B) WAGE MARKUP: BILS ADJUSTMENT for departures from perfect competition, x t will purely reflect movements in markups, that is, x t ( p t w t ). In the latter instance, x t corresponds exactly to our inefficiency gap, that is, x t gap t, for all t. Note that if x t indeed reflects exogenous preference shocks, it should be invariant to any other type of disturbance. In other words, the null hypothesis of preference shocks implies that x t should be exogenous. We next present

9 52 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS TABLE 3. GRANGER-CAUSALITY TESTS ( ): BASELINE CALIBRATION ( 1, 1), BIVARIATE VAR(4LAGS) p-value Variable Baseline CES Overhead Adj. cost Bils CBO output gap Nominal interest rate Yield spread Note: The values reported are p-values for the null hypothesis of no Granger causality from each variable listed to Hall x (F-test). Filtered data using third-order polynomial in time. two tests that reject the null of exogeneity, thus rejecting the preference shock hypothesis. First, we test the hypothesis of no Granger causality from a number of variables to our gap measure. The variables used are: detrended GDP, the nominal interest rate, and the yield spread. Both the nominal interest rate and the yield spread may be thought of as rough measures of the stance of monetary policy, whereas detrended GDP is just a simple cyclical indicator. Table 3 displays the p-values for several Granger-causality tests. These statistics correspond to bivariate tests using alternative lag lengths. They indicate that the null of no Granger causality is rejected for all specifications, at conventional significance levels. That finding is robust to reasonable alternative calibrations of and. Overall, the evidence of Granger causality is inconsistent with the hypothesis that x t mainly reflects variations in preferences. As a second test, we estimate the dynamic response of our gap variable to an identified exogenous monetary policy shock. The identification scheme is similar to the one proposed by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999) and others. It is based on a VAR that includes measures of output, the price level, commodity prices, and the Federal Reserve Funds rate, to which we add our gap measure (or, equivalently, Hall s residual) and the price markup. From the gap and the price markup response we can back out the behavior of the wage markup, using equation (6). We identify the monetary policy shock as the orthogonalized innovation to the Federal Reserve Funds rate, under the assumption that this shock does not have a contemporaneous effect on the other variables in the system. Figure 5 shows the estimated responses to a contractionary monetary policy shock. The responses of the nominal rate, output, consumption, and prices are similar to those found in Christiano et al. (1999), Bernanke and Mihov (1998), and other papers in the literature. Most interestingly for our purposes, the inefficiency gap declines significantly in response to the unanticipated monetary tightening. Its overall pattern of response closely mimics the response of output. This endogenous reaction, of course, is inconsistent with the preference shock hypothesis, but fully consistent with our hypothesis that countercyclical markups may underlie the cyclical variation in the Hall residual. In this connection, note that the monetary shock induces a rise in the wage markup that closely mirrors the decline in the gap, both in the shape and in the magnitude of the response. This countercyclical movement in the wage markup is consistent with evidence on unconditional comovements presented in table 1. The price markup also rises, though with a significant lag. Apparently, the sluggish response of wages, which gives rise to a strong countercyclical movement in the wage markup, delays the rise in the price markup. 17 In any event, the decline in the inefficiency gap is clearly associated with a countercyclical rise in markups. To be clear, because preference shocks are not observable, it is not possible to directly determine the overall importance of these disturbances. Although our evidence rejects the hypothesis that exogenous preference variation drives all the movement in our gap measure, it cannot rule out the possibility that some of this movement is due to preference shocks. Yet, to the extent that preference shocks are mainly a low-frequency phenomenon, they are likely to be captured by the trend component associated with our low-frequency filter (together with other institutional and demographic factors which may lead to low-frequency variations in markups). In this instance our filtered gap series, which isolates the high-frequency movement in this variable, is likely to be largely uncontaminated by exogenous preference variations. V. Welfare and the Gap We next propose a simple way to measure the welfare costs of fluctuations in the degree of inefficiency of aggregate resource allocations, as captured by our gap variable. We then apply this methodology to postwar U.S. data. In addition to obtaining a measure of the average cost of gap fluctuations, we also compute the welfare losses during particular episodes, including the major postwar recessions. As we noted in the introduction, our approach differs from Lucas (1987) and others in focusing on the costs stemming from fluctuations in the degree of inefficiency of the aggregate resource allocation, as reflected by the movements in our gap variable. 18 As in Ball and Romer (1987), the cycle generates losses on average within our framework 17 As Galí and Gertler (1999) and Sbordone (2002) observe, the sluggish behavior of the price markup helps explain the inertial behavior of inflation, manifested in this case by the delayed and weak response of inflation to the monetary shock. Staggered pricing models relate inflation to an expected discounted stream of real marginal costs, which corresponds to the reciprocal of the price markup. The sluggish response to the price markup translates into sluggish behavior of real marginal cost. 18 For other approaches to measuring the unconditional costs of fluctuations see, for example, Barlevy (2004) and Beaudry and Pages (2001). For a very early attempt to measure the welfare cost of inefficiently high unemployment, see Gordon (1973).

10 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 53 FIGURE 5. DYNAMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY SHOCKS: BASELINE CALIBRATION, SAMPLE PERIOD Note: 95% confidence bands for impulse responses are based on 5000 Monte Carlo replications. Sample period: 1960:1 2004:3. because the welfare effects of employment fluctuations about the steady state are asymmetric. As figure 1 illustrates, given that the steady-state level of employment is inefficient (due to positive price and wage markups in the steady state), the efficiency costs of an employment contraction below the steady state will exceed the benefits of a symmetric increase. In particular, note that the vertical distance between the labor demand and supply curves rises as employment falls below the steady state, and falls as it rises above. The quantitative effect of this nonlinearity on the welfare cost of fluctuations ultimately depends on the slopes of the labor demand and supply curves, and on the steady-state distance relative to the first-best, perfectly competitive steady state. Underlying this measure of the average costs of fluctuations are the gross gains from booms and losses from recessions. As we elaborate, under our maintained hypothesis that the flexible price equilibrium is distorted (due to imperfect competition and taxes, and so on), there are significant first-order welfare losses from employment contractions below the steady state, as well as gains from movements above. Below we present a time series measure of these gross efficiency costs and benefits, along with an overall net measure. A. A Welfare Measure We now proceed to derive our welfare measure. The economy is assumed to fluctuate around an underlying frictionless path characterized by a constant gap level: GAP MRS t MPNt exp 1 1, where upper bars denote values along a constant gap path, and is (minus) the steady-state value of our (log) gap variable. A second-order approximation of the period utility around its level along the underlying constant-gap path yields t U C t,n t U C t, N t U c,t C t c t 1 c 2 t 2 U n,t N t ñ t 1 ñ 2 t 2, where the tildes denote log deviations from the underlying constant-gap path, that is, x t log X t /X t, and where U nn,t N t / U n,t and U cc,t C t / U c,t.

11 54 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS In order to maintain tractability, we make two additional assumptions. First, we assume that all output is consumed, which in turn implies c t ỹ t for all t. Secondly, we assume that output is linearly related to hours in equilibrium, that is, y t a t n t, thus implying ñ t ỹ t. The latter assumption is consistent with the notion that variations in the stock of capital are negligible at business cycle frequencies, and that the rate of capital utilization is proportional to hours. Notice that these two assumptions imply that U n,t N t U c,t C t 1. Hence, we can rewrite the second-order approximation as t U c,t C t ỹ t ỹ t 2. (19) Furthermore, under the previous assumptions, together with the log linear specification for the marginal rate of substitution in equation (9), it is easy to check that ˆgap t ỹ t, where ˆt gap t gap. Using the previous expression to substitute for ỹ t in equation (19), we obtain t 1 U c,t C t gap ˆ t gap ˆ t2 gap ˆ t (20) where Notice that gap ˆt is the period efficiency loss or gain from the gap s deviations from its steady-state value, expressed as a percentage of the frictionless level of consumption C t. The first term in the parentheses, the linear term, reflects the symmetric first-order costs and benefits from the gap moving below and above the steady state, due to the positive steady-state markup (implying 0). The quadratic term captures the asymmetric, second-order effects of gap fluctuations on welfare. For plausible values of,, and we have 0. In that case is concave, implying that a reduction in the gap below its steady-state value results in an efficiency loss that exceeds the gain stemming from a commensurate increase in the gap above its steady state. We can use equation (20) to calculate a time series of the efficiency gain or loss in each quarter t. To obtain a measure of the average welfare cost over time analogous to those found in the literature, we take the unconditional expectation of equation (20) to obtain E t U c,t C t var gap t, (21) where var(gap t ) is the variance of our gap measure. Notice that, as a result of the concavity of, the expected welfare effects of fluctuations in the gap variable are negative, that is, these fluctuations imply losses in expected welfare. This loss, further, is of second order, as it is linearly related to the variance of the inefficiency gap. It is, however, potentially large, depending in particular on the magnitude var(gap t ). As section 3 suggests, var(gap t ) is potentially large if the labor supply is inelastic or the risk aversion is high. To be clear, our approach provides a lower bound on the measure of the total welfare costs of fluctuations. The reason is simple: it does not include the welfare costs from efficient fluctuations in consumption and employment. Suppose, for example, that the data were generated by a realbusiness-cycle model with frictionless, perfectly competitive markets. We should then expect to see no variation in our gap measure, as the resource allocation would always be efficient. Our metric would then indicate no welfare costs of fluctuations, but some losses would still be implied by the variability of consumption and leisure (under standard convexity assumptions on preferences). It is also important to stress that, to the extent that the steady-state value of the gap corresponds also to the average value around which the economy fluctuates (as assumed above), average welfare losses will only be of second order. On the other hand, our efficiency cost measure suggests possible first-order effects at any moment in time: As reflected in equation (20) and illustrated further below, deviations in the gap variable from that steady state may have nonnegligible first-order welfare effects, with the gap declines associated with recessions generating large welfare losses. B. Some Numbers Equation (20) provides a real-time measure of the efficiency costs of deviations of our gap variable from steady state. Accordingly, we construct a quarterly time series of gap ˆt, taking as input our measure of the gap. We consider three different parameterizations: first, our baseline case with 1 and 1; second, a case where we raise the risk aversion with 5 and 1; and third, a case where we reduce the labor supply elasticity with 1 and 5 (implying a Frisch labor supply elasticity of 0.2). For the parameter, the sum of the steady-state wage and price markups, we assume a value of A value of 0.15 to 0.20 is plausible for the steady-state price markup (see Rotemberg and Woodford, 1999). Inasmuch as the steady-state wage markup depends on tax distortions as well as workers market power, 0.30 to 0.35 seems a reasonable lower bound given the evidence on average labor tax rates. This range is also roughly consistent with the evidence in Mulligan (2002).

12 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 55 FIGURE 6. THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF POSTWAR U.S. FLUCTUATIONS Figure 6 plots the resulting time series over the sample 1960:4 2004:4. The value at each period t can be interpreted as the efficiency gain or loss in percentage units of consumption associated with the deviation of the inefficiency gap from its steady state. Our baseline parametrization indicates substantial fluctuations in welfare resulting

13 56 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS TABLE 4. WELFARE COSTS OF FLUCTUATIONS ( ) Percentage of One Year s Consumption Note: Based on calibration 0.5. The data were filtered using a third-order polynomial in the time. Welfare computations cover the sample period 1960:1 2004:3. TABLE 5. THE WELFARE COSTS OF RECESSION EPISODES 1970s 1980s 1990s Note: See table 4. Percentage of One Year s Consumption with changes in the degree of aggregate efficiency. For example, efficiency-based welfare losses during the major recessions are on average around 2.0% of period consumption around the time of the respective troughs. Furthermore, during the major recessions these large welfare losses tend to persist for a number of years. Likewise, the average gain at the major cyclical peaks is a bit over 1.0%. These gains also tend to persist. With higher risk aversion ( 5) or lower labor supply elasticity ( 5) the losses during downturns go up while the gains during booms decline. In either case the labor supply curve is steeper than in the baseline case, enhancing the asymmetric effects on efficiency of symmetric movements in employment above and below its natural level. In the case of low labor supply elasticity, for example, the efficiency losses during the major recessions hover around 3.0% of consumption per period around the time of the respective troughs. In table 4 we present a measure of the average welfare cost of the cycle, based on equation (21). As we noted earlier, the measure is simply proportional to the square of the gap. We construct estimates for alternative values of the parameters and. For the parameterization that corresponds to our baseline case ( 1, 1), we estimate the average efficiency costs of postwar U.S. business fluctuations to be quite small, roughly 0.01% of steady-state consumption. In this case, the asymmetric movements in efficiency over the cycle are small, implying that the gains during booms seen in figure 6 approximately cancel the losses during recessions. The estimates of efficiency losses go up as we reduce labor supply elasticity and increase risk aversion. With 5 and 10, for example, the average efficiency costs go up to This number, however, is still not large and is in the range of Lucas s original estimates. Any measure of the average cost of business cycles, however, obscures the fact that individual recessionary episodes may be rather costly. What moderates the impact of these episodes on the overall welfare measure is the fact they have been infrequent, particularly over the last several decades. One reason for this may be that stabilization policy has been reasonably effective. Another possibility is that the economy has been subject to smaller shocks. In either event, it is of interest to examine efficiency losses during the major recessionary episodes. Doing so provides a sense of the gains from avoiding future recessions (either by good policy or by good luck). There are three distinct recessionary periods in our sample where the gap fell below the steady state prior to the trough and then returned to steady state following the trough. These periods include the two major recessions of the mid-1970s and of the early 1980s and also the recession of the early 1990s. 19 For each recessionary period, we report the cumulative efficiency losses over the recession as a percentage of one year s consumption. We again consider a variety of parameterizations, including our baseline case. Table 5 reports the efficiency losses for the three recessionary periods. For our baseline case ( 1 and 1), the efficiency costs of each of the two major recessions was large, roughly 4.5% of one year s consumption. For the milder recession of the 1990s the cost was still nontrivial, more than 2% of one year s consumption. With lower labor supply elasticity ( 5), the efficiency costs of the two major recessions rise to over 6.0% of one year s consumption, and the the cost of the 1990s recession rises to over 3.0%. Increasing risk aversion boosts the costs of the recession in the early 1980s. With 5, the efficiency cost of the downturn rises to over 7.0% of steady state consumption in the case of high labor supply elasticity ( 1). It goes up to 8.0% when combined with low labor supply elasticity ( 5). Interestingly, for the other two recessions, raising risk aversion actually tends to reduce the estimated efficiency cost. Intuitively, higher risk aversion places more weight on consumption in the measure of gap fluctuations. Because the decline in consumption was relatively modest in each of these downturns, as compared to the recession, increasing risk aversion tends to dampen gap fluctuations over these periods. For these reasons it reduces measured efficiency losses. Overall, our results suggest only modest average efficiency losses from fluctuations. However, major recessionary episodes appear to entail rather significant losses. VI. Concluding Comments At the risk of considerable oversimplification, it is possible to classify modern business cycle models into two types. The first class attempts to explain quantity fluctuations by appealing to high degrees of intertemporal substi- 19 For the other recessions in the sample (the early 1960s and the early 2000s), we do not have the complete swing of the gap below and back to steady state.

14 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 57 tution in an environment of frictionless markets. The second instead appeals to countercyclical markups owing to particular market frictions. In this regard, there has been a considerable debate as to whether the markup is indeed countercyclical [see Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) for a summary]. Much of this debate has been centered around price markup measures that use wage data to calculate the cost of labor. We show, however, that the markup is highly countercyclical, using the household s consumption leisure tradeoff as the shadow cost of labor, as theory would suggest. Under this identification scheme, the markup corresponds exactly to the labor market residual studied by Hall (1997) and others. Whether the countercyclical markup variation is driven primarily by product market or labor market behavior is, however, an open question. To the extent that wages are allocative, we find that labor market frictions are the key factor. As we discussed, however, the exact form that these frictions may take (such as nominal wage rigidity, efficiency wages, or search frictions) is also an open question. A second message of this paper is that to the extent that our markup interpretation of the efficiency gap is correct, business cycles may involve significant efficiency costs. To be sure, our results suggest that these efficiency losses are modest when averaged over time. This result occurs, however, because whether by good luck or good policy significant recessions have not often occurred since World War II. We find, however that when they do occur, the efficiency costs may indeed be quite large. These results obtain for reasonably standard assumptions on preferences (for example, a coefficient of relative risk aversion of 5 and a unit-elasticity Frisch labor supply). Thus, though the gains from eliminating all fluctuations may not be large as suggested by the existing literature there nonetheless do appear to be significant efficiency benefits from avoiding severe recessions. Finally, we observe that our calculation ignores at least several important considerations that might be leading us to understate the efficiency costs of recessions. First, within our framework, a reduction in hours leads to increased enjoyment of leisure, which partially offsets the impact of the output decline. In reality, workers who are laid off during recessions do not simply get to enjoy the time off, but rather have to look for a new job. In addition, there is often a loss of human capital that was specific to the previous employer. Second, our calculation ignores the costs of fluctuations in price and wage inflation associated with variations in markups resulting from nominal rigidities (see, for example, Woodford, 1999). For this reason, our metric may overstate the gains from booms (and understate the losses from recessions). To the extent that the costs of high inflation roughly offset the efficiency gains from the boom, our measure of the gross efficiency loss of the recession may provide a more accurate indicator of the costs of these episodes. Taking these considerations into account is on the agenda for future research. REFERENCES Alexopolous, Michelle, Unemployment and the Business Cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (2004), Ball, Lawrence, and David Romer, Are Prices Too Sticky? Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (1987), Barlevy, Gadi, The Cost of Business Cycles under Endogenous Growth, American Economic Review 94:4 (2004), Barsky, Robert, Jonathon Parker, and Gary Solon, Measuring the Cyclicality of Real Wages: How Important is Composition Bias? Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (1994), Barsky, Robert, F. Thomas Juster, Miles S. Kimball, and Matthew D. Shapiro, Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1997), Basu, S., and M. Kimball, Cyclical Productivity with Unobserved Input Variation, NBER working paper no (1997). Baxter, M., and Robert King, Productive Externalities and Business Cycles, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, discussion paper no. 53 (1991). Baxter, M., and U. J. Jermann, Household Production and the Excess of Sensitivity of Consumption to Current Income, American Economic Review 89:4 (1999), Beaudry, Paul, and Carmen Pages, The Cost of Business Cycles and the Stabilization Value of Unemployment Insurance, European Economic Review 45:8 (2001), Bernanke, Ben, and Ilyan Mihov, Measuring Monetary Policy, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (1998), Blanchard Olivier, J., and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand, American Economic Review 77 (1987), Card, David, Intertemporal Labor Supply: An Assessment (pp ), in Christopher Sims (Ed.), Advances in Econometrics: Sixth World Congress, Vol. II, (Cambridge University Press, 1994). Chari, V. V., Kehoe, P., and Ellen R. McGrattan, Business Cycles Accounting, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis staff report 328 (2004). Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans, Sticky Prices and Limited Participation Models: A Comparison, European Economic Review 41 (1997), Monetary Policy Shocks: What Have We Learned and to What End? in J. Taylor and M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1A (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1999). Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy, Journal of Political Economy 113:1 (2005), Cooley, Thomas, and Edward Prescott, Economic Growth and Business Cycles, in Thomas Cooley (Ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research (Princeton University Press, 1995). Eichenbaum, Martin, Lars Hansen, and Kenneth Singleton, A Time Series Analysis of Representative Agent Models of Consumption and Leisure Choice under Uncertainty, Quarterly Journal of Economics 103:1 (1988), Erceg C., Dale Henderson, and Andrew Levin, Optimal Monetary Policy with Staggered Wage and Price Contracts, Journal of Monetary Economics 46:2 (2000), Francis, Neville, and Valerie Ramey, Is the Technology-Driven Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited, UCSD mimeograph (2001). Galí, Jordi, The Case for Price Stability. A Comment, in A. Garcia- Herrero, V. Gaspar, L. Hoogduin, J. Morgan, and B. Winkler (Eds.), Why Price Stability? (Frankfurt am Main, European Central Bank, 2001). Galí, J., and Mark Gertler, Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (1999), Galí, J., Mark Gertler, and J. David López-Salido, European Inflation Dynamics, European Economic Review 45:7 (2001), Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare Costs of Business Fluctuations, NBER working paper no (2002). Gordon, Robert J., The Welfare Cost of Higher Unemployment, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 4:1 (1973),

15 58 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS Hall, Robert E., Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption, Journal of Political Economy 96:2 (1988), Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Allocation of Time, Journal of Labor Economics 15:1, pt. 2 (1997), S223 S250. Holland, A., and A. Scott, Determinants of U.K. Business Cycles, Economic Journal 108 (1998), King, Robert, and Sergio Rebelo, Resuscitating Real Business Cycles, in J. Taylor and M. Woodford (Eds.), The Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1B (Amsterdam North-Holland, 1999). Lucas, Robert E. Models of Business Cycles (Oxford University Press, 1987). Macroeconomic Priorities, American Economic Review 93:1 (2003), Mulligan, Casey B., Substitution over Time: Another Look at Life-Cycle Labor Supply, in Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 13 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1998). A Century of Labor-Leisure Distortions, NBER working paper no (2002). Pencavel, John, The Market Work Behavior and Wages of Women, , Journal of Human Resources 33 (1998), Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford, The Cyclical Behavior of Prices and Costs, in J. Taylor and M. Woodford (Eds.), The Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1B (Amsterdam: North- Holland, 1999). Sbordone, Argia M. An Optimizing Model of Wage and Price Dynamics, Rutgers University mimeograph (2000). Prices and Unit Labor Costs: Testing Models of Pricing Behavior, Journal of Monetary Economics 45:2 (2002), Uhlig, Harald, What Moves Real GNP? presented at CEPR-ESSIM Conference, May Tarragona, Spain (2002). Woodford, M., Inflation Stabilization and Welfare, NBER working paper no (1999). APPENDIX A The Household s MRS Here we illustrate that the expression we use for the household s marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure, equation (9), may be motivated either by making the standard assumption that labor supply adjusts along the intensive margin or, under certain assumptions, that the adjustment is along the extensive margin. Our argument is based on Mulligan (1998). Case I. Labor Supply Adjustment along the Intensive Margin: Let C t and N t denote consumption and hours worked, respectively. Assume a representative agent with preferences given by 1 1 C t N t 1. It follows that MRS t C t N t. By taking the log of each side of this relation we obtain equation (9). Case II. Labor Supply Adjustment along the Extensive Margin: Now assume that individuals either do not work or work a fixed amount of hours per week. Suppose there is a representative household with a continuum of members represented by the unit interval, and who differ according to their disutility of work. Specifically, let us assume that j is the disutility of work for member j. Under perfect consumption insurance within the household, and interpreting N t as the fraction of working household members in period t, total household utility will be given by 1 N 1 C t t 1 j dj. 0 Note that 0 N t j dj 1 1 N t 1 Accordingly, the utility function for the family in this case is isomorphic to the case of adjustment along the intensive margin. It follows that the marginal rate of substitution has the same form as well. APPENDIX B Alternative Specifications We now present the details that underlie the alternative measures of the gap and its components that we examined in the text. Our baseline case assumes constant elasticity of output with respect to hours and takes the observed average wage as the relevant cost of hiring additional labor. The four alternatives we consider are those proposed by Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) in their analysis of cyclical markup behavior. As discussed in the text, deviations from the baseline include: CES production, overhead labor, marginal wage differing from the average wage due to an overtime premium, and convex costs of adjusting labor. As will become clear, the CES, overhead labor, and adjustment cost models all alter the marginal product of labor. They accordingly affect the measures of both the overall gap and the price markup, but not the wage markup. On the other hand, the marginal wage model alters only the composition of the gap between the price and wage markups at each point in time, without influencing the gap variable itself. 1. Baseline Specification Our baseline case assumes no adjustment costs and a production function isoelastic in labor, that is, Y t F(X t )N t. In this case we have the following expressions for the (log) marginal product of labor and the price markup (up to an additive constant): mpn t y t n t, t p p t w t mpn t s t, where s t is the log labor share. These two formulas are then used in conjunction with information on the households marginal rate of substitution to obtain measures of the gap and the wage markup. 2. CES Technology 1 1/ Here we assume a CES production function: Y t 1 K t Z t N t 1 1/ / 1. The implied elasticity of output with respect to labor input, t Y t / N t /N t /Y t, is given by t 1 1 Y t 1 1/ K t. Log-linearizing around a steady state yields (ignoring constants) log t (y t k t ), where (1 1 )( 1 1). Because MPN t t Y t /N t, we can write and mpn t y t n t y t k t t p p t (w t mpn t ) s t y t k t. Calibration of proceeds by first noticing that the gross price markup M t p equals MPN t / W t /p t. This allows allows us to derive a simple expression for the steady state value of the elasticity of output with respect to labor as a function of the steady state price markup and the labor share, that is,

16 MARKUPS, GAPS, AND THE WELFARE COSTS OF BUSINESS FLUCTUATIONS 59 SM p. Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) calibrate the coefficient using approximate values for the average labor income share (S 0.7), the average gross price markup (close to unity), and an estimate for elasticity of substitution between capital and labor ( 0.5), all of which combined yield a value Overhead Labor For this case we assume a technology given by the production function 1 Y t Z t K t (N t N t *), where N t * denotes the amount of overhead labor at each point in time. The elasticity of output with respect to (total) labor input is now given by N t t. N t N t * Log-linearizing around the steady state and ignoring constants yields log t nˆ t, where N*/N N* is the steady-state ratio of overhead to variable labor, and n t denotes the log deviation of hours from its long-run trend (around which the linearization is carried out). Using the fact that MPN t t Y t /N t, it follows that and mpn t y t n t nˆ t tp p t w t mpn t s t nˆ t. Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) use a zero-profit condition in steady state in order to calibrate. In particular, it can be shown that the ratio of average costs to marginal costs can be written as AC t N 1 MC t t *. N t N t * This implies the following steady-state relationship: AC 1 M 1 S. Following Rotemberg and Woodford (1999), we assume S 0.7, M 1.25, and impose the zero-profit condition AC 1, thus implying 0.4. We use the latter value to construct our overhead-labor measure of the gap and the price markup. 4. Marginal Wage Different from Average Wage In the previous analysis we have assumed that firms are wage-taking, so that the marginal wage is equal to the average wage. As emphasized by Bils (1987), this will not be the case if the wage rises as firms ask their employees to work more hours. The relevant wage needed to compute both the price and wage markups is no longer the average wage but the marginal wage, W m. Notice however, that the use of the marginal wage will only alter the decomposition of our gap measure between the price and the wage markup, but not the gap measure itself. Let q t w t m w t denote the ratio of the marginal to the average wage (expressed in logs). Then it follows that t p p t w t m mpn t p t w t mpn t q t s t q t. Similarly, tw w tm p t mrs t w t p t mrs t q t. Bils (1987) and Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) propose a simple model of overtime pay that implies that the ratio Q t is an increasing function of hours per worker H t. Log-linearization of that function around a steady-state value for hours per worker allows us to rewrite the price markup as tp p t w t mpn t ĥ t, where is the elasticity of the marginal-to-average wage ratio with respect to hours per worker. Similarly, the wage markup will now be given by tw w t p t mrs t ĥ t. As discussed in Bils (1987), the assumption of a 50% overtime premium (the statutory premium in the United States) implies 1.4, which we use to construct our overtime measure of the price and wage markups. 5. Labor Adjustment Costs Finally, we consider the implications of having a cost of adjusting labor, which we assume take the form of output lost. Those cost are to be taken into account when computing firms marginal costs and hence price markups. Following Rotemberg and Woodford (1999), we assume that those costs take the form U t N t (N t /N t 1 ), where U t is the price of the input required to make the adjustment. In this case, the (expected) total cost associated with hiring an additional worker for one period is given by W t 1 U t W t N t N t 1 E t R t,t 1 U t 1 U t N t N t 1 N t N t 1 N t 2 N t 1 N t 1 N t W t B t, where R t,t 1 is the usual stochastic discount factor for one-period-ahead income. Hence, the expression for the price markup is given by tp p t w t b t mpn t s t b t. Assuming that the ratio U t /W t is stationary, we can derive the following expression in terms of deviations from steady state as follows (ignoring constants): b t n t E t n t 1, where (U/W) (1) and R u with u being the steady-state value for U t 1 /U t. Hence, the expression for the price markup can now be written as tp s t n t E t n t 1. We construct our adjustment-cost measure of price markups under the assumption that 0.99 and 4, the values suggested by Rotemberg and Woodford (1999).

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles:

The RBC methodology also comes down to two principles: Chapter 5 Real business cycles 5.1 Real business cycles The most well known paper in the Real Business Cycles (RBC) literature is Kydland and Prescott (1982). That paper introduces both a specific theory

More information

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle?

Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Why Does Consumption Lead the Business Cycle? Yi Wen Department of Economics Cornell University, Ithaca, N.Y. yw57@cornell.edu Abstract Consumption in the US leads output at the business cycle frequency.

More information

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model

Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Intermediate Macroeconomics: The Real Business Cycle Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 1 Introduction Having developed an operational model of the economy, we want to ask ourselves the

More information

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008

Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 Further Discussion of Temporary Payroll Tax Cut During Recession(s) Mark Bils and Pete Klenow, December 12, 2008 We focus on three aspects of a cut in payroll taxes as a stabilizer in a recession: (1)

More information

SIMPLE GUIDELINES FOR INTEREST RATE POLICY*

SIMPLE GUIDELINES FOR INTEREST RATE POLICY* SIMPLE GUIDELINES FOR INTEREST RATE POLICY* José Maria Brandão de Brito** Pedro Teles*** 1. INTRODUCTION Those of us working at research departments in central banks are regularly questioned on the right

More information

Chapter Title: The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s?

Chapter Title: The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: International Dimensions of Monetary Policy Volume Author/Editor: Jordi Gali and Mark J. Gertler,

More information

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators

Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Discussion of Capital Injection, Monetary Policy, and Financial Accelerators Karl Walentin Sveriges Riksbank 1. Background This paper is part of the large literature that takes as its starting point the

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty

Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty 1 Conditional guidance as a response to supply uncertainty Appendix to the speech given by Ben Broadbent, External Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England At the London Business School,

More information

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper)

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration (Working Paper) Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell National Institute of Economic and Social Research

More information

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely

In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely Long-Term Interest Rates and Inflation: A Fisherian Approach Peter N. Ireland In recent years, Federal Reserve (Fed) policymakers have come to rely on long-term bond yields to measure the public s long-term

More information

The Real Business Cycle model

The Real Business Cycle model The Real Business Cycle model Spring 2013 1 Historical introduction Modern business cycle theory really got started with Great Depression Keynes: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynesian

More information

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013)

2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Prof. Dr. Thomas Steger Advanced Macroeconomics II Lecture SS 13 2. Real Business Cycle Theory (June 25, 2013) Introduction Simplistic RBC Model Simple stochastic growth model Baseline RBC model Introduction

More information

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler *

Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices? By Ben S. Bernanke and Mark Gertler * In recent decades, asset booms and busts have been important factors in macroeconomic fluctuations in both

More information

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle Chapter 11 Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle Goal of This Chapter In this chapter, we study three models of business cycle, which were each developed as explicit equilibrium (market-clearing)

More information

DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES

DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES DECONSTRUCTING THE SUCCESS OF REAL BUSINESS CYCLES EMI NAKAMURA* The empirical success of Real Business Cycle (RBC) models is often judged by their ability to explain the behavior of a multitude of real

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No. 4522 TECHNOLOGY SHOCKS AND AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS: HOW WELL DOES THE RBC MODEL FIT POST-WAR US DATA?

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No. 4522 TECHNOLOGY SHOCKS AND AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS: HOW WELL DOES THE RBC MODEL FIT POST-WAR US DATA? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 4522 TECHNOLOGY SHOCKS AND AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS: HOW WELL DOES THE RBC MODEL FIT POST-WAR US DATA? Jordi Galí and Pau Rabanal INTERNATIONAL MACROECONOMICS ABCD www.cepr.org

More information

The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s?

The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Price Shocks: Why are the s so different from the 197s? Olivier J. Blanchard Jordi Galí August 18, 7 Abstract We characterize the macroeconomic performance of a set of

More information

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts.

Agenda. Business Cycles. What Is a Business Cycle? What Is a Business Cycle? What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycle Facts. Agenda What is a Business Cycle? Business Cycles.. 11-1 11-2 Business cycles are the short-run fluctuations in aggregate economic activity around its long-run growth path. Y Time 11-3 11-4 1 Components

More information

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan

Real Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370. February 2006. Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 370 February 2006 Real Business Cycles Ellen R. McGrattan Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota Abstract:

More information

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different?

Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? International Review of Economics and Finance 9 (2000) 387 415 Stock market booms and real economic activity: Is this time different? Mathias Binswanger* Institute for Economics and the Environment, University

More information

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance

A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance A Primer on Forecasting Business Performance There are two common approaches to forecasting: qualitative and quantitative. Qualitative forecasting methods are important when historical data is not available.

More information

welfare costs of business cycles

welfare costs of business cycles welfare costs of business cycles Ayse Imrohoroglu From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, 2008 Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume Abstract The welfare cost of business

More information

Welfare Costs of Inflation in a Menu Cost Model

Welfare Costs of Inflation in a Menu Cost Model Welfare Costs of Inflation in a Menu Cost Model Ariel Burstein and Christian Hellwig January 2008 Recent years have seen substantial progress in our understanding of pricing decisions at the micro level.

More information

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53. What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 DEMB Working Paper Series N. 53 What Drives US Inflation and Unemployment in the Long Run? Antonio Ribba* May 2015 *University of Modena and Reggio Emilia RECent (Center for Economic Research) Address:

More information

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX

A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory. By Student E XXXXXXX A Review of the Literature of Real Business Cycle theory By Student E XXXXXXX Abstract: The following paper reviews five articles concerning Real Business Cycle theory. First, the review compares the various

More information

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3

Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3 Econ 303: Intermediate Macroeconomics I Dr. Sauer Sample Questions for Exam #3 1. When firms experience unplanned inventory accumulation, they typically: A) build new plants. B) lay off workers and reduce

More information

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Chapter 12. Unemployment and Inflation. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation Chapter Outline Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-Off? The Problem of Unemployment The Problem of Inflation 12-2 Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a

More information

The Optimal Inflation Rate in New Keynesian Models: Should Central Banks Raise Their Inflation Targets in Light of the Zero Lower Bound?

The Optimal Inflation Rate in New Keynesian Models: Should Central Banks Raise Their Inflation Targets in Light of the Zero Lower Bound? The Optimal Inflation Rate in New Keynesian Models: Should Central Banks Raise Their Inflation Targets in Light of the Zero Lower Bound? OLIVIER COIBION College of William and Mary and NBER YURIY GORODNICHENKO

More information

In#ation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis

In#ation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (1999) 195}222 In#ation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis Jordi GalmH, Mark Gertler * Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona, Spain Department of Economics, New

More information

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix

Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix Markups and Firm-Level Export Status: Appendix De Loecker Jan - Warzynski Frederic Princeton University, NBER and CEPR - Aarhus School of Business Forthcoming American Economic Review Abstract This is

More information

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS

CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS CH 10 - REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. The short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal at: A) a level of output determined by aggregate demand. B) the natural level of output. C) the level of output at which the

More information

Learning objectives. The Theory of Real Business Cycles

Learning objectives. The Theory of Real Business Cycles Learning objectives This chapter presents an overview of recent work in two areas: Real Business Cycle theory New Keynesian economics Advances in Business Cycle Theory slide 1 The Theory of Real Business

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Real Business Cycle Models Lecture 2 Nicola Viegi April 2015 Basic RBC Model Claim: Stochastic General Equlibrium Model Is Enough to Explain The Business cycle Behaviour of the Economy Money is of little

More information

Chapter 11. Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved

Chapter 11. Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity. 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 11 Keynesianism: The Macroeconomics of Wage and Price Rigidity Chapter Outline Real-Wage Rigidity Price Stickiness Monetary and Fiscal Policy in the Keynesian Model The Keynesian Theory of Business

More information

Cash in advance model

Cash in advance model Chapter 4 Cash in advance model 4.1 Motivation In this lecture we will look at ways of introducing money into a neoclassical model and how these methods can be developed in an effort to try and explain

More information

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian

Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative, by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Comments on \Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great Stag ation? A Monetary Alternative", by Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian Olivier Blanchard July 2001 Revisionist history is always fun. But it is not

More information

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM)

CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) 1 CHAPTER 11. AN OVEVIEW OF THE BANK OF ENGLAND QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE (BEQM) This model is the main tool in the suite of models employed by the staff and the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) in the construction

More information

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions

Answers to Text Questions and Problems. Chapter 22. Answers to Review Questions Answers to Text Questions and Problems Chapter 22 Answers to Review Questions 3. In general, producers of durable goods are affected most by recessions while producers of nondurables (like food) and services

More information

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory

Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory Chapter 13 Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle (RBC) Theory is the other dominant strand of thought in modern macroeconomics. For the most part, RBC theory has held much less sway amongst policy-makers

More information

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY)

The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share. by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY) The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share by Michael Elsby (University of Edinburgh), Bart Hobijn (FRB SF), and Aysegul Sahin (FRB NY) Comments by: Brent Neiman University of Chicago Prepared for: Brookings

More information

Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich. 6. The New Keynesian Model

Ifo Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich. 6. The New Keynesian Model 6. The New Keynesian Model 1 6.1 The Baseline Model 2 Basic Concepts of the New Keynesian Model Markets are imperfect: Price and wage adjustments: contract duration, adjustment costs, imperfect expectations

More information

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN C H A P T E R12 MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICY IN THE VERY SHORT RUN LEARNING OBJECTIVES After reading and studying this chapter, you should be able to: Understand that both fiscal and monetary policy can

More information

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics Topics Volume 1, Issue 1 21 Article 25 Financial Market Shocks during the Great Depression Alycia Chin Missaka Warusawitharana Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

More information

A visual essay: Post-recession trends in nonfarm employment and related economic indicators

A visual essay: Post-recession trends in nonfarm employment and related economic indicators A visual essay: Post-recession trends in nonfarm employment and related economic indicators David Langdon, Rachel Krantz, and Michael Strople Real GDP Corporate profits Unemployment Insurance (UI) claims

More information

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Spring 2015 Karl Whelan (UCD) Real Business Cycles Spring 2015 1 / 38 Working Through A DSGE Model We have

More information

Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle

Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle Working Capital Requirement and the Unemployment Volatility Puzzle Tsu-ting Tim Lin Gettysburg College July, 3 Abstract Shimer (5) argues that a search-and-matching model of the labor market in which wage

More information

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

11.2 Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Interest Rates 518 Chapter 11 INFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY Thus, the monetary policy that is consistent with a permanent drop in inflation is a sudden upward jump in the money supply, followed by low growth. And, in

More information

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy

Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Fiscal Stimulus Improves Solvency in a Depressed Economy Dennis Leech Economics Department and Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy University of Warwick d.leech@warwick.ac.uk Published

More information

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF VARIOUS PROPOSALS TO PROVIDE $500 BILLION IN TAX RELIEF Prepared by the Staff of the JOINT COMMITTEE ON TAXATION March 1, 2005 JCX-4-05 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION... 1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY...

More information

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER 7: AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY Learning goals of this chapter: What forces bring persistent and rapid expansion of real GDP? What causes inflation? Why do we have business cycles? How

More information

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem

Chapter 1. Vector autoregressions. 1.1 VARs and the identi cation problem Chapter Vector autoregressions We begin by taking a look at the data of macroeconomics. A way to summarize the dynamics of macroeconomic data is to make use of vector autoregressions. VAR models have become

More information

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand

Inflation. Chapter 8. 8.1 Money Supply and Demand Chapter 8 Inflation This chapter examines the causes and consequences of inflation. Sections 8.1 and 8.2 relate inflation to money supply and demand. Although the presentation differs somewhat from that

More information

Fourth Edition. University of California, Berkeley

Fourth Edition. University of California, Berkeley Fourth Edition University of California, Berkeley Introduction Chapter 1 Chapter 2 Chapter 3 Chapter 4 Chapter 5 Chapter 6 Chapter 7 Chapter 8 Chapter 9 Chapter 10 Chapter 11 Chapter 12 Epilogue References

More information

Should we Really Care about Building Business. Cycle Coincident Indexes!

Should we Really Care about Building Business. Cycle Coincident Indexes! Should we Really Care about Building Business Cycle Coincident Indexes! Alain Hecq University of Maastricht The Netherlands August 2, 2004 Abstract Quite often, the goal of the game when developing new

More information

Introduction to time series analysis

Introduction to time series analysis Introduction to time series analysis Margherita Gerolimetto November 3, 2010 1 What is a time series? A time series is a collection of observations ordered following a parameter that for us is time. Examples

More information

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation?

Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? No. 11-1 Do Commodity Price Spikes Cause Long-Term Inflation? Geoffrey M.B. Tootell Abstract: This public policy brief examines the relationship between trend inflation and commodity price increases and

More information

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation Multiple Choice Questions 1. The origin of the idea of a trade-off between inflation and unemployment was a 1958 article by (a) A.W. Phillips. (b) Edmund Phelps. (c)

More information

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes Why the drivers of migration matter for the labour market AN26/2 Jed Armstrong and Chris McDonald April 26 Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series

More information

Inflation dynamics, marginal cost, and the output gap: Evidence from three countries

Inflation dynamics, marginal cost, and the output gap: Evidence from three countries Inflation dynamics, marginal cost, and the output gap: Evidence from three countries Katharine S. Neiss a,* and Edward Nelson b,* a Monetary Analysis, Bank of England, London EC2R 8AH, U.K. b Monetary

More information

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP?

Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Can we rely upon fiscal policy estimates in countries with a tax evasion of 15% of GDP? Raffaella Basile, Ministry of Economy and Finance, Dept. of Treasury Bruno Chiarini, University of Naples Parthenope,

More information

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved.

. In this case the leakage effect of tax increases is mitigated because some of the reduction in disposable income would have otherwise been saved. Chapter 4 Review Questions. Explain how an increase in government spending and an equal increase in lump sum taxes can generate an increase in equilibrium output. Under what conditions will a balanced

More information

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability

Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Financial Development and Macroeconomic Stability Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California Urban Jermann Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania January 31, 2005 VERY PRELIMINARY AND

More information

18 ECB STYLISED FACTS OF MONEY AND CREDIT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE

18 ECB STYLISED FACTS OF MONEY AND CREDIT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE Box 1 STYLISED FACTS OF MONEY AND CREDIT OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE Over the past three decades, the growth rates of MFI loans to the private sector and the narrow monetary aggregate M1 have displayed relatively

More information

Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle

Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle Gross Worker Flows over the Business Cycle Per Krusell Toshihiko Mukoyama Richard Rogerson Ayşegül Şahin November 2012 Abstract We build a hybrid model of aggregate labor supply with predictions for gross

More information

Real Business Cycle Models

Real Business Cycle Models Phd Macro, 2007 (Karl Whelan) 1 Real Business Cycle Models The Real Business Cycle (RBC) model introduced in a famous 1982 paper by Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott is the original DSGE model. 1 The early

More information

Labor Market and Unemployment Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D.

Labor Market and Unemployment Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. Labor Market and Unemployment Ing. Mansoor Maitah Ph.D. Product and Factor Markets Demand for Goods and Services Market of Goods and Services S D Supply of Goods and Services Households Firms Supply of

More information

A Model of Financial Crises

A Model of Financial Crises A Model of Financial Crises Coordination Failure due to Bad Assets Keiichiro Kobayashi Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI) Canon Institute for Global Studies (CIGS) Septempber 16,

More information

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11

Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11 Answers to Text Questions and Problems in Chapter 11 Answers to Review Questions 1. The aggregate demand curve relates aggregate demand (equal to short-run equilibrium output) to inflation. As inflation

More information

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Suvey of Macroeconomics, MBA 641 Fall 2006, Final Exam Name MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. 1) Modern macroeconomics emerged from

More information

Equilibrium Unemployment Theory

Equilibrium Unemployment Theory Equilibrium Unemployment Theory Model Modifications Matthias S. Hertweck University of Basel March 26, 2012 Matthias S. Hertweck Equilibrium Unemployment Theory 1/38 Lecture Outline The Volatility Puzzle

More information

Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited

Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited by Neville Francis Lehigh University and Valerie A. Ramey University of California, San Diego and

More information

4 Macroeconomics LESSON 6

4 Macroeconomics LESSON 6 4 Macroeconomics LESSON 6 Interest Rates and Monetary Policy in the Short Run and the Long Run Introduction and Description This lesson explores the relationship between the nominal interest rate and the

More information

THE ROLE OF DEBT AND EQUITY FINANCING OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE

THE ROLE OF DEBT AND EQUITY FINANCING OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE THE ROLE OF DEBT AND EQUITY FINANCING OVER THE BUSINESS CYCLE Francisco Covas and Wouter J. den Haan November 14, 2005 d Key Words: S JEL Classification: E Abstract Covas, Bank of Canada, den Haan: London

More information

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B

Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Economics Letters 82 (2004) 167 172 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Financial predictors of real activity and the financial accelerator B Ashoka Mody a,1, Mark P. Taylor b,c, * a Research Department,

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II (second half)

Advanced Macroeconomics II (second half) Barcelona Graduate School of Economics Universitat Pompeu Fabra Master in Economics Spring 2012 Professor Jordi Galí (23.413, jgali@crei.cat) Advanced Macroeconomics II (second half) The lectures will

More information

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates

Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates Monetary Policy and Long-term Interest Rates Shu Wu The University of Kansas First Draft: July 2004 This version: March 2005 Abstract This paper documents some new empirical results about the monetary

More information

S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS

S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS Fill in the Blanks. Module 1 S.Y.B.COM. (SEM-III) ECONOMICS 1. The continuous flow of money and goods and services between firms and households is called the Circular Flow. 2. Saving constitute a leakage

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory

Real Business Cycle Theory Real Business Cycle Theory Guido Ascari University of Pavia () Real Business Cycle Theory 1 / 50 Outline Introduction: Lucas methodological proposal The application to the analysis of business cycle uctuations:

More information

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition

Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Gains from Trade: The Role of Composition Wyatt Brooks University of Notre Dame Pau Pujolas McMaster University February, 2015 Abstract In this paper we use production and trade data to measure gains from

More information

Money and Public Finance

Money and Public Finance Money and Public Finance By Mr. Letlet August 1 In this anxious market environment, people lose their rationality with some even spreading false information to create trading opportunities. The tales about

More information

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35

Real Business Cycle Theory. Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Real Business Cycle Theory Marco Di Pietro Advanced () Monetary Economics and Policy 1 / 35 Introduction to DSGE models Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models have become the main tool for

More information

Surprising Comparative Properties of Monetary Models: Results from a New Model Database

Surprising Comparative Properties of Monetary Models: Results from a New Model Database JOHN B. TAYLOR, VOLKER WIELAND Surprising Comparative Properties of Monetary Models: Results from a New Model Database Institute for Monetary and Financial Stability GOETHE UNIVERSITY FRANKFURT AM MAIN

More information

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all.

Increasing for all. Convex for all. ( ) Increasing for all (remember that the log function is only defined for ). ( ) Concave for all. 1. Differentiation The first derivative of a function measures by how much changes in reaction to an infinitesimal shift in its argument. The largest the derivative (in absolute value), the faster is evolving.

More information

What do Aggregate Consumption Euler Equations Say about the Capital Income Tax Burden? *

What do Aggregate Consumption Euler Equations Say about the Capital Income Tax Burden? * What do Aggregate Consumption Euler Equations Say about the Capital Income Tax Burden? * by Casey B. Mulligan University of Chicago and NBER January 2004 Abstract Aggregate consumption Euler equations

More information

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds

Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds International Department Working Paper Series 00-E-3 Predicting the US Real GDP Growth Using Yield Spread of Corporate Bonds Yoshihito SAITO yoshihito.saitou@boj.or.jp Yoko TAKEDA youko.takeda@boj.or.jp

More information

Debt and the U.S. Economy

Debt and the U.S. Economy Debt and the U.S. Economy Kaiji Chen Ayşe İmrohoroğlu This Version: April 2012 Abstract Publicly held debt to GDP ratio in the U.S. has reached 68% in 2011 and is expected to continue rising. Many proposals

More information

The Real Business Cycle School

The Real Business Cycle School Major Currents in Contemporary Economics The Real Business Cycle School Mariusz Próchniak Department of Economics II Warsaw School of Economics 1 Background During 1972-82,the dominant new classical theory

More information

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix

Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix Investors and Central Bank s Uncertainty Embedded in Index Options On-Line Appendix Alexander David Haskayne School of Business, University of Calgary Pietro Veronesi University of Chicago Booth School

More information

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina

FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina FDI as a source of finance in imperfect capital markets Firm-Level Evidence from Argentina Paula Bustos CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra September 2007 Abstract In this paper I analyze the financing and

More information

Business Cycle Models - A Review of the Published Works Paper, Part 1

Business Cycle Models - A Review of the Published Works Paper, Part 1 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES 2008-02 McMASTER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics Kenneth Taylor Hall 426 1280 Main Street West Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4M4 http://www.mcmaster.ca/economics/

More information

Analysis of the U.S. labor market is a difficult

Analysis of the U.S. labor market is a difficult Openings and Labor Turnover Job Openings and Labor Turnover New tools for labor market analysis: JOLTS As a single, direct source for data on job openings, hires, and separations, the Job Openings and

More information

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Downward Nominal Wage Rigidities Bend the Phillips Curve Mary C. Daly Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Bart Hobijn Federal Reserve Bank of

More information

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS

REAL BUSINESS CYCLE THEORY METHODOLOGY AND TOOLS Jakub Gazda 42 Jakub Gazda, Real Business Cycle Theory Methodology and Tools, Economics & Sociology, Vol. 3, No 1, 2010, pp. 42-48. Jakub Gazda Department of Microeconomics Poznan University of Economics

More information

A Decomposition of the Increased Stability of GDP Growth

A Decomposition of the Increased Stability of GDP Growth FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE September 1999 Volume 5 Number 13 A Decomposition of the Increased Stability of GDP Growth Margaret M. McConnell, Patricia C. Mosser, and Gabriel

More information

Using Policy to Stabilize the Economy

Using Policy to Stabilize the Economy Using Policy to Stabilize the Economy Since the Employment ct of 1946, economic stabilization has been a goal of U.S. policy. Economists debate how active a role the govt should take to stabilize the economy.

More information

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital

Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Asymmetry and the Cost of Capital Javier García Sánchez, IAE Business School Lorenzo Preve, IAE Business School Virginia Sarria Allende, IAE Business School Abstract The expected cost of capital is a crucial

More information

Statement by. Janet L. Yellen. Chair. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Financial Services

Statement by. Janet L. Yellen. Chair. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. before the. Committee on Financial Services For release at 8:30 a.m. EST February 10, 2016 Statement by Janet L. Yellen Chair Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System before the Committee on Financial Services U.S. House of Representatives

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model The Basic New Keynesian Model January 11 th 2012 Lecture notes by Drago Bergholt, Norwegian Business School Drago.Bergholt@bi.no I Contents 1. Introduction... 1 1.1 Prologue... 1 1.2 The New Keynesian

More information