What is What?: A Simple Time-Domain Test of Long-memory vs. Structural Breaks

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "What is What?: A Simple Time-Domain Test of Long-memory vs. Structural Breaks"

Transcription

1 What is What?: A Simple Time-Domain Test of Long-memory vs. Structural Breaks By Juan J. Dolado a, Jesus Gonzalo a, and Laura Mayoral b a Dept. of Economics, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. b Dept. of Economics, Universidat Pompeu Fabra September 5, 2005 Abstract This paper proposes a new time-domain test of a process being I(d), 0 <d 1, under the null, against the alternative of being I(0) with deterministic components subject to structural breaks at known or unknown dates, with the goal of disentangling the existing identification issue between long-memory and structural breaks. Denoting by A B (t) the different types of structural breaks in the deterministic components of a time series considered by Perron (1989), the test statistic proposed here is based on the t-ratio (or the infimum of a sequence of t-ratios) of the estimated coefficient on y t 1 in an OLS regression of d y t on a simple transformation of the above-mentioned deterministic components and y t 1, possibly augmented by a suitable number of lags of d y t to account for serial correlation in the error terms. The case where d = 1 coincides with the Perron (1989) or the Zivot and Andrews (1992) approaches if the break date is known or unknown, respectively. The statistic is labelled as the SB-FDF (Structural Break-Fractional Dickey- Fuller) test, since it is based on the same principles as the well-known Dickey-Fuller unit root test. Both its asymptotic behavior and finite sample properties are analyzed, and two empirical applications are provided. We are grateful to Manuel Santos and participants in seminars at IGIER (Milan), ESEM 2004 (Madrid) and Univ.de Montreal for helpful comments. Special thanks go to Benedikt Pöstcher for help in one of the proofs. This research was supported by MCYT grants SEJ ECON, SEC and SEC and the Barcelona Economics Program of CREA. 1

2 1. INTRODUCTION This paper proposes a new test for the null hypothesis that a time-series process exhibits long-range dependence (LRD) against the alternative that it has short memory, but suffers from structural shifts in its deterministic components. The problem of distinguishing between both types of processes has been around for some time in the literature. The detection of LRD effects is often based on statistics of the underlying time series, such as the sample ACF, the periodogram, the R/S statistic, the rate of growth of the variances of partial sums of the series, etc. However, as pointed out some time ago in the applied probability literature,statisticsbasedonshortmemoryperturbedbysomekindofnonstationaritymay display similar properties as those prescribed by LRD under alternative assumptions (see e.g. Bhattacharya et al., 1983, and Teverosky and Taqqu, 1997). In particular, this is the case of short-memory processes affected by shifts in trends or in the mean. In a certain sense, it can be thought that the inherent difficulty of this identification problem originates directly from the fact that some of the statistics used to detect LRD were originally proposed to detect the existence of structural breaks (see Naddler and Robbins, 1971). More recently, a similar issue has re-emerged in the econometric literature dealing with financial data. For example, Ding and Granger (1996), and Mikosch and Starica (2004) claim that the LRD behavior detected in both the absolute and the squared returns of financial prices (bonds, exchange rates, options, etc.) may be well explained by changes in the parameters of one model to another over different subsamples due to significant events, such as the Great Depression of 1929, the oil-price shocks in the 1970s or the Black Monday of On the contrary, Lobato and Savin (1998) conclude that the LRD found in the squared returns is genuine and, thus, not an spurious feature. A useful starting point to pose this problem is to give some definitions of LRD (see e.g., Beran, 1994, Baillie, 1996, and Brockwell and Davies, 1991). In the time domain, LRD is defined for a stationary time series {y t } via the condition that lim j Pj ρ y (j) =, where ρ y denotes the ACF of sequence {y t }. Typically, for series exhibiting long-memory, this requires a hyperbolic decay of the autocorrelations instead of the standard exponen- 2

3 tial decay. In the frequency domain, LRD requires that the spectral density f y (ω) of the sequence is asymptotically of order L(ω)ω ν for some ν > 0 and a slowly varying function L(.), asω 0. Both characterizations are not necessarily equivalent, but for fractionally integrated processes of order d (henceforth, I(d)), to which we restrict our attention in the rest of the paper when defining the null hypothesis. Specifically, y t is said to be I(d) if (for some constants c ρ and c f ) ρ y (j) c ρ j 2d 1 for large j and d (0, 1 2 ),f y(ω) c f ω 2d for small frequencies ω, the variance of the partial sums of the series increases at the rate T 1+2d, and the normalized partial sums converge to fractional Brownian motion (fbm). Hence, fractional integration is a particular case of LRD. In view of these properties, a simple way to illustrate the source of confusion between an I(d) process and a short-memory one subject to structural breaks is to consider the following simple data generating process (DGP). Let y t be generated by an I(0) process whose mean is subject to a break at a known date T B, y t = α 1 +(α 2 α 1 )DU t (λ)+u t, (1) where u t is a zero-mean I(0) process with autocovariances γ u (j), λ = T B /T is the fraction of the sample where the break occurs, and DU t (λ) =1(t >T B ), with 1 <T B <T,is an indicator function of the breaking date. Then, denoting the sample mean by y T,itis straightforward to show by means of the ergodic theorem that the sample autocovariances of the sequence {y t } T t=1, given by eγ T,y (j) = 1 T behave as follows when T, T j X y t y t+j (y T ) 2,j N, (2) t=1 eγ T,y (j) γ u (j)+λ(1 λ)(α 2 α 1 ) 2 a.s., (3) for fixed j 1 and λ (0, 1). From (3), it can be observed that, even if the autocovariances γ u (j) decay to zero exponentially as j forlongerlagsasu t is I(0), the sequence of 3

4 sample autocovariances, eγ y (j), approaches a positive constant given by the second term in (3) as long as α 2 6= α 1. Thus, despite having a non-zero asymptote, the ACF of the process in (1) is bound to mimic the slow (hyperbolic) convergence to zero of LRD. 1 This presumption can be confirmed by performing a small Monte Carlo experiment. We simulate 1000 series of sample size T = 20, 000, such that y t is generated according to (1), with λ = 0.5, α 1 =0, ε t n.i.d. (0, 1). Three cases are considered: (α 2 α 1 )=0(no break), 0.2 (small break) and 0.5 (large break). Then, in order to examine the consequences of ignoring the break in the mean in (1), we estimate the order of fractional integration, d, of the series by means of the well-known Geweke and Porter-Hudak (GHP, 1983) semiparametric estimator at different frequencies ω 0 =2π/g(T ), including the popular choice in GPH estimation of g(t )=T 0.5. From the results in Table 1, it becomes clear that the estimates of d increase monotonically with the size of the shift in the mean, giving the wrong impression that y t is I(d), d>0 when it happens to be I(0) (a more detailed explanation can be found in Perron and Qu, 2004). Additionally, Figure 1 depicts, for T =20, 000, the estimated ACFs of two processes. The first one is a process like (1), with λ =0.5 and u t being an AR(1) process with a parameter equal to 0.7, while the second one is an I(d) process with d =0.3. As can be inspected, except for the first few autocorrelations, the ACFs behave very similarly in both cases. Thus, this type of result illustrates the source of confusion which has been stressed in the literature. The problem aggravates even more when the DGP contains a break in the trend. For example, using the same experiment with a DGP given by y t = α 1 + β 1 DT (λ) t + ε t,withdtt (λ) =(t T B )1 (TB +1 t T ), β 1 =0.1, and ε t n.i.d (0, 1) yields estimates of d in the range (1.008, ), depending on the choice of frequency, well in accord with the results of Perron (1989) about the lack of consistency of the DF test of a unit root in such a case. 1 This result has been recently generalized by Mikosch and Starica (2004) to the case of multiple breaks in the mean. 4

5 I(d) I(0)+break Fig. 1.Sample ACF of an I(d)and an I(0)+break processes. Table 1 GPH Estimates of d (DGP(1)) Frequency T 0.5 T 0.45 T 0.4 T 0.35 α 2 α 1 = α 2 α 1 = α 2 α 1 = Rejection of the null hypothesis d=0 at 1% significance level (s.l.). Along this way of reasoning, similar results about the possibility of confusing other types of nonlinear models with I(d) processes have been derived very recently in slightly different frameworks to the one discussed in (1). First, there is Parke s (1999) error duration (ED) model, which considers the cumulation of a sequence of shocks that switch to 0 after a random delay that follows a power law distribution, so that if the delays were of infinite extent the process would be a random walk, and if of zero extent, an i.i.d. process. Controlling the probability that a shock survives for k periods, p k,todecreasewithk at the 5

6 rate p k = s 2d 2 for d (0, 1], Parke shows that the ED model generates a process with thesameautocovariancestructureasani(d) process, i.e., γ y (j) =O(T 2d 1 ) for large j. Secondly, there are Granger and Hyung s (1999) and Diebold and Inoue s (2001) models which consider processes that are stationary and short memory, but exhibit periodic regime shifts, i.e., random changes in the mean of the series. For example, consider a DGP with y t = m t +ε t and m t = q t η t, where =(1 L), andsuchthatq t follows an i.i.d. binomial distribution where q t =1with probability p and q t =0with probability (1 p), andε t and η t are independent i.i.d. processes. Then, by assuming that the regime-shift probability p declines at a certain rate as the sample size increases, i.e., p = O(T 2d 2 ), it can be shown that the variance of the partial sums in this model will be related to the sample size in just thesamewayasinani(d) process, i.e., increasing at the rate T 1+2d. Therefore, the message to be drawn from all these works is that modelers face a hazard of mis-identification when the incidence of structural shifts is linked to the sample size in a particular ad hoc way. On the whole, the class of models described above are nonlinear models capable of reproducing some observationally equivalent characteristics of I(d) processes, albeit not all. 2 Moreover, they do so as long as the incidence of the shifts is related to the sample size in the specific fashion described earlier, which may be too restrictive in practice. For this reason, we consider more relevant for practitioners to develop a test statistic which helps to distinguish an I(d) process from a short-memory process subject to a small number of breaks, in the spirit of DGP (1). Since among the I(0) processes subject to breaks, the ones having more impact on empirical research are those popularized by Perron (1989), which are tested against I(1) processes as the null, our main contribution in this paper is to extend Perron s testing approach to the more general setting of I(d) processes, with d (0, 1], insteadof d =1. For the most part, our analysis in the sequel will focus on the case of a single break, although we briefly conjecture about how to deal with processes containing more breaks. In parallel with Perron (1989) who uses suitably modified Dickey-Fuller (DF) tests for 2 Davidson and Sibbersten (2003) have recently demonstrated that the normalized sequence partial sums of {y t} generated by the ED and the other periodic regime shift models do not converge to fbm. 6

7 the I(1) vs. I(0) case in the presence of regime shifts, our strategy lies upon generalizing the Fractional Dickey-Fuller (FDF) approach proposed by Dolado, Gonzalo and Mayoral (DGM, 2002, 2004) to test I(1) vs. I(d), 0 d<1, but now suitably modified to test I(d) vs. I(0) cum structural breaks. In DGM (2002) it was shown that if the order of fractional integration under the alternative is 0 d<1 and no deterministic components are present, then an unbalanced OLS regression of the form y t = φ d y t 1 + ε t, yields aconsistenttestofh 0 : d =1against H 1 : d [0, 1) based on the t-ratio of b φ ols in the previous regression model. 3 If the error term in the DGP is autocorrelated, then the regression should be augmented with a suitable number of lagged values of y t. The degree of integration under the alternative hypothesis (d 1 ) canbetakentobeknown(inasimple alternative) or estimated with a T 1 2 -consistent estimator (in a composite alternative). 4 deterministic components, µ(t), are present under the null (say, a constant or a linear trend), DGM (2004) derive a FDF test now based on the regression y t = H(L)µ(t)+φ d y t 1 +ε t, where H(L) = φ d L. Despite focusing on the test of I(1) vs. I(d) processes, DGM (2002) show that their results could be generalized to the case where the degrees of fractional integration under the null (d 0 ) and the alternative (d 1 ) verify the inequality d 1 <d 0. Accordingly, we propose in this paper a new test of I(d) vs. I(0) cum structural breaks, namely d 0 = d (0, 0.5) (0.5, 1] 5 and d 1 =0, along the lines of the well-known procedures proposed by Perron (1989) when the date of the break is taken to be aprioriknown, and the extensions of Banerjee et al. (1992) and Zivot and Andrews (1992) when it is assumed to be unknown. 3 To operationalise the FDF test, the regressor d y t 1 is constructed by applying the truncated binomial expansion of the filter (1 L) d to y t,sothat d y t = P t 1 0 π i(d) y t i, where π i(d) is the i-th coefficient in that expansion given by π i = Γ (i d) /Γ ( d) Γ (i +1)with Γ (.) the Gamma function. 4 Empirical applications of such a testing procedure can be found in DGM (2003), whereas a generalization of the FDF test in the I(1) vs. I(d) case allowing for deterministic components (drift/ linear trend) under the maintained hypothesis has been developed in DGM (2004). 5 Although the case of d =0.5 was treated in DGM (2002), it constitutes a discontinuity point in the analysis of I(d) processes; cf. Liu (1998). For this reason, as is often the case in the literature, we exclude this possibility in our analysis. Nonetheless, to simplify notation in the sequel, we will refer to the permissable range of d under the null as 0 <d 1. If 7

8 To avoid confusion with the FDF for unit roots, the test presented hereafter will be denoted as the Structural Break FDF test (SB-FDF henceforth). It is based on the t-ratio of φ b ols in an OLS regression of the form d 0 y t = Π(L)A B (t)+φ y t 1 + ε t, where Π(L) = d φl and A B (t) captures different structural breaks. As in Perron (1989), we will consider the following possibilities: a crash shift, a changing growth shift, and a combination of both. 6 At this stage it should be stressed that a test that extends Perron s DF testing approach of I(1) vs. I(0) cum structural breaks to a null of I(d) with d (0, 1] can be very useful in order to improve the power of the DF test when the true process is I(d) but d<1. Insuch an instance, Sowell (1990) and Krämer (1998) have shown that the DF and ADF tests are consistent,i.e.theyrejectthenullofi(1) with probability one as the sample size tends to infinity. However, the simulation results in Diebold and Rudebusch (1991) indicate that the power against fractional alternatives in finite samples can be low in some cases. To obtain further evidence on this issue, we report in Table 2 the rejection frequencies of Zivot and Andrews (1992) generalization of Perron s (1989) DF test in the case where the true DGP is an I(d) process with 0 <d<1, and I(1) is tested against I(0) cum a changing growth shift, assuming that T B is unknown. The number of replications is 5, 000 and ε t n.i.d (0, 1). As can be observed, when T =100, the rejection frequencies of the I(1) null hypothesis are high for values of d up to 0.7 but then, as one would expect, falls drastically as d gets closer to unity. For T =400, this reduction in power occurs when d is above 0.8. In light of our previous discussion about the confound of LRD and structural breaks, these results seem to imply that, when the true series is I(d), for low and moderate values of d, oneis bound to find structural breaks too often, whereas for high values of d, the false null of I(1) will hardly be rejected. Thus, this evidence supports the need of a test where the null 6 Note, however, that extensions to more than one break, along the lines of Bai and Perron (1998) and Bai (1999) should not be too difficult to devise once the simple case of a single break is is worked out. Some discussion on this case can be found in Section 4. 8

9 is I(d). TABLE 2 PowerofDFtestofI(1)vs.I(0)+breaks Regression Model: y t = α + βt + γdt t (0.5) + φy t 1 + ε t DGP: d 0 y t = ε t ; ε t n.i.d (0, 1) Sample size/d T= % 100% 99.9% 99.7% 94.4% 73.0% 38.0% 14.2% 4.0% T= % 100% 100% 100% 100% 99.9% 93.5% 49.9% 8.9% Lastly, to place our SB-FDF test in the existing literature, it is convenient to differentiate between several characterizations of the process governing the evolution of a time series under the null and alternative hypotheses. These different characterizations depend upon the degree of integration of the series and the potential existence of structural breaks in its deterministic components. Specifically, four possibilities can be considered: (I) I(0) and no structural breaks; (II) I(0) and structural breaks; (III) I(d) and no structural breaks, and (IV) I(d) and structural breaks. The cases (I) against (II), and (I) against (III) have been extensively analyzed in the literature; cf. for the former see Perron (2005), and for the latter see Robinson (2003). The case (III) against (IV), when 0 <d<0.5, has also been treated, among others, by Hidalgo and Robinson (1996) when the break date is assumed to be known, and by Lazarova (2003) who extends their analysis to the case where the break date is considered to be unknown. Using a frequency-domain approach, Hidalgo and Robinson (1996) derive a test statistic whose limiting distribution under the null of no break is chisquared for the former case, whereas in the case of an unknown break critical values need to be obtained by bootstrap methods (see Lazarova, 2003). Sibbertsen and Venetis (2004) have also studied the case where there are only shifts in mean, the break date is considered to be unknown, and 0 <d<0.5. Their test is based upon the (squared) difference between the GPH estimator of d and its tapered version, which converges to zero under the null of no break and diverges under the alternative of a break. It has a limiting chi-squared 9

10 distribution if the errors are gaussian; otherwise, again bootstrap methods need to be used to obtain critical values. The case (II) versus (IV) has been treated by Giraitis, Kokoszka and Leipus (2001) who analyze how large the size of the mean shift in an I(0) series has to be in order to be mistaken with a stationary long-memory process (0 <d<0.5) in a given sample. In comparison to all these previous works, the case considered in this paper is (III) against (II) which surprisingly has received much less attention in the literature. This is the case that can really help in solving the identification issue between LRD and SB which can be extremely relevant for at least three reasons: (i) shock identification (persistent vs. transitory), (ii) forecasting (do we need a long-history of the time series or only a short past will be of much use in forecasting?), and (iii) detection of spurious fractional cointegration (see Gonzalo and Lee, 1998). Indeed, Giraitis, Kokoszka and Leipus (2001) and the comments by Robinson to Lobato and Savin (1998) have stressed the importance of constructing a proper test statistic to distinguish between these alternative specifications. However, so far, the only attempt in this direction that we know of is Mayoral (2004a) whose approach relies upon a LR test in the time domain, but which is can only be applied to non-stationary processes under the null. Thus, to the best of our knowledge, there is not yet any available test in the literature for testing I(d) versus I(0) cum structural breaks allowing for both stationary and non-stationary processes under the null-hypothesis. This is the goal of the proposed SB-FDF test, which additionally presents the advantage of not requiring a correct specification of a parametric model and other distributional assumptions, besides being computationally simple since it is based on an OLS regression. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we derive the properties of the FDF test for I(d) vs. I(0) in the presence of deterministic components, like a constant or a linear trend, but without considering breaks yet, to next discuss the effects on this test of ignoring structural breaks in means or slopes when they exist. 7 Given that, as 7 Note that the FDF tests proposed in DGM (2002, 2004) refer to the case of I(1) vs. I(d). Thus, this section extends our previous results to the new setup of I(d) vs. I(0), with d (0, 1]. 10

11 discussed above, the power of this test can be severely affected by parameter changes in the deterministic component of the process, the SB-FDF test of I(d) vs I(0) with a single structural break at a known or an unknown date is introduced in Section 3, where both its limiting and finite-sample properties are analyzed in detail. Section 4 contains a brief discussion of how to modify the test to account for autocorrelated disturbances, in the spirit of the ADF test, leading to the SB-AFDF test (where A stands for augmented versions of the test-statistics) and conjectures on how to generalize the testing strategy to multiple breaks, rather than a single one. Section 5 contains two empirical applications; the first application deals with long U.S GNP series, where the stochastic or deterministic nature of their trending components has engendered some controversy in the literature; the second application centers on the behavior of the absolute values and squares of financial logreturns series, which has also been subject to some dispute. Finally, Section 6 concludes. Appendix A gathers the proofs of theorems and lemmae while Appendix B contains the tables of critical values for the cases where the limiting distributions are non-standard. 2. THE FDF TEST FOR I(d) vs. I (0) 2.1 Preliminaries Before considering the case of structural breaks, it is convenient to start by analyzing the problem of testing I(d), with 0 <d 1, against trend stationarity, i.e. d =0, along the lines of the FDF framework for the general case of I(d 0 ) vs. I(d 1 ) processes. The motivation for doing this is twofold. First, taking an I (d) process as a generalization of the unit root parameterization, the question of whether the trend is better represented as a stochastic or a deterministic component arises on the same grounds as in the I (1) case. And, secondly, the analysis in this subsection will provide the foundation for the treatment of the general case where non-stationarity can arise due to the presence of structural breaks. Under the alternative hypothesis, H 1, we consider processes with an unknown mean µ or a linear trend (µ + βt), y t = µ + ε t1 (t>0) d 0 φl, (4) 11

12 y t = µ + βt + ε t1 (t>0) d, (5) 0 φl where, ε t is assumed to be i.i.d.(0, σ 2 ε ), with 0 < σ 2 <, and d 0 (0, 1]. Hence, under H 1, d 0 y t = α + d 0 δ + φy t 1 + ε t, (6) d 0 y t = α + d 0 δ + γt + d 0 1 ϕ + φy t 1 + ε t, (7) where α = φµ, δ = µ, γ = φβ and ϕ = β. For simplicity, hereafter we write ε t 1 (t>0) = ε t. Under H 0, when φ =0, d 0y t = d 0µ + ε t in (6) and d 0y t = µ d 0 + β d ε t in (7). 8 Thus, E( d y t )= d µ and E( d y t )= d (µ + βt), respectively. Note that d µ = µ P t 1 i=0 π i (d) and β d 1 = β P t 1 i=0 π i (d 1) where the sequence {π i (ξ)} i=0 comes from the expansion of (1 L) ξ in powers of L and the coefficients are defined as π i (ξ) =Γ(i ξ)/[γ( ξ)γ (i +1)]. Inthesequel,weusethenotationτ t (ξ) = P t 1 i=1 π i (ξ). Also note that τ t (d) for d<0 induces a deterministic trend which is less steep than a linear trend and coincides with it when d = 1 since τ t ( 1) = P t 1 i=0 π i ( 1) = t. As demonstrated in DGM (2004), τ (.) is a concave function for values of d<0, being the function less steep the ³ smaller (in absolute value) d is. Under H 1, the polynomial Π (z) = (1 z) d φz has absolutely summable coefficients and verifies Π (0) = 1 and Π (1) = φ 6= 0. All the roots of the polynomial are outside the unit circle if 2 d < φ < 0. As in the DF framework, this condition excludes explosive processes. Consequently, under H 1,y t is I (0) and admits the representation y t = µ + u t, or y t = µ + βt + u t, u t = Λ (L) ε t, Λ (L) =Π (L) 1. 8 Note that d t = d 1 = d 1, after suitable truncation. 12

13 Computing the trends τ t (ξ), ξ = d or d 1 in (6) or (7) does not entail any difficulty since it only depends on d 0, which is known under H 0. As discussed earlier, the case where d 0 =1and a linear trend is allowed under the alternative of d 1 = d, 0 <d<1, has been analyzed in DGM (2004) where it is shown that the FDF test is (numerically) invariant to the values of µ and β in the DGP. Next, we derive the corresponding result for H 0 : d 0 = d, d (0, 1] vs. H 1 : d 1 =0. The following theorem summarizes the main result. Theorem 1 Under the null hypothesis that y t is an I (d) process defined as in (4) or (5) with φ =0, the OLS coefficient associated to φ in regression model (6), ˆφ µ ols, or (7), ˆφ τ ols, respectively is a consistent estimator of φ =0and converges at a rate T d if 0.5 <d 1 and at the usual rate T 1/2 when 0 <d<0.5. The asymptotic distribution of the associated t statistic, t iˆφols,i={µ, τ} is given by and R 1 t iˆφols w 0 Bi d (r) db (r) ³ R 1 0 B i d (r), if 0.5 <d 1, 2 d (r) 1/2 t iˆφols w N (0, 1), if 0 <d<0.5, where w denotes weak convergence and Bd i (r) with i ={µ, τ} is the L 2 projection residual from the continuous time regressions 9 B d (r) =ˆα 0 +ˆα 2 r d + B µ d (r) and B d (r) =ˆα 0 + ˆα 1 r d +ˆα 2 r 1 d +ˆα 3 r + Bd τ (r), respectively. The intuition for this result is similar to the one offered by DGM (2002) in the case of I(1) vs. I(d) processes with 0 <d<1. The different nature of the limiting distributions depend on the distance between d 0 and d 1. When d 0 (=1in the DGM case ) and d 1 are close, then the asymptotic distribution is asymptotically normal whereas it is a functional R 9 1 The parameters ˆα 0, ˆα 1, ˆα 2, and ˆα 3 solve min α0,α 1 B 0 d (r) ˆα 0 ˆα 1 r d 2 dr and R 1 min α0,α 1,α 2,α 3 B 0 d (r) ˆα 0 ˆα 1 r d +ˆα 2 r 1 d +ˆα 3 r 2 dr for the constant and constant and trend cases, respectively. 13

14 of fbm when both parameters are far apart. Hence, since in our case d 0 = d, 0 <d 1, and d 1 =0, asymptotic normality arises when 0 <d<0.5. Also note that d 0 =1renders the standard DF limiting distribution. The finite-sample critical values of the cases considered in Theorem 1 are presented in Appendix B (Tables B1 and B2). Three sample sizes are considered, T = 100, 400 and 1, 000, andthenumberofreplicationsis10, 000. Table B1 gathers the corresponding critical values for the case where the DGP is a pure I(d) without drift (since the test is invariant to the value of µ), i.e, d y t = ε t with ε t n.i.d (0, 1), when (6) is considered to be the regression model. Table B2, in turn, offers the corresponding critical values when (7) is taken to be the regression model. As can be observed, the empirical critical values are close to those of a standardized N(0, 1) (whose critical values for the three significance levels reported below are 1.28, 1.64 and 2.33, respectively, ) when 0 <d<0.5, particularly for T 400. However, for d>0.5 the critical values start to differ drastically from those of a normal distribution, increasing in absolute value as d gets larger. As for power, Table 3 reports the rejection rates at the 5% level (using the effective sizes in Table B2) of the FDF test in (7) in a similar Monte Carlo experiment to the one above, where now the DGP is an i.i.d. process cum a linear trend, i.e., y t = α + βt + ε t,with α =0.1, β =0.5. The main finding is that, except for low values of d and T =100where rejection rates of the null still reach 55%, the test turns out to be very powerful in all the other cases. 14

15 TABLE 3 Power (Corrected size: 5%) Regression Model: d 0 y t = α + δτ t (d)+γt + ϕτ t (d 1) + φy t 1 + ε t DGP: y t = α + βt + ε t ; α =0.1, β =0.5, ε t n.i.d (0, 1) d 0 /Samplesize T =100 T =400 T = % 98.9% 100% % 100% 100% % 100% 100% % 100% 100% % 100% 100% 2.2 The effects of structural breaks on the FDF test of I(d) vs. I(0) Following Perron s (1989) analysis in his Theorem 1, our next step is to assess the effects on the FDF tests for I(d) vs. I(0) of ignoring the presence in the DGP of a shift in the mean of the series or a shift in the slope of the linear trend. Let us first consider the consequences of performing the FDF test with an invariant mean,astheonediscussedabove,whenthe DGP contains a break in the mean. Thus, y t is assumed to be generated by, DGP 1 : y t = µ 0 + ζ 0 DU t (λ)+ε t, (8) where ε t iid(0, σ 2 ε) and DU t (λ) =1 (TB +1 t T ). Ignoring the break in the mean, the SB-FDF test will be based on regression (6) which is repeated for convenience d y t = α + δτ t (d)+φy t 1 + ε t. (9) Then, the following theory holds. Theorem 2 If y t isgivenbydgp1in(8)andregressionmodel(9) is used to estimate φ, 15

16 when T B = λt for all T and 0 < λ < 1, then, as T, it follows that, and, p dσ ˆφ 2 ols ε[c1 2 (d) C 2(d)] D (d, σ 2, if 0 ε) < d < 0.5, p dσ ˆφ 2 ols [ζ 2 0 λ (1, if 0.5 λ)+σ2 ε] < d 1, tˆφols p, if 0 <d 1, where p denotes convergence in probability, D ³ d, σ 2 ε = C 2 1 (d)[ζ 0 λ (1 λ)+σ 2 ε] C 2 {ζ 2 0(2 λ λ 1 d ) 2λ λ 1 d 1 + σ 2 ε}, and C 1 (d) =Γ (2 d), C 2 (d) =Γ 2 (1 d)(1 2d). Theorem 2 shows that, under the crash hypothesis, the limit depends on the size of relative shift in the mean, ζ 0. Note that if λ =0or λ =1, i.e., when there is no break, then b φ ols p d. This result is quite intuitive since, being yt I(0) under DGP 1, the covariance between d y t and y t 1 is π 1 (d) = d. Further, for d =1, the expression in part (a) in Theorem 1 of Perron (1989) is recovered, generalizing therefore his results to the more general case of d (0, 1]. Moreover, the fact that b φ ols converges to a finite negative number implies that T 1/2 b φols for d (0, 0.5), T d b φols for d (0.5, 1) and the corresponding t-ratios in each case will diverge to. Thus the FDF test for I(d) vs. I(0) would eventually reject the null hypothesis of d = d 0, 0 <d 0 < 1, when it happens to be false. Notice, however, that, as in Perron s analysis, the power of the FDF test will be decreasing in the distance between the null and the alternative, namely as d gets closer to its true zero value, and in the size of the break, namely as ζ 0 gets larger relative to σ 2 ε. Next consider the case where there is a (continuous) break in the slope of the linear trend, such that y t is generated by, DGP 2 : y t = µ 0 + β 0 t + ψ 0 DT t (λ)+ε t, (10) 16

17 where DTt (λ) =(t T B )1 (TB +1 t T ). The FDF test is again implemented ignoring the breaking trend, that is, it is computed in the regression, d y t = α + γt + δτ t (d)+ϕτ t (d 1) + φy t 1 + ε t. (11) Theorem 3 If y t is given by DGP 2 in (10) and regression model (11) is used to estimate φ,when T B = λt for all T and 0 < λ < 1, then, as T, it follows that t bφols p + if 0 <d<0.5, and, p t bφols 0, if 0.5 <d 1. In contrast to the result in Theorem 2, the FDF is unambiguously inconsistent when a breaking trend is ignored. The intuition behind this result, which again extends part (b) of Theorem 1 in Perron (1989) to our more general setting, is that φ b ols is O p (T d ) with a positive limiting constant term for d (0, 1] and that the sample s.d ( φ b ols ) is O p (T 1/2 ), implying that the t-ratio is O p (T 1/2 d ). Therefore, it will tend to 0, for d (0.5, 1], and to +, for d (0, 0.5). In sum, the FDF test for I(d) vs. I(0) without consideration of structural shifts is not consistent against breaking trends and, despite being consistent against a break in the mean, its power is likely to be reduced if such a break is large. Hence, there is a need for alternative forms of the FDF test that could distinguish an I(d) process from a process being I(0) around deterministic terms subject to structural breaks. 3. THE SB-FDF TEST OF I(d) vs. I(0) WITH STRUCTURAL BREAKS Given the above considerations, we now proceed to derive the SB-FDF invariant test for I(d) vs. I(0) allowing for structural breaks under H 1. To account for structural breaks, we consider the following variant of (5) as the maintained hypothesis, y t = A B (t)+ a t1(t >0) d φl, (12) 17

18 where A B (t) is a linear deterministic trend function that may contain breaks at unknown dates (in principle, just a single break at date T B would be considered) and a t is a stationary I (0) process. In line with Perron (1989) and Zivot and Andrews (1992), the null hypothesis of I(d) will be implied by a value of φ =0whereas φ < 0 means that the process is I(0). In line with these papers, three definitions of A B (t) are considered, Case A : A A B(t) =µ 0 +(µ 1 µ 0 )DU t (λ), (13) Case B: A B B(t) =µ 0 + β 0 t +(β 1 β 0 )DT t (λ), (14) Case C: A C B(t) =µ 0 + β 0 t +(µ 1 µ 0 )DU t (λ)+(β 1 β 0 )DT t (λ). (15) Case A corresponds to the crash hypothesis, case B to the changing growth hypothesis and case C to a combination of both. The dummy variables DU t (λ) and DTt (λ) are defined as before, and DT t (λ) =t1 (TB +1 t T ) with λ = T B /T. Initially, let us assume that the break date T B is known a priori and that a t = ε t where ε t is an i.i.d(0, σ 2 ) process. Then, the SB-FDF test of I(d) vs. I(0) in the presence of structural breaks is based on the t-ratio of the coefficient φ in the regression model, d y t = d A i B(t) φa i B(t 1) + φy t 1 + ε t,i= A, B, and C. (16) As above, the SB-FDF test is invariant to the values of µ 0,µ 1, β 0 and β 1 under H 0. Following the discussion in section 2.1, it is easy to check that under H 1 : φ < 0, y t is I(0) and is subject to the regime shifts defined by A i B (t). Conversely, under H 0 : φ =0,the process is I(d) with E[ d (y t A i B (t))]=0. Using similar arguments to those employed in Theorem 1, the following theory holds. 18

19 Theorem 4 Let y t be a process generated as in (12) with a t = ε t i.i.d 0, σ 2. Then, when T B = λt for all T and 0 < λ < 1, under the null hypothesis of φ =0, the OLS estimator associated to φ in regression model (16), as T, is consistent. The asymptotic distribution of the associated t ratio is given by, R 1 t i w φ(λ) b 0 B i d (λ,r) db (r) ³ R if d 1 1/2 0 B i d (λ,r)2 d (r) (0.5, 1], t i b φ(λ) w N(0, 1) if d (0, 0.5), where Bd i (.,.) is the L 2 projection residual from the corresponding continuous time regressions associated to models i = {A, B, and C}, defined in Appendix A. Although it was previously assumed that the date of the break T B is known, in general this might not be the case. Thus, we explore in what follows how to implement the SB-FDF test under this more realistic situation. For that, we follow the approach in Banerjee et al. (1992) and Zivot and Andrews (1992) by assuming that, under H 0, no break occurs, that is, φ =0,µ 0 = µ 1 and β 0 = β 1, implying that (12) can be written as, or, where a t is an I(0) process. d (y t µ 0 )=a t,ifi= A, t =1, 2,..., (17) d (y t µ 0 β 0 t)=a t,ifi= {B and C}, t=1, 2,..., (18) As discussed before, under the alternative hypothesis, the process is I(0) and may contain a single break in (some of) the parameters associated to the deterministic components, that occurs at an unknown time T B = λt, λ Λ (0, 1). Then, the potential break point under H 1 willbeestimatedinsuchawaythatgivesthe highest weight to the I(0) alternative. The estimation strategy will therefore consist in choosing the break point that gives the least favorable result for the null hypothesis of I(d) using the SB-FDF test in (16) for each of the three cases, i = A, B, and C. Thet statistic on ˆφ i ols, t bφ(λ), is computed for the values of λ Λ =(0.15, 0.85), following Andrews (1993) 19

20 choice of range, and then the infimum (most negative) value would be chosen to run the test. Thus, the test would reject the null hypothesis when inf t b λ Λ φ(λ) >kinf,α i, where kinf,α i is a critical value to be provided in Appendix B. Under these conditions, the following theory holds. Theorem 5 Let y t be a process generated as in (17) or (18) with a t ε t i.i.d 0, σ 2 and possibly µ 0 = β 0 =0. Let Λ be a closed subset of (0, 1). Then, under the null hypothesis of φ =0, the asymptotic distribution of the t statistic associated to φ in regression model (16), (witha A B (t) if y t is generated by (17) and A B B (t) or AC B (t) if y t is generated in (18)) is given by, and, inf λ Λ ti w φ(λ) b inf λ Λ R 1 0 B i d (λ,r) db (r) if d (0.5, 1], i = {A, B and C} 1/2 ³ R 1 0 B i d (λ,r)2 d (r) inf λ Λ ti w φ(λ) b N(0, 1) if d (0, 0.5). To compute critical values of the inf SB-FDF t-ratio test, a pure I (d 0 ) process with ε t n.i.d.(0, 1) has been simulated 10, 000 times, whereas the three regression models (A, B, and C) have been considered for samples of size T =100, 400, Notice hat the sequence {t i b φ(λ) } are normally distributed and perfectly correlated. Hence, as shown in the proof of Theorem 5, the inf of this sequence corresponds to a N(0, 1) as well. However, in finite samples, there are several asymptotically negligible terms which depend on the product (1 λ) 1 T 2δ, 0 < δ < 1, which may be sizeable for sufficiently large (small) values of λ (δ) at a given T (see equation A.2 in the Appendix). Tables B3, B4 and B5 in Appendix B report the corresponding critical values which, due to the presence of those terms, are larger (in absolute value) than the critical values of the SB-FDF test reported in Tables B1 and B2 when considering the left tail. Even for T =1000, the critical values for d (0, 0.5) are to the left of those of a N(0, 1) and, in unreported simulations, we 20

21 found that they slowly converge to them for sample sizes with around 5000 observations. Thus, for smaller sample sizes, we advice to use the effective critical values rather than the nominal ones. In order to examine the power of the test, we have generated 5000 replications of DGP 2(10)withsamplesizesT =100and 400, where λ =0.5, i.e., a changing growth model with a break in the middle of the sample. Both regression models B and C, in (16), have been estimated. Rejection rates are reported in Table 4 where, in order to compute the size-corrected power, the corresponding critical values in Tables B4 and B5 have been used. The power is very high except when d =0.1 and T =100but even in this case it is close to 50% when T = TABLE 4 Power inf SB-FDF, I(d) vs. I(0) + S.B. Regression Model: d y t = d A i B (t) φai B (t 1) + φy t 1 + ε t,i= {B, C} dgp: y t = µ 0 + β 0 t + ψ 0 DTt (λ)+ε t ; µ 0 =1, β 0 =0.5, λ =0.5, ε t n.i.d (0, 1) ψ 0 =0.1 ψ 0 =0.2 RModel B RModel C RModel B RModel C d 0 /Sample size T=100 T=400 T=100 T=400 T=100 T=400 T=100 T= % 50.3% 14.5% 48.9% 13.7% 48.9% 12.4% 47.4% % 74.9% 26.2% 73.5% 66.3% 73.4% 62.9% 71.3% % 100% 68.8% 100% 99.8% 100% 99.6% 100% % 100% 98.0% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% % 100% 99.9% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 10 In DGM (2002, 2004), we provide both Monte-Carlo and analytical results showing that the FDF test for I(1) vs. I(d) processes has better size-corrected power, except for very local alternatives (and even in this case the loss in power is small), than other available time-domain tests in the literature, like Tanaka s (1999) LM test. Unreported calculations (available upon request), show that this is also the case for our new I(d) vs. I(0) testing setup. 21

22 4. AUGMENTED SB-FDF TEST AND MULTIPLE BREAKS The limiting distributions derived above are valid for the case where the innovations are i.i.d. and no extra terms are added in the regression equations. If some autocorrelation structure are allowed in the innovation process, then the asymptotic distributions will depend on some nuisance parameters. To solve the nuisance-parameter dependency, two approaches have been typically employed in the literature. One is the non-parametric approach proposed by Phillips and Perron (1988) which is based on finding consistent estimators for the nuisance parameters. The other, which is the one we follow here, is the well-known parametric approach proposed by Dickey and Fuller (1981) which consists of adding a suitable number of lags of d y t to the set of regressors (see DGM, 2002). As Zivot and Andrews (1992) point out, a formal proof of the limiting distributions when the assumption of i.i.d. disturbances is relaxed is likely to be very involved. However, along the lines of the proof for the AFDF test in Theorem 7 of DGM (2002), it can be conjectured that if the DGP is d y t = u t 1 (t>0) and u t follows an invertible and stationary ARMA(p, q) process α p (L)u t = β q (L)ε t with E ε t 4+δ < for some δ > 0, then the inf SB-FDF test based on the t-ratio of φ b ols in (19) augmented with k lags of d y t will have the same limiting distributions as in Theorem 5 above and will be consistent when T and k, as long as k 3 /T 0. Hence, the augmented SB-FDF test (denoted as SB-AFDF) will be based on the regression model, kx d y t = d A i B(t) φa i B(t 1) + φy t 1 + ς j d y t j + a t, i = A, B, and C. (19) Although a generalization of the previous results to multiple breaks is not considered in this paper, it is likely that this extension can be done following the same reasoning as in the procedure devised by Bai and Perron (1998). In their framework, where there are m possible breaks affecting the mean and the trend slope, they suggest the following procedure to select the number of breaks. Letting sup F T (l) be the F - statistic of no structural break (l =0)vs. k breaks (k m), they consider two statistics to test the null of no breaks against an unknown number of breaks given some specificboundonthemaximum number of shifts considered. The first one is the double maximum statistic (UD max ) where j=1 22

23 UD max =max 1 k m supf T (l) while the second one is supf t (l +1/l) which test the null of l breaks against the alternative of l +1 breaks. In practice, they advise to use a sequential procedure based upon testing first for one break and if rejected for a second one, etc., using the sequence of supf t (l +1/l) statistics. Therefore, our proposal is to use such a procedure to determine λ 1,..., λ k in the A B (t) terms in (16). By continuity of the sup function and tightness of the probability measures associated with t bφols, we conjecture that a similar result to that obtained in Theorem 5 would hold as well, this time with the sup of a suitable functional of fbm. Derivation of these results and computation of the corresponding critical values exceeds the scope of this paper but they are in our future research agenda. 5. EMPIRICAL APPLICATIONS In order to provide some empirical illustrations of how easy the SB-FDF test can be used in practice, we consider the following two applications. 5.1 Real GNP. The first application deals with the log. of a long series of U.S. real GNP, y t, which basically corresponds to the same data set used in Diebold and Senhadji (1996) (DS henceforth) in their discussion on whether GNP data is informative enough to distinguish between trend stationarity (T-ST) and first-difference stationarity (D-ST). The data are annual and range from 1869 to 2001 giving rise to a sample of 133 observations where the last 8 observations have been added to DS s original sample ending in 1995; cf. Mayoral (2004b), for a detailed discussion of the construction of the series. Since this series is based on the historical annual real GNP series constructed by Balke and Gordon (1989), it is denoted as GNP-BG. 11 According to DS s analysis, there is conclusive evidence in favor of T-ST and against D-ST. To achieve this conclusion, DS follow Rudebusch (1993) s bootstrap approach in computing the best-fitting T-ST and D-ST models for the series. Then, they compute the exact finite sample distribution of the t-ratios of the lagged (log. of) GNP-BG level in 11 Following DS (1996), we have also implemented the SB-FDF test to a long series of U.S. real GNP based on the historical annual series of Romer (1989). The results, available upon request, are not reported since they are very similar to those displayed in Table 5. 23

24 9 GNP-BG, series in logarithms Fig. 2. Plot of (logged) real GNP-BG series. an augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test for a unit root when the best-fitting T-ST D-ST models are used as the DGPs. Their main finding is that the p-value of the ADF test is very small under the D-ST model but quite large under the T-ST model, providing overwhelming support in favour of the latter model. Nonetheless, as DS acknowledge, rejecting the null does not mean that the alternative is a good characterization of the data. Indeed, Mayoral (2004b) has pointed out that when the same exercise is done with the well-known KPSS test, where the null is TS-T, it is also rejected in both series. This inconclusive outcome leads this author to conjecture that, since both the I(0) and I(1) null hypotheses are rejected, itmaybethecasethattherightprocessisani(d), 0 <d<1. Considering values of d in the range , she finds favorable evidence for an I(d) using the FDF test of I(1) vs. I(d), which rejects the null, and a LR test of I(d) vs. I(0), which does not reject the null. Nonetheless, from inspection of Figure 2, where the log. of GNP-BG is displayed, one could as well conjecture that the data are generated by a T-ST process subject to some structural breaks as in Perron (1989). Hence, given the mixed evidence about the data being generated either by an I(d) process or by an I(0) process cum structural breaks, this example provides a good illustration of the usefulness of the SB-FDF test. 24

25 In Table 5, we report the t-ratios of the inf SB-AFDF test constructed according to (19) where up to three lags of d y t have been included as additional regressors in order to account for residual correlation. The critical values that have been employed are those reported in Tables B4, B5 for T =100. Values of d in the non-stationary (albeit meanreverting) range (0.5, 1) have been used to construct d y t and d A i B (t), i= B, and C, since the trending behaviour of the series precludes the use of model A which does not include a linear trend in the maintained hypothesis. TABLE 5 inf SB-AFDF Tests GNP-BG series Model Model B Model C Lags/d C.V. (95%) number of lags chosen by the AIC criterion. Rejection at the 95% s.l. As can be inspected, the null of I(d) cannot be rejected at the conventional significance level. Interestingly, this result against T-ST is reinforced by application of the conventional Zivot and Andrews (1992) inf test for the null of I(1), with two lags, which yields values of 4.23 (model B) and 5.03 (model C) against 5% critical values of 4.42 and 5.08, respectively. However, concluding that the series is I(1) may not be correct (see Table 2), given the results of the SB-AFDF test which does not reject the null for large values of d, yet below unity. In sum, the evidence provided by the SB-FDF test seems to point out that the GNP-BG series behaves as an I(d) process with a large d. This result is qualitatively consistent with 25

26 other empirical investigations of fractional processes in GNP, such as Sowell (1992), on the basis that GNP is obtained by aggregating heterogeneously persistent sectorial value added which, according to Granger s (1980) aggregation argument, yields long memory. In the same direction, recently Michelacci (2004) has shown that if Gibrat s law fails and small firms grow faster than big firms, as empirical evidence suggests, aggregate output should exhibit a fractional order of integration. 5.2 Financial returns. The second application deals with the (absolute values and squared) financial returns series, r t, obtained from the Standard & Poor s 500 composite stock index over the period January 2, 1953 to October 10, 1977 (the number of observations is 6217). Thisserieshas been modelled in several papers where it has been argued that shifts in the unconditional variance of an ARCH or GARCH model may induce the typical ACF of a long memory process (see, inter alia, Ding et al., 1996, Lobatoand Savin (1998), and Mikosch and Starica, 2004). Notice that, although the sample considered in these papers are quite longer than ours, we restrict our sample to because Mikosch and Starica (2004) claim that there is a single structural break in the constant term of a GARCH (1,1) model over that period, as a consequence of the first oil crisis in Since our proposed approach refers to a single shift, we deem this an appropriate choice of sample size. Further, the end of the sample has been chosen so that the potential break date in included in the range λ [0.15, 0.85] used to implement the inf SB-AFDF test. From Figure 3, where the stock returns are depicted, it becomes clear that the series experiences a higher variance after Figures 4a and b shows the ACF for the absolutes values, r t, and the squares, rt 2, respectively, which display the typical plateau for longer lags, as if LRD were present. The results of performing the inf SB-AFDF test for an unknown break date in version A ( no trend) of model (19) are shown in Table 6, where the number of lags is k =15(further lags were insignificant), and only values of d<0.5 have been used, in agreement with the 12 For example, the estimates of the GARCH (1,1) model σ 2 t = α 0 +α 1σ 2 t 1 +β 1 h 2 t 1 yield α 0 =.325x10 6, α 1 =0.150, β 1 =0.600 for T= and α 0 =.1.40x10 5, α 1 =0.150, β 1 =0.600 for T=

Minimum LM Unit Root Test with One Structural Break. Junsoo Lee Department of Economics University of Alabama

Minimum LM Unit Root Test with One Structural Break. Junsoo Lee Department of Economics University of Alabama Minimum LM Unit Root Test with One Structural Break Junsoo Lee Department of Economics University of Alabama Mark C. Strazicich Department of Economics Appalachian State University December 16, 2004 Abstract

More information

Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory

Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory Uwe Hassler and Jan Scheithauer Goethe-University Frankfurt This version: January 2, 2008 Abstract This paper studies some well-known tests for the null

More information

Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory

Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory Testing against a Change from Short to Long Memory Uwe Hassler and Jan Scheithauer Goethe-University Frankfurt This version: December 9, 2007 Abstract This paper studies some well-known tests for the null

More information

Non-Stationary Time Series andunitroottests

Non-Stationary Time Series andunitroottests Econometrics 2 Fall 2005 Non-Stationary Time Series andunitroottests Heino Bohn Nielsen 1of25 Introduction Many economic time series are trending. Important to distinguish between two important cases:

More information

The Power of the KPSS Test for Cointegration when Residuals are Fractionally Integrated

The Power of the KPSS Test for Cointegration when Residuals are Fractionally Integrated The Power of the KPSS Test for Cointegration when Residuals are Fractionally Integrated Philipp Sibbertsen 1 Walter Krämer 2 Diskussionspapier 318 ISNN 0949-9962 Abstract: We show that the power of the

More information

Probabilistic properties and statistical analysis of network traffic models: research project

Probabilistic properties and statistical analysis of network traffic models: research project Probabilistic properties and statistical analysis of network traffic models: research project The problem: It is commonly accepted that teletraffic data exhibits self-similarity over a certain range of

More information

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth

Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Testing for Granger causality between stock prices and economic growth Pasquale Foresti 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/2962/ MPRA Paper No. 2962, posted

More information

Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis Time Series Analysis Identifying possible ARIMA models Andrés M. Alonso Carolina García-Martos Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Universidad Politécnica de Madrid June July, 2012 Alonso and García-Martos

More information

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series.

The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Cointegration The VAR models discussed so fare are appropriate for modeling I(0) data, like asset returns or growth rates of macroeconomic time series. Economic theory, however, often implies equilibrium

More information

Sales forecasting # 2

Sales forecasting # 2 Sales forecasting # 2 Arthur Charpentier arthur.charpentier@univ-rennes1.fr 1 Agenda Qualitative and quantitative methods, a very general introduction Series decomposition Short versus long term forecasting

More information

Chapter 9: Univariate Time Series Analysis

Chapter 9: Univariate Time Series Analysis Chapter 9: Univariate Time Series Analysis In the last chapter we discussed models with only lags of explanatory variables. These can be misleading if: 1. The dependent variable Y t depends on lags of

More information

Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis Time Series Analysis Autoregressive, MA and ARMA processes Andrés M. Alonso Carolina García-Martos Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Universidad Politécnica de Madrid June July, 212 Alonso and García-Martos

More information

Testing for Cointegrating Relationships with Near-Integrated Data

Testing for Cointegrating Relationships with Near-Integrated Data Political Analysis, 8:1 Testing for Cointegrating Relationships with Near-Integrated Data Suzanna De Boef Pennsylvania State University and Harvard University Jim Granato Michigan State University Testing

More information

Semi Parametric Estimation of Long Memory: Comparisons and Some Attractive Alternatives

Semi Parametric Estimation of Long Memory: Comparisons and Some Attractive Alternatives Semi Parametric Estimation of Long Memory: Comparisons and Some Attractive Alternatives Richard T. Baillie Departments of Economics and Finance, Michigan State University Department of Economics, Queen

More information

Chapter 5: Bivariate Cointegration Analysis

Chapter 5: Bivariate Cointegration Analysis Chapter 5: Bivariate Cointegration Analysis 1 Contents: Lehrstuhl für Department Empirische of Wirtschaftsforschung Empirical Research and und Econometrics Ökonometrie V. Bivariate Cointegration Analysis...

More information

Performing Unit Root Tests in EViews. Unit Root Testing

Performing Unit Root Tests in EViews. Unit Root Testing Página 1 de 12 Unit Root Testing The theory behind ARMA estimation is based on stationary time series. A series is said to be (weakly or covariance) stationary if the mean and autocovariances of the series

More information

Software Review: ITSM 2000 Professional Version 6.0.

Software Review: ITSM 2000 Professional Version 6.0. Lee, J. & Strazicich, M.C. (2002). Software Review: ITSM 2000 Professional Version 6.0. International Journal of Forecasting, 18(3): 455-459 (June 2002). Published by Elsevier (ISSN: 0169-2070). http://0-

More information

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion

Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion Nonparametric adaptive age replacement with a one-cycle criterion P. Coolen-Schrijner, F.P.A. Coolen Department of Mathematical Sciences University of Durham, Durham, DH1 3LE, UK e-mail: Pauline.Schrijner@durham.ac.uk

More information

Univariate and Multivariate Methods PEARSON. Addison Wesley

Univariate and Multivariate Methods PEARSON. Addison Wesley Time Series Analysis Univariate and Multivariate Methods SECOND EDITION William W. S. Wei Department of Statistics The Fox School of Business and Management Temple University PEARSON Addison Wesley Boston

More information

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model

Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model Overview of Violations of the Basic Assumptions in the Classical Normal Linear Regression Model 1 September 004 A. Introduction and assumptions The classical normal linear regression model can be written

More information

Is the Basis of the Stock Index Futures Markets Nonlinear?

Is the Basis of the Stock Index Futures Markets Nonlinear? University of Wollongong Research Online Applied Statistics Education and Research Collaboration (ASEARC) - Conference Papers Faculty of Engineering and Information Sciences 2011 Is the Basis of the Stock

More information

Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models

Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models Econometrics 2 Spring 25 Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models Heino Bohn Nielsen of4 Outline of the Lecture () Introduction to univariate time series analysis. (2) Stationarity. (3) Characterizing

More information

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate?

Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate? University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Commerce - Papers (Archive) Faculty of Business 2013 Does the interest rate for business loans respond asymmetrically to changes in the cash rate? Abbas

More information

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU

PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS. Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU PITFALLS IN TIME SERIES ANALYSIS Cliff Hurvich Stern School, NYU The t -Test If x 1,..., x n are independent and identically distributed with mean 0, and n is not too small, then t = x 0 s n has a standard

More information

Unit root properties of natural gas spot and futures prices: The relevance of heteroskedasticity in high frequency data

Unit root properties of natural gas spot and futures prices: The relevance of heteroskedasticity in high frequency data DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 20/14 Unit root properties of natural gas spot and futures prices: The relevance of heteroskedasticity in high frequency data Vinod Mishra and Russell

More information

Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis Time Series Analysis hm@imm.dtu.dk Informatics and Mathematical Modelling Technical University of Denmark DK-2800 Kgs. Lyngby 1 Outline of the lecture Identification of univariate time series models, cont.:

More information

Testing for Unit Roots: What Should Students Be Taught?

Testing for Unit Roots: What Should Students Be Taught? Testing for Unit Roots: What Should Students Be Taught? John Elder and Peter E. Kennedy Abstract: Unit-root testing strategies are unnecessarily complicated because they do not exploit prior knowledge

More information

Powerful new tools for time series analysis

Powerful new tools for time series analysis Christopher F Baum Boston College & DIW August 2007 hristopher F Baum ( Boston College & DIW) NASUG2007 1 / 26 Introduction This presentation discusses two recent developments in time series analysis by

More information

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia

Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data. joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia Estimating the Degree of Activity of jumps in High Frequency Financial Data joint with Yacine Aït-Sahalia Aim and setting An underlying process X = (X t ) t 0, observed at equally spaced discrete times

More information

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE

ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE ECON20310 LECTURE SYNOPSIS REAL BUSINESS CYCLE YUAN TIAN This synopsis is designed merely for keep a record of the materials covered in lectures. Please refer to your own lecture notes for all proofs.

More information

Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights

Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights Supplement to Call Centers with Delay Information: Models and Insights Oualid Jouini 1 Zeynep Akşin 2 Yves Dallery 1 1 Laboratoire Genie Industriel, Ecole Centrale Paris, Grande Voie des Vignes, 92290

More information

Simple Linear Regression Inference

Simple Linear Regression Inference Simple Linear Regression Inference 1 Inference requirements The Normality assumption of the stochastic term e is needed for inference even if it is not a OLS requirement. Therefore we have: Interpretation

More information

Fractionally integrated data and the autodistributed lag model: results from a simulation study

Fractionally integrated data and the autodistributed lag model: results from a simulation study Fractionally integrated data and the autodistributed lag model: results from a simulation study Justin Esarey July 1, 215 Abstract Two contributions in this issue, Grant and Lebo (215) and Keele, Linn

More information

VI. Real Business Cycles Models

VI. Real Business Cycles Models VI. Real Business Cycles Models Introduction Business cycle research studies the causes and consequences of the recurrent expansions and contractions in aggregate economic activity that occur in most industrialized

More information

Empirical Properties of the Indonesian Rupiah: Testing for Structural Breaks, Unit Roots, and White Noise

Empirical Properties of the Indonesian Rupiah: Testing for Structural Breaks, Unit Roots, and White Noise Volume 24, Number 2, December 1999 Empirical Properties of the Indonesian Rupiah: Testing for Structural Breaks, Unit Roots, and White Noise Reza Yamora Siregar * 1 This paper shows that the real exchange

More information

Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models

Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models Econometrics 2 Fall 25 Univariate Time Series Analysis; ARIMA Models Heino Bohn Nielsen of4 Univariate Time Series Analysis We consider a single time series, y,y 2,..., y T. We want to construct simple

More information

Statistical Tests for Multiple Forecast Comparison

Statistical Tests for Multiple Forecast Comparison Statistical Tests for Multiple Forecast Comparison Roberto S. Mariano (Singapore Management University & University of Pennsylvania) Daniel Preve (Uppsala University) June 6-7, 2008 T.W. Anderson Conference,

More information

Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save

Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save Online Appendices to the Corporate Propensity to Save Appendix A: Monte Carlo Experiments In order to allay skepticism of empirical results that have been produced by unusual estimators on fairly small

More information

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract

Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Pricing of an Exotic Forward Contract Jirô Akahori, Yuji Hishida and Maho Nishida Dept. of Mathematical Sciences, Ritsumeikan University 1-1-1 Nojihigashi, Kusatsu, Shiga 525-8577, Japan E-mail: {akahori,

More information

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model

Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model Some stability results of parameter identification in a jump diffusion model D. Düvelmeyer Technische Universität Chemnitz, Fakultät für Mathematik, 09107 Chemnitz, Germany Abstract In this paper we discuss

More information

Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note

Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note ERC Working Paper in Economic 03/10 November 2003 Testing The Quantity Theory of Money in Greece: A Note Erdal Özmen Department of Economics Middle East Technical University Ankara 06531, Turkey ozmen@metu.edu.tr

More information

RANDOM INTERVAL HOMEOMORPHISMS. MICHA L MISIUREWICZ Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis

RANDOM INTERVAL HOMEOMORPHISMS. MICHA L MISIUREWICZ Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis RANDOM INTERVAL HOMEOMORPHISMS MICHA L MISIUREWICZ Indiana University Purdue University Indianapolis This is a joint work with Lluís Alsedà Motivation: A talk by Yulij Ilyashenko. Two interval maps, applied

More information

A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500

A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500 A Trading Strategy Based on the Lead-Lag Relationship of Spot and Futures Prices of the S&P 500 FE8827 Quantitative Trading Strategies 2010/11 Mini-Term 5 Nanyang Technological University Submitted By:

More information

Forecasting in supply chains

Forecasting in supply chains 1 Forecasting in supply chains Role of demand forecasting Effective transportation system or supply chain design is predicated on the availability of accurate inputs to the modeling process. One of the

More information

1 Short Introduction to Time Series

1 Short Introduction to Time Series ECONOMICS 7344, Spring 202 Bent E. Sørensen January 24, 202 Short Introduction to Time Series A time series is a collection of stochastic variables x,.., x t,.., x T indexed by an integer value t. The

More information

Lesson19: Comparing Predictive Accuracy of two Forecasts: Th. Diebold-Mariano Test

Lesson19: Comparing Predictive Accuracy of two Forecasts: Th. Diebold-Mariano Test Lesson19: Comparing Predictive Accuracy of two Forecasts: The Diebold-Mariano Test Dipartimento di Ingegneria e Scienze dell Informazione e Matematica Università dell Aquila, umberto.triacca@univaq.it

More information

Introduction to time series analysis

Introduction to time series analysis Introduction to time series analysis Margherita Gerolimetto November 3, 2010 1 What is a time series? A time series is a collection of observations ordered following a parameter that for us is time. Examples

More information

Uncovering Long Memory in High Frequency UK Futures

Uncovering Long Memory in High Frequency UK Futures UCD GEARY INSTITUTE DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Uncovering Long Memory in High Frequency UK Futures John Cotter University College Dublin Geary WP2004/14 2004 UCD Geary Institute Discussion Papers often represent

More information

Time series Forecasting using Holt-Winters Exponential Smoothing

Time series Forecasting using Holt-Winters Exponential Smoothing Time series Forecasting using Holt-Winters Exponential Smoothing Prajakta S. Kalekar(04329008) Kanwal Rekhi School of Information Technology Under the guidance of Prof. Bernard December 6, 2004 Abstract

More information

Advanced Forecasting Techniques and Models: ARIMA

Advanced Forecasting Techniques and Models: ARIMA Advanced Forecasting Techniques and Models: ARIMA Short Examples Series using Risk Simulator For more information please visit: www.realoptionsvaluation.com or contact us at: admin@realoptionsvaluation.com

More information

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles

Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Topic 5: Stochastic Growth and Real Business Cycles Yulei Luo SEF of HKU October 1, 2015 Luo, Y. (SEF of HKU) Macro Theory October 1, 2015 1 / 45 Lag Operators The lag operator (L) is de ned as Similar

More information

Some useful concepts in univariate time series analysis

Some useful concepts in univariate time series analysis Some useful concepts in univariate time series analysis Autoregressive moving average models Autocorrelation functions Model Estimation Diagnostic measure Model selection Forecasting Assumptions: 1. Non-seasonal

More information

Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? National University of Ireland, Galway

Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? National University of Ireland, Galway Provided by the author(s) and NUI Galway in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available. Title Are the US current account deficits really sustainable? Author(s)

More information

Vector Time Series Model Representations and Analysis with XploRe

Vector Time Series Model Representations and Analysis with XploRe 0-1 Vector Time Series Model Representations and Analysis with plore Julius Mungo CASE - Center for Applied Statistics and Economics Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin mungo@wiwi.hu-berlin.de plore MulTi Motivation

More information

Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis JUNE 2012 Time Series Analysis CONTENT A time series is a chronological sequence of observations on a particular variable. Usually the observations are taken at regular intervals (days, months, years),

More information

PPP Hypothesis and Multivariate Fractional Network Marketing

PPP Hypothesis and Multivariate Fractional Network Marketing econstor www.econstor.eu Der Open-Access-Publikationsserver der ZBW Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft The Open Access Publication Server of the ZBW Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Caporale,

More information

SYSTEMS OF REGRESSION EQUATIONS

SYSTEMS OF REGRESSION EQUATIONS SYSTEMS OF REGRESSION EQUATIONS 1. MULTIPLE EQUATIONS y nt = x nt n + u nt, n = 1,...,N, t = 1,...,T, x nt is 1 k, and n is k 1. This is a version of the standard regression model where the observations

More information

3. Regression & Exponential Smoothing

3. Regression & Exponential Smoothing 3. Regression & Exponential Smoothing 3.1 Forecasting a Single Time Series Two main approaches are traditionally used to model a single time series z 1, z 2,..., z n 1. Models the observation z t as a

More information

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate?

Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Is the Forward Exchange Rate a Useful Indicator of the Future Exchange Rate? Emily Polito, Trinity College In the past two decades, there have been many empirical studies both in support of and opposing

More information

Financial TIme Series Analysis: Part II

Financial TIme Series Analysis: Part II Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, Finland January 29 February 13, 2015 Feb 14, 2015 1 Univariate linear stochastic models: further topics Unobserved component model Signal

More information

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan Yoshiaki Azuma and Takeo Nakao January 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/62581/ MPRA Paper No. 62581, posted

More information

Chapter 4: Statistical Hypothesis Testing

Chapter 4: Statistical Hypothesis Testing Chapter 4: Statistical Hypothesis Testing Christophe Hurlin November 20, 2015 Christophe Hurlin () Advanced Econometrics - Master ESA November 20, 2015 1 / 225 Section 1 Introduction Christophe Hurlin

More information

Is Infrastructure Capital Productive? A Dynamic Heterogeneous Approach.

Is Infrastructure Capital Productive? A Dynamic Heterogeneous Approach. Is Infrastructure Capital Productive? A Dynamic Heterogeneous Approach. César Calderón a, Enrique Moral-Benito b, Luis Servén a a The World Bank b CEMFI International conference on Infrastructure Economics

More information

Unit Root Tests. 4.1 Introduction. This is page 111 Printer: Opaque this

Unit Root Tests. 4.1 Introduction. This is page 111 Printer: Opaque this 4 Unit Root Tests This is page 111 Printer: Opaque this 4.1 Introduction Many economic and financial time series exhibit trending behavior or nonstationarity in the mean. Leading examples are asset prices,

More information

Time Series Analysis

Time Series Analysis Time Series Analysis Forecasting with ARIMA models Andrés M. Alonso Carolina García-Martos Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Universidad Politécnica de Madrid June July, 2012 Alonso and García-Martos (UC3M-UPM)

More information

Likelihood Approaches for Trial Designs in Early Phase Oncology

Likelihood Approaches for Trial Designs in Early Phase Oncology Likelihood Approaches for Trial Designs in Early Phase Oncology Clinical Trials Elizabeth Garrett-Mayer, PhD Cody Chiuzan, PhD Hollings Cancer Center Department of Public Health Sciences Medical University

More information

Department of Economics

Department of Economics Department of Economics Working Paper Do Stock Market Risk Premium Respond to Consumer Confidence? By Abdur Chowdhury Working Paper 2011 06 College of Business Administration Do Stock Market Risk Premium

More information

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula

Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula Chapter 2: Binomial Methods and the Black-Scholes Formula 2.1 Binomial Trees We consider a financial market consisting of a bond B t = B(t), a stock S t = S(t), and a call-option C t = C(t), where the

More information

Lecture 2: ARMA(p,q) models (part 3)

Lecture 2: ARMA(p,q) models (part 3) Lecture 2: ARMA(p,q) models (part 3) Florian Pelgrin University of Lausanne, École des HEC Department of mathematics (IMEA-Nice) Sept. 2011 - Jan. 2012 Florian Pelgrin (HEC) Univariate time series Sept.

More information

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND

TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND I J A B E R, Vol. 13, No. 4, (2015): 1525-1534 TEMPORAL CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN STOCK MARKET CAPITALIZATION, TRADE OPENNESS AND REAL GDP: EVIDENCE FROM THAILAND Komain Jiranyakul * Abstract: This study

More information

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68)

Working Papers. Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market. Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek. No. 2/2012 (68) Working Papers No. 2/2012 (68) Piotr Arendarski Łukasz Postek Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market Warsaw 2012 Cointegration Based Trading Strategy For Soft Commodities Market

More information

ARMA, GARCH and Related Option Pricing Method

ARMA, GARCH and Related Option Pricing Method ARMA, GARCH and Related Option Pricing Method Author: Yiyang Yang Advisor: Pr. Xiaolin Li, Pr. Zari Rachev Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics State University of New York at Stony Brook September

More information

MAN-BITES-DOG BUSINESS CYCLES ONLINE APPENDIX

MAN-BITES-DOG BUSINESS CYCLES ONLINE APPENDIX MAN-BITES-DOG BUSINESS CYCLES ONLINE APPENDIX KRISTOFFER P. NIMARK The next section derives the equilibrium expressions for the beauty contest model from Section 3 of the main paper. This is followed by

More information

Modern Optimization Methods for Big Data Problems MATH11146 The University of Edinburgh

Modern Optimization Methods for Big Data Problems MATH11146 The University of Edinburgh Modern Optimization Methods for Big Data Problems MATH11146 The University of Edinburgh Peter Richtárik Week 3 Randomized Coordinate Descent With Arbitrary Sampling January 27, 2016 1 / 30 The Problem

More information

Planning And Scheduling Maintenance Resources In A Complex System

Planning And Scheduling Maintenance Resources In A Complex System Planning And Scheduling Maintenance Resources In A Complex System Martin Newby School of Engineering and Mathematical Sciences City University of London London m.j.newbycity.ac.uk Colin Barker QuaRCQ Group

More information

Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models

Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models Introduction to General and Generalized Linear Models General Linear Models - part I Henrik Madsen Poul Thyregod Informatics and Mathematical Modelling Technical University of Denmark DK-2800 Kgs. Lyngby

More information

Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability

Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability Nonlinear Dynamics and Systems Theory, 1(2) (2001) 111 119 Fuzzy Differential Systems and the New Concept of Stability V. Lakshmikantham 1 and S. Leela 2 1 Department of Mathematical Sciences, Florida

More information

TURUN YLIOPISTO UNIVERSITY OF TURKU TALOUSTIEDE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH REPORTS. A nonlinear moving average test as a robust test for ARCH

TURUN YLIOPISTO UNIVERSITY OF TURKU TALOUSTIEDE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH REPORTS. A nonlinear moving average test as a robust test for ARCH TURUN YLIOPISTO UNIVERSITY OF TURKU TALOUSTIEDE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS RESEARCH REPORTS ISSN 0786 656 ISBN 951 9 1450 6 A nonlinear moving average test as a robust test for ARCH Jussi Tolvi No 81 May

More information

Distressed Debt Prices and Recovery Rate Estimation

Distressed Debt Prices and Recovery Rate Estimation Distressed Debt Prices and Recovery Rate Estimation Robert Jarrow Joint Work with Xin Guo and Haizhi Lin May 2008 Introduction Recent market events highlight the importance of understanding credit risk.

More information

An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model

An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model An exact formula for default swaptions pricing in the SSRJD stochastic intensity model Naoufel El-Bachir (joint work with D. Brigo, Banca IMI) Radon Institute, Linz May 31, 2007 ICMA Centre, University

More information

A Regime-Switching Model for Electricity Spot Prices. Gero Schindlmayr EnBW Trading GmbH g.schindlmayr@enbw.com

A Regime-Switching Model for Electricity Spot Prices. Gero Schindlmayr EnBW Trading GmbH g.schindlmayr@enbw.com A Regime-Switching Model for Electricity Spot Prices Gero Schindlmayr EnBW Trading GmbH g.schindlmayr@enbw.com May 31, 25 A Regime-Switching Model for Electricity Spot Prices Abstract Electricity markets

More information

Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering

Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering Two Topics in Parametric Integration Applied to Stochastic Simulation in Industrial Engineering Department of Industrial Engineering and Management Sciences Northwestern University September 15th, 2014

More information

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models

Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models Chapter 4: Vector Autoregressive Models 1 Contents: Lehrstuhl für Department Empirische of Wirtschaftsforschung Empirical Research and und Econometrics Ökonometrie IV.1 Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR)...

More information

Integrated Resource Plan

Integrated Resource Plan Integrated Resource Plan March 19, 2004 PREPARED FOR KAUA I ISLAND UTILITY COOPERATIVE LCG Consulting 4962 El Camino Real, Suite 112 Los Altos, CA 94022 650-962-9670 1 IRP 1 ELECTRIC LOAD FORECASTING 1.1

More information

Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models

Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models Analysis of Bayesian Dynamic Linear Models Emily M. Casleton December 17, 2010 1 Introduction The main purpose of this project is to explore the Bayesian analysis of Dynamic Linear Models (DLMs). The main

More information

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim

Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim J. Korean Math. Soc. 43 (2006), No. 4, pp. 845 858 TWO APPROACHES FOR STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATE OPTION MODEL Jung-Soon Hyun and Young-Hee Kim Abstract. We present two approaches of the stochastic interest

More information

Online Appendix. Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and. Equilibrium Prices. by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos

Online Appendix. Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and. Equilibrium Prices. by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos Online Appendix Supplemental Material for Insider Trading, Stochastic Liquidity and Equilibrium Prices by Pierre Collin-Dufresne and Vyacheslav Fos 1. Deterministic growth rate of noise trader volatility

More information

The Ergodic Theorem and randomness

The Ergodic Theorem and randomness The Ergodic Theorem and randomness Peter Gács Department of Computer Science Boston University March 19, 2008 Peter Gács (Boston University) Ergodic theorem March 19, 2008 1 / 27 Introduction Introduction

More information

FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATED PANELS

FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HETEROGENEOUS COINTEGRATED PANELS FULLY MODIFIED OLS FOR HEEROGENEOUS COINEGRAED PANELS Peter Pedroni ABSRAC his chapter uses fully modified OLS principles to develop new methods for estimating and testing hypotheses for cointegrating

More information

BANACH AND HILBERT SPACE REVIEW

BANACH AND HILBERT SPACE REVIEW BANACH AND HILBET SPACE EVIEW CHISTOPHE HEIL These notes will briefly review some basic concepts related to the theory of Banach and Hilbert spaces. We are not trying to give a complete development, but

More information

Medical Net Discount Rates:

Medical Net Discount Rates: Medical Net Discount Rates: An Investigation into the Total Offset Approach Andrew G. Kraynak Fall 2011 COLLEGE OF THE HOLY CROSS ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT HONORS PROGRAM Motivation When estimating the cost

More information

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2015, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm

Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2015, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Midterm Booth School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2015, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Midterm Problem A: (30 pts) Answer briefly the following questions. Each question has

More information

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University

A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses. Michael R. Powers[ 1 ] Temple University and Tsinghua University A Coefficient of Variation for Skewed and Heavy-Tailed Insurance Losses Michael R. Powers[ ] Temple University and Tsinghua University Thomas Y. Powers Yale University [June 2009] Abstract We propose a

More information

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams

Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles. Noah Williams Lecture 14 More on Real Business Cycles Noah Williams University of Wisconsin - Madison Economics 312 Optimality Conditions Euler equation under uncertainty: u C (C t, 1 N t) = βe t [u C (C t+1, 1 N t+1)

More information

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1

Solución del Examen Tipo: 1 Solución del Examen Tipo: 1 Universidad Carlos III de Madrid ECONOMETRICS Academic year 2009/10 FINAL EXAM May 17, 2010 DURATION: 2 HOURS 1. Assume that model (III) verifies the assumptions of the classical

More information

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.436J/15.085J Fall 2008 Lecture 5 9/17/2008 RANDOM VARIABLES Contents 1. Random variables and measurable functions 2. Cumulative distribution functions 3. Discrete

More information

Threshold Autoregressive Models in Finance: A Comparative Approach

Threshold Autoregressive Models in Finance: A Comparative Approach University of Wollongong Research Online Applied Statistics Education and Research Collaboration (ASEARC) - Conference Papers Faculty of Informatics 2011 Threshold Autoregressive Models in Finance: A Comparative

More information

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models

The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates. An Impossible Bond Pricing Model. 780 w Interest Rate Models 780 w Interest Rate Models The Behavior of Bonds and Interest Rates Before discussing how a bond market-maker would delta-hedge, we first need to specify how bonds behave. Suppose we try to model a zero-coupon

More information

Understanding Poles and Zeros

Understanding Poles and Zeros MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY DEPARTMENT OF MECHANICAL ENGINEERING 2.14 Analysis and Design of Feedback Control Systems Understanding Poles and Zeros 1 System Poles and Zeros The transfer function

More information

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast

I. Basic concepts: Buoyancy and Elasticity II. Estimating Tax Elasticity III. From Mechanical Projection to Forecast Elements of Revenue Forecasting II: the Elasticity Approach and Projections of Revenue Components Fiscal Analysis and Forecasting Workshop Bangkok, Thailand June 16 27, 2014 Joshua Greene Consultant IMF-TAOLAM

More information